CONFIDENTIAL Comparative Review of Content Regulation A McKinsey Report for the Independent Television Commission 1 May 2002 SUMMARY OF KEY FINDINGS This report contains the findings of a review of content regulation in ten countries undertaken by McKinsey & Company for the Independent Television Commission. The countries reviewed were: Europe: France, Germany, Italy, Finland, Sweden Asia/Pacific: Japan, New Zealand, Australia North America: United States, Canada The review has highlighted four overarching trends in the regulation of content around the world – trends that are affecting all countries, albeit to varying degrees. 1. Access is emerging as the key theme of modern content regulation. Regulators everywhere are seeking to ensure the widest possible access to content, especially through new networks. In doing so, they are confronting a fundamental dilemma – how to encourage financial investment in these new networks and services, whilst minimising the risk of potential market dominance: Modern regulation is increasingly concerned with ensuring widespread access to content, delivered through new networks and services (such as digital television, mobile telephony and broadband). In most countries, this is viewed as essential to both economic and cultural dynamism. It is also a critical element in social policy, since there is an evident risk of a growing digital divide. There is an increasing need, therefore, for regulation that supports and encourages investment in these new networks and services. As recent events in several countries have illustrated, the investment required to enable speedy and ubiquitous roll-out is considerable – and it will only happen if investors feel that there is an appropriate balance between risk and reward. On the other hand, the network access business is inherently susceptible to market dominance (either outright monopoly or at least oligopoly). So, regulators are equally on their guard against the risks of market dominance either by seeking to ensure effective 1 competition amongst alternative service providers, or by mitigating the effect of a single dominant player. This dilemma between investment and competition is exemplified by the current debate on how to encourage the speedy roll-out of broadband networks and services. Most countries are concerned that broadband roll-out will not happen quickly enough under ‘normal’ market conditions – but their solutions vary. A few are investing public money to ensure rapid market penetration (Korea, Sweden and Japan). But most are limiting public investment to targeted subsidies aimed at outlying communities (US, France, Australia), focusing instead on regulatory measures to encourage effective competition. And some have foresworn any direct intervention in the market (New Zealand). 2. Editorial standards require new and innovative regulatory approaches. Regulators around the world continue to view the preservation of editorial standards as a primary focus. Services of all kinds need to command assent, and there is continued watchfulness on issues such as accuracy of news, decency and child protection. But the proliferation of content through multiple outlets makes the task of standards regulation ever more complex: There are now far too many sources of content to regulate in a uniform way across the board. Content delivered across hundreds of television channels and thousands of websites requires a new and more differentiated approach. Regulators are actively seeking ways to segment content sources, and to identify those that pose the greatest risk to the preservation of standards. Most are holding to the principle that regulatory controls should be proportionate to the pervasiveness and impact of the service involved. In pursuit of that principle, regulators continue to maintain active monitoring of editorial standards across traditional mass-market media, notably the leading free-to-air television channels. Notwithstanding the emergence of other outlets, these channels still capture the lion’s share of media consumption, and are therefore the most important priority for standards regulation. Regulators are tending to take a lighter touch approach to new niche or encrypted channels, aimed at an inherently smaller and more selfselecting audience. And this principle of self-selection applies even more strongly on the Internet, where standards regulation is at its lightest. 2 In the face of ever-increasing content proliferation, there is a perceptible trend around the world towards ‘self-regulation’. Content users are being supplied with a growing array of ‘selfregulation tools’ such as ratings mechanisms and content filters – although currently these tools are more prevalent and effective on encrypted, subscriber-based media. The next few years will test the efficacy of a self-regulation regime for multi-channel television and the Internet. Some countries are clearly tempted to pursue a more interventionist approach, and there have been several recent examples of judicial bodies seeking to impose legal liability for content carriers, including in the U.S. 3. Regulators are taking an increasingly structural approach to ensuring a range of high quality domestic content is available to national audiences. There is growing concern in most countries about the effect of multiple television channels and Internet websites on the range of high quality domestic content available to audiences. Given the economic forces that tend to favour imported content and cheaper derivatives, there is a widely shared need for regulatory intervention to nurture domestic production businesses. Again, different countries are addressing this concern in different ways: Only the US has a domestic market of sufficient size to be confident in the preservation of content quality through a thriving indigenous production industry. Everywhere else, there is a perceived need to encourage and support content quality and domestic production through some form of regulatory intervention. In most countries, the primary regulatory mechanism is the funding of one or more public service broadcasters (PSBs), which are mandated to deliver key aspects of quality and diversity to the national audience and to selected audience segments. Most countries around the world continue to support public service broadcasting, primarily through the licensing of specific public service channels. Limited experiments with subsidies for public service content delivered across commercial channels, such as in New Zealand, do not seem to have worked. As commercial pressures on media owners increase, there is a growing perception in most countries that behavioural regulation of content quality is declining in its effectiveness. There is an accelerating trend towards the use of structural regulation, and an expanding menu of structural mechanisms – restrictions on foreign ownership (France, Germany, Australia); investment targets and/or 3 quotas (France, Canada, Australia); privileges given to commercial networks in exchange for public service obligations (France, UK). The effect of structural regulation can be seen most directly in the level of spending on domestic content production, adjusted for market size. On that measure the UK currently comes close behind the US and well ahead of most other countries – a function apparently of a regulatory structure that ensures high levels of funding for public service broadcasting and an intensively competitive commercial market. Countries that have limited public funding and/or constrained commercial competition appear to be putting content quality and domestic production at risk. 4. Increasing media convergence is creating an expectation of a more coherent regulatory approach. Audiences around the world are increasingly able to access the same or similar content through multiple different media outlets. There is growing pressure, therefore, for common approaches to regulation across media – or at least for clarity about why different media are regulated in different ways. This is leading to changes both in regulatory structure and style. Several of the countries surveyed have taken steps to integrate previous separate regulatory bodies, or to consolidate and reinforce an already integrated structure (U.S., Canada, Japan, Finland). These and others have also sought to evolve the style of regulatory monitoring and intervention. There has been a growing emphasis on co-regulation in collaboration with industry participants. And regulators everywhere are adjusting their processes to make them more open and transparent. Impending UK legislation, enabling the creation of Ofcom, will embody these changes in regulatory structure and style, ensuring that the UK has a world-class regulatory regime for media content and services. 4 A. OBJECTIVES AND TOOLS OF CONTENT REGULATION Regulatory Objectives Our review has identified that most countries are pursuing four principal objectives in the regulation of content – albeit that they are pursuing those objectives in different ways. The objectives are: 1. Ensuring access to networks and services. Traditionally, this has meant promoting widespread access to basic content. A clear example is the Federal Communications Commission of the United States, an element of whose mission is to ensure universal access to basic broadcast services “so far as possible.” Section B discusses why industry changes are creating specific access challenges for new platforms and services. 2. Setting standards. Most countries pursue some sort of control over content standards. Most are concerned that citizens should be protected from harmful content, with the definition of “harmful” varying from country to country. For example, the French CSA aims to “safeguard fundamental principles such as respect, human dignity and public order”. The second focus of these standards revolves around a desire to maintain impartial, accurate news and current affairs reporting. An example of this is the imposition by the German regulator of the requirement “to distinguish between information and comment.” In the UK, “due accuracy and impartiality” has been required of broadcast news for over 50 years. These standards are analogous to Tier 1 regulation as proposed in the Government’s White Paper and Communications Legislation. 3. Promoting quality. This objective has three broad dimensions with countries pursuing one or more of these dimensions simultaneously. To encourage content that promotes a shared sense of national identity. This area has drawn increasing attention recently and includes the promotion of minority cultures. Canadian programming, for example, is required to reflect “Canadian creativity, talent and linguistic duality”. To encourage diversity and plurality of programming in subject and intended audience. In Italy, for example, RAI’s programming mission includes diversity “in order to satisfy the tastes of everyone.” 5 To promote investment in high-quality programming. For example, the Australian Broadcasting Act is designed to “promote diverse, innovative and quality programming”. 4. Ensuring a healthy, technologically up-to-date industry. This dimension aims to introduce an element of innovation into the regulator’s objective function. It has been stated less frequently as an explicit objective and is often subsumed within objectives 1 to 3 (where fulfilling those objectives would necessarily be done through a healthy, technologically up-to-date industry). However, some countries do choose to discuss it explicitly. Finland’s regulator aims to ensure consumers have access to “competitive and technically advanced communications services”. The countries reviewed can be characterised according to whether they have a light touch approach to these objectives, characterised by non-intervention or correction of market failures only, or whether they take a more goal-oriented approach to delivering positive outcomes. Regulatory Tools The regulatory tools used appear to fall into three broad categories: 1. Rules plus penalties: for example, codes governing editorial standards, production quotas or detailed content and scheduling requirements; 2. Targets plus incentives: targets that are more generalised and less prescriptive than rules and may be linked to incentives; for example, tax reliefs designed to encourage investment in infrastructure or content; 3. Structural alignment: where the industry framework is designed to support desired behaviour, for example by funding public service output, whilst avoiding detailed prescriptions. Countries may use a combination of these tools or apply specific tools to specific purposes. The UK, for example, has proposed in new legislation to apply codes and penalties to editorial standards in broadcasting and a combination of investment targets and funding interventions to support diversity and quality of content. The countries reviewed can be plotted on a matrix (Exhibit 1), with the extent to which they pursue positive goals and objectives on the Y axis, and the tools used to achieve them on the X axis. The arrows on the chart indicate that a number of countries are moving towards more goal-oriented objectives, but that the tools used are increasingly structural and incentive based and decreasingly reliant on rules and penalties. 6 Exhibit 1: Regulatory framework by country Exhibit 1 positions the United States at one corner of the matrix. With relatively limited objectives (mostly focused on anti-trust law) and employing few direct rules to shape market behaviour, the US is clearly pursing a non-interventionist approach to content regulation, and appears to be moving further in the direction of limited intervention. At the other extreme, countries like Canada and France clearly intend to guide the content providers towards specific goals (in both cases, centred around the promotion of specific national cultural elements). These two countries differ in how they support those objectives, with France relying more on rules and penalties, and Canada more likely to employ incentives. A group of countries, including Canada, Germany, Finland and Sweden, have quite substantial commitments to the objectives of regulation but are moving away from rules based tools towards reliance on structural interventions only, for example, by funding public service output. The UK would appear towards the bottom left of the matrix, with substantial policy goals for the sector but an increasing reliance under new legislation on industry structures and incentives and a reduction in regulation based on rules and penalties. 7 What emerges from this analysis, is that there are several different models of regulatory approach being pursued around the world. Three particular models seem worth of emphasis: 1. Regulation of market competition (e.g. U.S., Japan). Some of the larger countries place their primary emphasis on defining the competitive framework within which market players will operate. Often this approach is coupled with limited prescription of a regulatory vision for content. The US has effectively no direct rules for intervention. The country relies on rigorous application of antitrust law, to the point that industry attempts to implement a self-regulating Code of Conduct were banned by an antitrust ruling in 1982. The objective of regulation is primarily to deliver a competitive market; little specific standards regulation is applied, partly due to the strength of free speech limitations in the US Constitution. However, these countries are moving towards increasing positive interventions to encourage infrastructure developments, through tax incentives to encourage broadband infrastructure rollout in the US and government-led, direct funding in Japan. 2. Regulation of industry structure (e.g. Sweden, Finland). In several of the smaller countries, the market is not robust enough to bear the burden of using market mechanisms. Most of these countries, therefore, use structural tools to enable domestic content supply – the most common tool being the licensing of a public service broadcaster with a specific mandate to promote and deliver quality content. Differences in objectives have driven differences in the role that countries assign to their PSBs. For example, Sweden has created a strong PSB and only one other FTA channel. Historically Finland created a unique relationship between its PSB and its commercial company to ensure that the PSB remained free of advertising while not relying purely on state funding. This close relationship also prevented rivals from entering the market. The system has now been abandoned, but Finland has continued to use structural mechanisms to deliver its objectives - for example awarding the operating license for a 4th commercial channel in 1997 to Ruutunelonen which helps keep the Finnish broadcasting system in the hands of national owners. 3. Regulation of content supply (e.g. France, Canada, Australia). This approach continues to be quite common, although increasingly countries are moving away from command and control enforcement due in part to the difficulties in enforcing regulation as access and content proliferate, and in part to trends in international trade law. In particular, domestic content typically continues to be protected/encouraged through straightforward quotas. 8 The French regulator continues to have the clear goal of promoting French culture and language through strict quotas. The industry views this framework favourably as it is seen to be aligned with their interests in protecting their market position. In Australia, both ownership controls and quotas are used to ensure domestic control of the industry. Aggregate foreign ownership of a channel cannot exceed 20%. Domestic content quotas include 55% of daytime programming and 200 hours of Australian first release drama broadcast each year (this is similar to Canada, with 60% Canadian content required out of total broadcast time). 9 B. IMPACT OF MAJOR INDUSTRY CHANGES Rapid and accelerating changes in industry structure and performance are significantly changing the economic context in which content regulation is undertaken. These changes are reducing the effectiveness of some of the tools that regulators have traditionally deployed to fulfil their objectives. They are also altering content regulators’ view of what the regulatory objectives mean and their relative importance. Our review has identified four major industry trends with significant implications for content regulation. 1. Explosive growth in content. The diversity of content and its availability have grown significantly in the past 15 years, with the proliferation of commercial TV channels, interactive TV, and the Internet. Much of this content is international in origin and hence less easily controllable than domestic content Anyone can be a content producer for many of these content types, facilitating entry and exit Diverse ranges of content types have emerged – some with very narrow scope (e.g. TV channels specialising in certain programme types), others with a broad scope (e.g. Yahoo! websites) 2. Significant discontinuities in how content is used. Technological change is increasing the ability of content users to draw on content when it is needed and to tailor it to their individual tastes or needs (streaming video to a PC or delivering websites to a TV). Overall, there is a move towards interactivity (and hence individual control) rather than passive reception on the part of the end user. 3. Proliferation in access platforms and devices. These include the Internet, broadband, and third generation mobile receivers. Consumers have increasing choice and may become increasingly indifferent which platform is used to view which content. 4. Growing financial difficulties. Financial pressures have recently been inhibiting the roll-out of new services. The high costs of new networks and services have (at least temporarily) outstripped consumer willingness to pay, leading to a slowdown in take-up and some prominent business failures. 10 Exhibit 2: Summary of key industry trends These trends are raising a number of significant issues for each of the 4 key regulatory objectives (promoting access, setting standards, promoting quality, and ensuring a healthy industry). While the forces affecting regulation appear to be similar from country to country, the relative strength of each force, its challenge to existing regulation, and the regulatory responses differ. 1. Promoting Access There has been strong growth in the penetration of pay television and the Internet in many countries, but technological and economic constraints are likely to limit ubiquitous market penetration. In traditional broadcasting, the principle of universal access is firmly established. The focus now is on what degree of access the regulator will aim to ensure for new access platforms. Our review has identified the following observations: All countries are providing some incentives for digital TV rollout. There is a widespread desire to encourage the move to digital television as a way of supporting universal access to some of the new content. Most are creating incentives for the move to digital by announcing a date for analogue switch-off. The addition of new, 11 digital FTA channels is meant to further encourage consumers to move (e.g., in Sweden, Australia and the UK). Two opposite approaches to pay TV. While the debate is often not made explicit, some countries are taking the view that access to pay TV is not a regulatory objective (e.g., Germany), while others believe that access to pay TV should be included in the definition of ‘access’ (e.g., Netherlands). No clear position on broadband. All countries reviewed are concerned with ensuring that some sort of broadband rollout takes place, and most believe that wide access to broadband ultimately should be an objective of policy. However, there is no consensus either on whether the regulator should intervene or, if a decision to intervene is taken, how to do this effectively. The general approach with some exceptions (such as Sweden, which has devoted funding to encourage deployment in uneconomic areas) has appeared to be to take small incremental actions, or no actions in the short run. In addition to deployment, there is increasing focus on the financial challenges faced by potential broadband providers and on the challenge of ensuring the economic viability of platform providers. A major question is how to fund significant investment in the upgrades needed while at the same time boosting profits. In the absence of direct government funding, the resolution of this challenge appears to be leading to reduced competition between networks and to limited and sequential rollouts of the broadband platform in the medium term. More broadly, countries are increasingly evaluating the relative importance of content and access to prioritise the deployment of their regulatory resource and policy effort. There appears to have been some trend towards emphasising access, given the major hurdles that stand as barriers to broad access. However, as can be seen from Exhibit 3, most countries are still taking an approach that limits government intervention on access issues. 1 1 Korea, although not part of the review, is included in this Exhibit and in the discussion on access because of its aggressive promotion and funding of broadband. 12 Exhibit 3: Country classification: Approaches for regulating quality and access Even if a policy of widespread access to new platforms is adopted, there are significant barriers to delivering against this objective: Digital TV. While there is agreement that universal DTV access is a regulatory objective, the key question is who will fund it. This has not been answered in any of the countries reviewed, although a wide range of solutions is being considered. Pay TV. Those countries that aim to expand access to pay TV are finding it difficult in view of the financial difficulties of the industry. – Some countries reviewed are taking measures that actively restrict the growth of the sector. For example, in Germany the decision to preserve ‘killer’ content such as sports and movies on FTA means that pay TV has struggled to add subscribers. The collapse of Kirch Media was a recent, high profile example of the difficulties for pay TV. – Some countries are imposing access price caps on pay TV (e.g., Netherlands). While this is intended to ensure a wider swathe of the population can afford access, it also significantly worsens the economics of rollout for pay TV providers. 13 – Other countries seem to be reassessing the industry and considering measures to boost its health. This has been precipitated by the precarious financial state in which pay TV finds itself in many of the countries reviewed. Broadband Countries appear to be following one of three broad approaches to address issues surrounding the rollout of broadband. Light touch. Some countries are taking only small-scale actions to support rollout. In NZ, for example, the government has rejected direct subsidies to broadband, but has required Telecom NZ to upgrade its network to ensure access to narrowband for 99% of its users. This light touch may typically include: Creating transparent regulatory frameworks that do not restrict competition and access. Extending coverage of telephony universal service obligation (USO) to the Internet Targeting specific instances of the digital divide (and slightly boosting the industry). This can be achieved in its role as purchaser (e.g., buying broadband connections for schools and government offices in Switzerland) and through an online presence (e.g., making it easier to file taxes online than on paper). Co-operative. Other countries are using economic levers to incentivise rollout. For example, in the US this has included direct subsidies and tax deductions. Typically, this approach may also include: Focusing on specific issues/areas where the regulator believes the market will not deliver (e.g., France forcing France Telecom to decrease DSL wholesale prices) Direct government funding available for last mile connectivity and community/rural locations (e.g., US provides 50% subsidies to cable networks rolling out services to sparsely-populated areas and 20-90% subsidies on access to schools, libraries and health care facilities) Tax subsidies for broadband connections, particularly for professionals and small enterprises (e.g., Australian subsidy scheme for end-users upgrading to faster access technologies; 14 French subsidies and tax deductions for firms and public organisations to upgrade to broadband access) Subsidised or free programmes for education and training on the Internet to help create demand (e.g., USA – e-rate subsidises discounts of 20% to 90% on broadband services and applications for school/library/healthcare facilities; France – allocate a percent of education budget for online programmes) Funding available for R&D and for content (e.g., France) Government-led. Direct funding of infrastructure expansion has been adopted as the most effective alternative in some countries (e.g., Korea, Sweden, and now Japan). Direct government funding for broadband infrastructure deployment (e.g., Japan provides corporate tax deductions for build out of backbone and local loop) Comprehensive government-funded education and training programmes with explicit social and developmental objectives (e.g., aim of putting country at the forefront in the digital revolution) Reforms of the regulatory structure to ensure a competitive industry in broadband delivery Fully subsidised R&D (e.g., Japan) 2. Setting Content Standards With hundreds of new channels and thousands of websites, regulators are finding it increasingly difficult to control content through direct regulatory intervention. Content proliferation will require a much more differentiated approach. Options are summarized in Exhibit 4. 15 Exhibit 4: Regulation of Standards “Complaints and criminal law” “Brand value and co-regulation” “Regulatory sanctions” H* Use ex-post complaints system to monitor “RISK” (harm M created) Proactively involve top industry players (incentivised by their brand value etc.) in regulation Regulatory sanctions for highest risk and impact L L M H “IMPACT” (audience share) * Countries also use harsh penalties for high risk content (e.g., criminal law) but some violations may slide through Content can be classified by risk (severity of potential harm) and impact (number of people affected if harm occurs). Depending on the classification, content is being regulated differently: High risk, high impact content such as free-to-air content on national broadcast networks is generally subject to a combination of legal penalties, regulatory sanctions and self-regulation. High risk, low impact content such as violent or pornographic internet sites are, of course, subject to criminal laws that apply to such content, however published. But the law is hard to enforce and there is much debate about imposing legal liability on carriers or on content providers. Although specific liability on carriers has not yet been imposed outside China and similar regimes, the courts are increasingly imposing legal liabilities on carriers in the United States. Administrative fines have also been introduced in the US for offending content, and in France the courts ruled that Yahoo was required to block French users from accessing illegal content. 16 Low risk, low impact content such as companies’ or organisations’ web pages tends to be co-regulated by involving industry players and monitored through a system of ex-post complaints. Content providers collaborate in the definition and enforcement of standards. For example, Internet Watch is an industry association that operates rating and filtering systems, supported by a hotline to report illegal material on the web. It is funded both by the EU and the ISP industry and works closely with government and police. This approach also depends on ‘self-regulation’ by an increasingly sophisticated group of consumers. For example, Net Nanny software now allows parents to decide who in the family can access what, using pre-programming and pin codes. In Australia, the government has launched the Cyber Smart Kids programme to educate users on how to avoid harmful content. 3. Promoting Content Quality As traditional networks lose audience share, questions increasingly emerge as to the best way of maximising the availability of high quality content. The options include: Strengthening the public service broadcaster and/or FTA channels. This can take several forms: Strengthen the PSB to provide a quality alternative to commercial channels (e.g., Sweden, NZ) Use the digital licensing process to influence who is awarded licenses for terrestrial TV in order to ensure that digital TV provides a quality alternative to pay TV (e.g., Australia, Finland). Preserve audience share on FTA by prohibiting certain forms of content from pay TV (e.g., anti-siphoning legislation in Germany). In Germany, premium sports content and movies were prohibited from being moved onto pay TV by a court ruling (which effectively created a nearly insuperable challenge for German pay TV providers to overcome). Extending the scope of quality content into new forms of content (pay TV, Internet). This can include placing content requirements on pay TV and commercial FTA licensees, as with Canal+ in France. Alternatively, it may include providing a high-quality PSB presence on the Internet (e.g. BBC Online). Continued emphasis on content quotas, despite threat from international trade law. In Australia, France, Canada and other 17 countries, content quotas continue to be applied to both commercial and public broadcasters. However, this may be threatened by international trade law, which may treat these quotas as impeding the free flow of content. Increasing emphasis on funding of particular content. Countries that have not had strong PSB’s have considered direct funding of certain programme services. For example, NZ on Air provided direct funding to quality and minority-interest content production for delivery on otherwise totally commercial channels. However, recently, the New Zealand government moved away from this approach and reconstituted TVNZ as a public service channel with an overall remit to deliver quality and diversity across the schedule. In the US, the National Endowment for the Arts serves a similar purpose, providing direct funding to quality content. In the EU, the Initiative for European Content provides training, financial support for production, funding for distribution, and support for festivals, inter alia. 4. Creating a healthy industry The troubled financial situation of many players in the industry suggests the need for some regulatory actions to improve the health of the industry. While there is general agreement that this is an important objective, the challenge lies more in the ’how.’ There are two emerging approaches: The actions discussed above under access are also being weighed in terms of their ability to deliver a healthy industry. For example, the decision to impose pay TV price caps is designed to increase penetration, but will limit the health of the industry. This trade-off is being made differently in different countries. Network convergence increasingly means that the health of a given part of the sector cannot be viewed in isolation; regulators are increasingly under pressure to ensure that the industry is regulated in a holistic way. One of the key ways this is being delivered is through convergence of regulatory structures, as discussed in the next section. 18 C. EVOLUTION OF REGULATORY STRUCTURES AND STYLES Trends in the industry are not only affecting the ‘what’ and ‘how’ of regulation. They are also causing changes in how regulatory bodies are structured and the regulatory models with which they operate. In particular, there appears to be a trend towards consolidation both across industries and across functions. Our review has identified four alternative models of regulatory structure and approach, as illustrated in different countries around the world. Exhibit 5: Trends in regulatory structures 1. Creation of an integrated communications regulator (US, Japan). This structure uses one merged communications regulator, covering a broad range of issues in broadcasting and telecommunications. This body is then supported by competition law, which is applied to all sectors including communications. This appears to be where the UK will be positioned as well, once OFCOM is put into place. 19 Exhibit 6: Countries with merged broadcasting and telecommunications regulation 2. Some functions remaining outside merged regulator (Finland, Italy, Canada). In this case, there is a merged communications regulator but one or more functions continue to be addressed outside this body. In the case of Finland and Italy the functions outside the communications regulator are licensing/spectrum allocation, and in the case of Canada broadcasting standards set by the industry. 3. Some consolidation by function, but no stated intentions for further consolidation. In these countries, the split between regulatory bodies for different industries is being maintained. This includes NZ, Australia, France and Sweden. Typically this will mean that the regulation of telecommunications and broadcasting are still kept separate. 4. Highly fragmented, but moving towards consolidation. The current UK structure for content regulation is more fragmented than other countries reviewed. (Germany is also fragmented, but on a model of decentralised regional regulation). However, the UK appears to be moving towards the US/Japan model with the creation of OFCOM, which will be a major shift in the degree of consolidation. 20 Exhibit 7: Countries retaining distinct broadcasting regulators Changes in the regulatory style Regulatory structure only goes part of the way to explaining the nature of the interaction between the regulators and the industry. How rule-making is handled, or what we have called regulatory style, is a key aspect of the regulatory environment. This includes: Transparency of decision-making, Degree of consultation with industry in regulatory decision-making and standards-setting, Reliance on rule-making (i.e., as opposed to self-regulation with post-hoc enforcement where necessary), and Degree of ad hoc decision-making 21 This is a difficult area in which to categorise countries, since stated rules often do not indicate the true nature of regulatory and industry behaviour. Broadly speaking, however, countries follow one of 3 approaches: 1. Traditional rulemaking emphasis (e.g., France, Italy, Germany). In these markets the regulators retain a strong degree of control over the rulemaking process. As a result, it is often seen as somewhat unpredictable. Regulators may seek the informal input of industry but there are few formal processes for regular industry consultation. Consequently, the impact of one regulatory decision can have a huge effect on the health of a given part of the industry (e.g., the impact of blocking rights to premium content from pay TV players in Germany). In several of these countries, regulators have come under criticism for being insufficiently transparent, and in particular for being influenced by political pressures. Interestingly, however, at least certain industry sectors see themselves as benefiting from this – to the extent that they either (a) have found informal ways of having their views heard with the regulator or (b) are having their views well represented (e.g., the French film industry). France and Italy have recently restructured their regulators in an attempt to create greater independence. 2. Open approach with relatively high degree of reliance on industry coregulation (e.g., Australia, New Zealand). In contrast, several regulators have moved to increasing reliance on industry co-regulation for areas such as setting standards. For example, Australia has defined broad standards for TV broadcasting, but is relying on the industry to develop detailed standards (although the outcome is currently unclear). Most countries are using this approach to some degree or another (primarily of necessity, as discussed earlier) to regulate the Internet. 3. Emphasis on rulemaking, but with reasonably open process (e.g., US, Finland). A third group of countries continue to emphasise rulemaking by the regulator but with a clear process for decision-making which includes industry consultation. For example, in the U.S., rules are typically issued in draft form with a specified period allowed for written responses and input through hearings. This process creates less room for ad hoc regulatory decisions, which could otherwise introduce significant risk and unpredictability for industry players. 22 D. IMPACT OF REGULATORY POLICIES It is difficult to demonstrate with certainty the correlation between regulatory policies and market outcomes, especially given the influence of a range of other cultural factors. However, a number of patterns do seem to emerge. (1) Domestic content production. Not surprisingly, domestic content production is strongly reinforced by domestic content quotas. In Australia, these quotas have meant that over two-thirds of programme expenditure by commercial TV licensees is spent on Australian content each year (see Exhibit 8). Viewing time, as a result, is spent 50-70% on Australian content as well. Exhibit 8: Impact of quotas on provision of domestic content on Commercial TV Australian Example – Impact on commercial TV % domestic content on broadcast peak time commercial TV Programme expenditure by commercial TV licensees 70 864 267 60 Ch 9 50 Ch 7 Ch 10 596 40 187 30 153 20 120 19 26 Children’s Other Drama Light News Sport Total Foreign entertainAustralian ment Source: 10 91 Total 0 1998 1999 2000 ABA (2) Domestic control of content distribution. The degree of domestic control varies significantly across countries (see Exhibit 9). Typically, FTA television continues to be dominated by domestic ownership, but pay TV is increasingly foreign-owned, with major international providers increasingly taking control. Explicit measures have been taken that made it difficult for foreign companies to play in the German market, and as a result the only foreign ownership is in niche terrestrial channels on FTA and in 22% of the collapsed Kirch pay-TV 23 provider. In Italy, FTA channels are Italian-owned, but pay-TV is entirely in foreign hands. Exhibit 9: Degree of foreign ownership Low Medium Terrestrial U.K. • Channel 5 is currently the only terrestrial channel with any foreign ownership (67% RTL) France • Largest commercial channel (TF1) is French-owned • M6 40% owned by RTL Germany • Major channels are German-owned • Niche channels include ownership by U.S. firms Italy • 90% of audience share is Italianowned (by Berlusconi interest) Spain • Main commercial channels Spanishowned except Telecinco, 40% Mediaset U.S. • All networks are U.S.-owned (Murdoch Pay TV High • BSkyB controlled by News Corp Telewest 50% U.S.-owned (Liberty, Microsoft) • NTL U.S. company • ITV Digital (British-owned)* • Both pay TV businesses (Canal+ and TPS) are French-owned • Kirch pay TV was 22% owned by News Corp (via BSkyB) – Kirch has collapsed and its future is uncertain • Stream and Tele+ likely to merge with Vivendi in control • Italian investor Telecom Italia is exiting • Via Sat controlled by Telefonica • Canal+ majority owns Sogecable • U.S. owned networks has taken U.S. citizenship) * Has gone into administration Source: Zenith Media (3) Consolidation of the media industry. Across all countries, there are significant trends towards horizontal and vertical consolidation. In France, the major broadcasters all have production arms. Horizontal consolidation (e.g., across cable companies in the US) seems in addition to generate pressure for vertical consolidation to reap the benefits of scale. Exhibit 10 describes the degree of consolidation in selected countries reviewed. 24 Exhibit 10: Degree of industry consolidation Low Degree of industry consolidation Terrestrial U.K. • Strong BBC production • Granada/Carlton large content operations • C4/C5 rely on outside producers France • Main commercial broadcasters have strong production businesses • PSBs also invest heavily in their own production Germany • Commercial broadcasters hold minority stakes in independent producers • PSB invests in proprietary programming Italy • RAI shows predominantly own production • Mediaset shows significant amounts of Hollywood films/TV Spain • Still relatively fragmented market Medium High Pay TV • BSkyB has strong channel business • Telewest also has strong content business • NTL is weak in content production • Canal+ invests heavily in French content • TPS also produces own content • Kirch pay TV operated Germany’s sole pay TV business and was heavily reliant on U.S. programming – has collapsed • Both Stream and Tele+ invest heavily in local sports rights • Both pay platforms are reliant on U.S. content U.S. • Increasing media concentration and • Increasing as cable industry consolidates integration - e.g., Time Warner AOL Source: Zenith Media (4) Level of broadcasting expenditure per capita. Overall spend per capita appears to have an impact on content production. The level of funding in broadcasting varies widely across different countries (see Exhibit 11). Total spend in the US, Japan and the UK is far higher than in any of the other countries reviewed. In Japan, the highest share of that spend is in advertising (nearly 70%), with roughly 55% from advertising in the US and slightly under 50% in the UK. The UK’s public funding per capita is significantly higher than any other country reviewed. The combination of a competitive commercial market and high public funding means overall UK spend per capita is close to US levels and well ahead of all other countries except Japan. 25 Exhibit 11: Broadcasting expenditure per capita Broadcasting expenditure per capita Advertising Subscription Public funding Per capita, 1999, US$ Australia 89 Canada* 45 Finland 44 23 63 16 16 53 France 58 Germany 55 35 Italy 57 10 22 54 NZ Spain Sweden 46 160 Japan Korea 36 29 34 U.K. public funding per capita is the highest of the countries surveyed 44 38 39 33 56 51 U.K. U.S. 6 23 2 47 129 154 46 71 72 122 1 * Canada figures 1998 Source: OECD, U.S. Census Bureau 26 E. SUMMARY OF CONCLUSIONS Our review has identified how different countries around the world are tackling the challenge of regulating a rapidly changing content industry and market-place. While approaches inevitably vary between countries, we have identified four broad themes: 1. Increased emphasis on access. Regulators are increasingly focussing on network access, particularly as new digital and broadband networks are deployed. Their challenge is to enable speedy and ubiquitous roll-out of these networks, which will only happen if operators are able to secure an attractive return on their investment. At the same time, however, they have to protect against the risks of market dominance, by encouraging competition amongst alternative service providers. 2. Differentiated approaches to editorial standards. Content proliferation is complicating the task of regulating content standards – but issues such as accuracy of news, decency and child protection remain paramount. Regulators are having to develop differentiated approaches that are proportionate to the pervasiveness and impact of the services involved – with as much emphasis on self-regulation as possible. 3. Increasingly structural approach to content quality. As behavioural regulation declines in its efficacy, regulators are taking a more structural approach to content quality. Their primary focus is on structures that nurture a strong domestic production industry, able to deliver high quality content to the national audience – using mechanisms such as the licensing of public service broadcasters, investment targets and quotas. 4. More coherent regulatory structure and style. As media outlets converge, there is growing expectation of a coherent regulatory approach. This is reflected in the increasing integration of regulatory structures to grow the content industry. It is also reflected in changes to regulatory style – with growing emphasis on co-regulation and on open and transparent processes. The forthcoming legislation should enable the UK to meet these requirements and create a world-class regulatory regime. 27