LECTURE 12: LATIN AMERICA TO 1913 We need to begin with some very obvious points. We know comparatively little about output, employment, population and any other economic or social variable for any of the individual nations covered in this second semester before about 1950. Naturally, we know even less about the main regions (Latin America and the Middle East). I work on the basis that it is far better to have some data, whose reliability can be estimated and whose strengths and weakness can be recorded, than to have no data at all. The brief overview of the Latin American economies in the twentieth is based on figures from just 6 of the 20 mainland Central and Southern American nations. These are Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico and Venezuela. But these are the biggest, most economically and politically important countries and so should capture the broad picture of the continent as a whole. Or at least, these are the six most important economies when measured at the end of the 20 th century. Uruguay would have been included, and Venezuela excluded, if we had taken the six biggest economies of the late 19th century. Statistical Overview We have a number of tables that show the development of Latin America during the twentieth century. The most obvious place to begin is with population, and a broad picture of relatively rapid population growth since 1900. The simple graph of population for the six countries plus Colombia illustrates very well the rapid rise in population during the century, from just under 50 million in 1900 to in excess of 350 millions at the end of the century. The rate of population growth has been very fast, at approximately 2 per cent per annum over the period as a whole. But we need to be aware that there have been very different stimuli to growth. In the period up to 1913, not only were birth rates relatively high but also many Latin American countries gained population by migration from Europe. The phase of most rapid population growth in Argentina, for example came in the years of migration to 1913. Mexico, on the other hand, was stagnating demographically for most of the first three decades of the present century, but experienced pretty rapid acceleration thereafter. Brazil is the most populous country on the continent and its growth rate has mirrored that of the Latin American group as a whole. Figure 12.1: Population Growth in Latin America, 1900-94 180,000 160,000 140,000 120,000 100,000 80,000 60,000 40,000 20,000 19 00 19 04 19 08 19 12 19 16 19 20 19 24 19 28 19 32 19 36 19 40 19 44 19 48 19 52 19 56 19 60 19 64 19 68 19 72 19 76 19 80 19 84 19 88 19 92 0 Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru Venezuela When we look at economic change it is useful to be aware of turning points in the historical pattern and to adopt a comparative framework, to try to set Latin America into some sort of context. There are three main phases of Latin American development. The first phase takes us broadly up to the First World War and encompasses the very end of the period of export led growth in an integrated international economy. The next two phases embrace the very difficult period of depression and the Second World War, which is perhaps best sub-divided into two at the onset of the world slump of 1929. The final period embraces the second half of the century and takes in both the golden age of the world economy, the long boom between 1950 and roughly 1973, and the slower more disturbed period of growth that followed. The comparative dimension is covered by including Spain and Portugal, countries that share obvious cultural affinities with Latin America, and the USA, as the standard setter in the developed world. We can look at this in two ways. The first is simply to compare growth rates for the various periods and sub-periods. We are using GDP, adjusted by PPPs, as outlined in an early lecture in the previous semester. The figures in Table 1 show pretty clearly that Latin American performance was pretty good in the first half of the century, but during the second half performance has been generally disappointing. There is no simple explanation for the change in relative pace. In the 2 period 1900-13 Latin America was an export economy in a period of substantial international economic growth and increasing international integration. From 1913 to 1929, the large Latin America economies were being driven forward both by exports, but in a more troubled international economy, and the growing signs of domestic industrialisation, which were certainly evident in Brazil, Argentina and Mexico. The first real phase of ISI took place between 1929 and 1950, when the international economy slumped and the domestic industrial centres expanded more purposively. Table 12.1: Growth of GDP per capita, 1900-89, various countries (average annual compound rates) 1900-13 1913-29 1929-50 1950-73 1973-80 1980-9 Argentina 2.5 0.9 0.6 2.3 1.4 -2.5 Brazil 2.3 2.5 2.6 3.9 4.7 0.2 Mexico 1.9 0.1 1.6 3.3 3.5 -0.8 Latin American 6 2.2 2.4 1.8 2.6 2.3 -0.5 Spain & Portugal 1.3 0.7 0.4 5.3 1.2 2.5 However, the golden age of the world economy, when trade grew rapidly among the richer nations, seems to have had only muted impact on Latin America. Growth rates certainly accelerated, and the Brazilian and Mexican economies clearly strengthened their relative positions, but the other economies did much less well and were in part held back by Argentina, where growth was relatively disappointing. However, the overall performance was much less good than that of Spain and Portugal, included here as the most useful European comparators, for much of the period since 1945. Table 1 also shows that the 1980s were pretty dire in Latin America. The countries for which we have figures experienced net contraction through the 1980s, and Latin American living standards fell back very significantly indeed relative to the developed countries. So, at the level of the continent as a whole, or at least that part for which we have figures, there was relatively encouraging progress before 1950 and relative disappointment thereafter, with particular difficulties in the 1980s. Within the continent, there have been three main changes of note. The Argentine economy has relatively weakened, particularly after 1929 and again more dramatically in the 1980s. Brazil’s star on the other hand has waxed, especially in the period 1929-80, but it too had problems there after. Finally, Mexico’s ride has been more uneven, with real problems during the second phase, 1913-50, followed by a fairly stunning recovery during the long boom, and an equally substantial check in the 1980s. That really is the big picture. It is rather mixed, but there are discernible patterns that require explanation both for the whole continent and within it. 3 The Export Age The period of export-led growth that culminates in 1914 really began with the expansion of the world economy from 1850 onwards as Europe began to industrialise. You should be aware that the dominant interpretation of this period from the 1950s onwards came from within the dependency school. They saw the connections with the old colonial powers as conditioning the path of subsequent development. In more recent terminology, Latin America was path dependent. Structures were established early on, which offered few alternatives to economic agents that followed. The colonial pattern of exploitation of the periphery led to the transfer of capital from the periphery to the centre and resulted in the failure of the periphery, Latin America, to develop in the sense of broadening its economic structures and fundamentally strengthening its economic system. When these countries gained their independence from the colonial powers in the early 19th century, they were compelled to continue with the path of export-led development. By the Singer-Prebisch mechanism of deteriorating terms of trade for primary producers, the mechanisms of transferring capital from the periphery to the centre continued, and the control of the individual Latin American economies remained in the hand of the large-scale landowners, whose interests were furthered by keeping the economy open and avoiding any measures to ensure the development of local industry. If Latin America continued to import British textiles, Latin American primary producers would not only retain free access to British markets but also be able to import capital from London to extend the scope of the export economy. The big landowners also had large-scale agricultural holdings that might have been modernised to produce food for domestic consumption more efficiently, but instead were held as stores of wealth and emblems of social prestige. Thus Latin American domestic agriculture remained underdeveloped, manufacturing industry had only the most tenuous foothold, and the economy as a whole remained underdeveloped. This dependency approach came under increasing criticism in the last two decades of the twentieth century, not least because the Latin American economy performed reasonably well between 1870 and 1939, as Table 12.2 illustrates. Table 12.2: World Economic Growth, 1820-1929 (average annual growth rates) 1820-1870 1870-1913 Western Europe (GDP) 1.7 2.1 Latin America (GDP) 1.5 3.3 World (GDP) 1.0 2.1 World real exports 4.2 3.4 Latin America real exports 3.4 1913-1929 1.5 3.3 1.9 2.2 4.0 I want to spend the rest of this lecture exploring the new view of Latin American economic development. The logical place to begin is with the export sector. Latin America had traditionally 4 supplied precious metals to the colonial powers in Spain and Portugal, but after 1850 the continent became a major supplier of all types of primary products to the developing industrial centres in the European mainland. Some Latin American countries supplied industrial raw materials. Bolivia was a major tin exporter, and both Mexico and Peru supplied copper. Many more provided food, especially coffee (Brazil, Columbia, El Salvador, Guatemala, Haiti, Nicaragua, Venezuela) and sugar (Cuba, Puerto Rico). One of the characteristics of the Latin American economies during the period to 1914 was their extreme dependence on a very narrow range of export goods. In almost all the coffee exporters for example, that product comprised upwards of 50% of total export revenues, and in some cases (Guatemala and El Salvador) almost 80% of export earnings were dependent on the single product. There are 20 Latin American countries and none of them had a broadly based portfolio of exports. The best, Argentina, received more than 40% of its 1913 export revenues from two products, maize and wheat. Many of these countries recognised the vulnerabilities implied in heavy dependence on one or two major exports and attempted to broaden the base of their export economies. They naturally chose what was in demand in the major expanding markets of the industrialising economies, basically foodstuffs and industrial raw materials, but as they developed new products, so their older products seemed to go into decline and export vulnerability remained. In one sense, however, vulnerability was limited. In 1850, the UK was by far the major market for Latin American exports, but by 1913, the USA had become the main market, followed by Britain, but France and Germany also took sizeable shares of Latin American exports. In all these respects, Argentina was the example of best practice. It had far more success than most other countries in developing a range of export products, and it certainly serviced many more markets than any other Latin American nation. If the Latin America’s exports were dominated by primary products, its imports were dominated by manufactures, but as with its export trade the reliance on Britain diminished over the long period 1850-1913. Britain’s main export to Latin America had been cotton textiles and clothing in 1850 and remained so in 1913. The USA, however, came to dominate the supply of mining equipment, which was especially important for the tin and copper exporters, and both French and German manufactures found substantial markets in the main Latin American markets. There was, however, great competition between the major industrial countries for markets in Latin America during the late 19th and early 20th centuries and there is no real suggestion that Singer-Prebisch condition of extreme competitiveness in primary product exports, but monopoly supply in imports of manufactures was in 5 any way established before 1913. Indeed, it is highly unlikely that the Singer-Prebisch condition of adverse movements in the net barter terms of trade (the relation between the movement of prices in imports and exports) applied in any real sense in the period before 1913. Attempts have been made to calculate the NBTT for some of the Latin American republics, but they are extremely difficult to produce and tend to show a tendency to fluctuate through very broad cycles rather than to show any obvious trend towards decline. It seems unlikely, therefore, that the great bogey of dependency really can be brought forward to explain the inadequate development of the Latin American economies to press on towards full economic and social modernisation and become developed industrial economies as has happened in parts of the Far East and to a lesser extent in the Middle East. Indeed, one of the great advantages of participation in the integrated international economy of the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries is implicit in the diverse patterns of trade just discussed. The global, even globalised, economy in which the Latin American nations participated in the late nineteenth century was a multilateral international system. Countries participated in a sophisticated network of international trade in which there was a common world money, gold (which was supported by what we might now call reserve or trading currencies that were as good as gold – notably sterling, but also the German Mark and the French franc) and a multilateral system of settlements. Multilateralism is important. It allows trade to proceed much further than if trade is governed by bilateral principles in which each country has to balance its imports from each individual country in the system with exports to the same value. It should not take long to recognise that a bilateral world discourages trade, and anything that discourages trade will discourage the growth of world income. Latin American economies in the period up to 1913 not only experienced the vulnerabilities of the global system of trade and payments, but also enjoyed the considerable benefits, as the table shows. Table 12.2: Latin America, Economic and Social Indicators, c. 1913 Exports per GDP per Railways % of labour Literacy Life capita capita per capita in expectancy agriculture Argentina 67 188 4.4 34.2 63 46 Bolivia 20 0.7 21 29 Brazil 13 44 1.0 66.7 35 31 Chile 75 140 2.3 37.7 56 30 Mexico 13 78 0.6 63.7 Uruguay 59 195 2.1 28.0 67 52 Venezuela 9 0.3 72.0 30 30 Exports per capita and GDP per capita in current US$ Railways measured in kilometres per thousand population Literacy is the rate for those 15< years Life expectancy is measured in years at birth Source: Cardenas et al,, ‘Introduction’, in An Economic History of 20th Century Latin America, Tab. 1.4 6 If they had rejected world trade before 1913, there is little doubt that their incomes would have been lower, and probably by a considerable amount. Constraints on Latin America Development If the simple/simplistic dependency explanation of the failure to use this engagement in the international system as a springboard for industrialisation and modernisation carries little weight, it remains to be asked why they remain among the group of LDCs rather than can be counted in the DCs. One potential answer could lie in the export economy itself. The big textbook on the Latin American economy since the early nineteenth century, written by Bulmer-Thomas, suggests that very few of the Latin American nations could generate a sufficiently rapid rate of export growth to produce economic development of the wider economy. His argument has two parts. First, there were difficulties in getting sufficiently fast export growth because of shortages of factors of production. Secondly, the non-export sides of the Latin American economies were in many cases woefully inefficient and were resistant to pressures for greater efficiency and so acted as a big drag on the wider national, and indeed continental, economy. This is quite a complex argument, so we will begin with the easier part, the difficulty in channelling resources into the export sector to produce sufficiently rapid export growth. Any productive economic activity requires the application of factors of production to that activity. The factors of production are land, labour and capital. Land is sometimes omitted, especially when considering the developed countries, but it was clearly of great importance in Latin America. None of the Latin American countries was short of land in the period up to 1913, because in even the most heavily populated the land-labour balance was very favourable. Getting access to this land was however not always easy. There were two main obstacles. The first was the relatively underdeveloped state of transport and communications, and was overcome, where it was overcome, by the introduction of railways. The second problem was the systems of land ownership inherited from the colonial systems of Spain and Portugal, with land ownership heavily concentrated in the hands of the ultrawealthy. The amount of land in private ownership in 1913 was much, much greater than the amount privately owned in 1850, but the concentration of ownership had changed little. The wealthy also dominated political and social power and used this domination to ensure that land was not distributed more widely and also helped to ensure that the tax regime did not bear so heavily on landowners that 7 the break-up of the great estates at death or to meet fiscal liabilities. Thus access to land, and especially to fertile land, was a problem. The development of a more dynamic export economy also required capital and labour. The mobilisation of capital required potential borrowers, potential lenders and a financial system to bring the two together. The obvious borrowers were those wishing to develop the export economy and indeed governments ready to extend the infrastructure so that the export economy could move into new areas. The financial intermediaries were also fairly obvious. A number of British finance houses established commercial banking in a number of South American countries during the 19th century and helped channel funds from lenders to borrowers. The real problem was however the lenders. Although these banks tended to make good returns, they found it difficult to persuade those with the potential to save to commit their potential savings to the banking sector. Landowners tended to put their money back into land-ownership, indeed they needed to retain the concentration of land ownership already noted. The absence of a fully developed banking system did not prevent either the British or American industrial revolutions, and it was possible in Latin America to raise money from kinship or social networks but the examples were comparatively rare. For this reason, imports of capital were important. Britain remained the major supplier of investment to Latin America throughout the period to 1913, but France, Germany and the USA also became important inward investors by 1900. The governments of Latin American countries would issue foreign bonds on the London or Paris stock market, and use the money raised for whatever purpose it saw fit. But as Argentina has periodically demonstrated, these loans were not always used to the maximum benefit, and the failure to meet interest payments on a loan could lead to lengthy exclusion from the capital markets of developed market economies. The most famous is the collapse of Argentine credit in what is called the Baring crisis, which virtually ensured that Argentina was excluded from London money markets for a decade or so. The other main method of importing capital was to rely on foreign direct investment, or the creation of firms or productive facilities by overseas nationals. FDI tended to go into areas where there would be comparatively limited competition, so by 1913 Latin American railways, banks, public utilities, mining and shipping were dominated by foreigners. In addition US companies owned sugar mills in the Caribbean and banana plantations in Central America. Britain owned meat-packing plants in Argentina and Uruguay. Such companies tended to exploit natural and technological monopolies and cases of unfair competition and abuse of 8 power are not difficult to find. But this was mostly in the export sector. Domestic agriculture and domestic manufacturing saw hardly any foreign investment. So the supply of capital was patchy. A similar position can be found in respect of labour. Other New World countries acquired their labour on the basis of mass immigration from the Old World, but comparatively few Latin American were willing to adopt immigration on this pattern. Argentina was the main beneficiary, and as we have seen Argentina was the most successful at developing a range of export staple sectors throughout the century. Countries opted instead for selective immigration; Chinese coolies to work in sugar and cotton industries, workers from the British West Indies in some of the major transport projects etc., but most countries relied on the relatively high rate of natural increase and by transferring labour from within the economy. The populations of most of the Latin American republics were predominantly rural, with Argentina the main exception. The short-distance mobility from one rural occupation, probably in subsistence agriculture to another in export-oriented agriculture ought to have been relatively easy to organise, but the producers in the export sector were unwilling to raise wage levels to attract new workers. The markets into which they sold in Europe and North America were fiercely competitive and higher wage costs were definitely not on the agenda. A number of export industries tended to rely therefore on compulsion of various sorts to get their labour, especially where working conditions were arduous. Slavery was the pre-eminent form of compulsory labour service, and slavery died away only relatively slowly from Brazil. The net effect of all this was that many exportoriented primary producing industries in Latin America were short of labour through much of the later 19th century. In other words, given more plentiful and mobile supplies of land labour and capital, the export economies of Latin America would have grown faster than they did and might have provided a more favourable foundation for faster economic growth and more substantial modernisation than actually occurred, even in the relatively prosperous period before 1913. The other, equally significant dimension of the problem facing the Latin American economy in the years to 1913 was the difficulty in transforming the non-export side of the Latin American economy. The classic pattern is for the relatively less developed economy to be partially overwhelmed by imports from a more advanced neighbour, or equally to send exports to a more distant and more advanced complementary economy, and then to use those proceeds to finance more advanced imports. By these events, the domestic economy of the less developed country – and at this time the domestic economy would consist mainly of handicrafts, like spinning and weaving, or production of agricultural 9 products for domestic consumption – will be in some difficulty. The problem is to transform it and to make it competitive in the face of these new imports, and that process usually involves investment and some sort of technological adjustment or transformation. The classical example is the European industrial revolution. It was stimulated by a flood of cheap British cotton textile exports from Britain. Initially, continental industry was turned completely upside down by this influx. But those sections of textiles or handicraft metal-working that managed to withstand the initial influx quickly transformed their operations by using British methods, British capital and British skilled labour. At the same time the agriculture of France, the Low Countries and the German states was transformed to earn export revenues to pay for British cotton textile imports. The essence of the story is that modernisation spreads out from the foreign trade sector into much of the rest of the economy. In the European case, this process tended to take place without the positive assistance of governments, but rather as a result of market pressures and stimuli. Why did similar patterns not reveal themselves in 19 th century Latin America? There were two main non-export sectors in the 19th century Latin American economy. The first was what might be called ‘domestic’ agriculture and the second handicraft manufacturing, in other words almost identical to the situation in Europe on the eve of its industrial revolution. If, for example, the building of transport networks to service the export economy had also significantly widened the market for domestic agriculture by reducing transport costs; it is very likely that domestic agriculture would have been transformed. By and large, this transformation did not occur. Many Latin American economies were not only big exporters of agricultural products for export but were also significant importers of foodstuffs. The reasons why the agriculture of Latin America failed to respond to this situation more positively are complex, and Bulmer-Thomas has not yet given a very persuasive answer. At one level, the export-oriented agriculture created problems because it absorbed the best land and drove that part of agriculture producing food for the domestic market into more marginal lands in some of the republics. The further this sort of agriculture was pushed into the margins the more remote it was from its potentially transforming markets. The general shortage of capital was also a great problem, as was the cheapness of labour. The main point to emerge from Bulmer-Thomas’s account is that the system of land tenure in Latin America, which has figured so prominently in the accounts of the dependency school, seems to have relatively little impact. It is not really very realistic to compare the agriculture of Europe on the eve of its industrial revolution with that of Latin America in 1900. In 10 Europe agriculture had absorbed about 40% of the total population; in Latin America about 70%. This difference implies a very significant difference in average productivity in the two areas. In Europe, there was already a complex market system and reasonable infrastructure to foster commercial relations in agriculture and production for towns and for cash. In Latin America, agriculture was essentially providing subsistence for a poor rural population, kept poor by the comparative lack of infrastructural and institutional development. Almost exactly the same general framework of comparison will explain the failure of Latin American handicraft industry to transform and modernise itself in the face of competition from US and European manufactures. There were few major centres of urban population in Latin America outside a handful of major cities, Rio, Sao Paulo, Montevideo, Lima and Buenos Aires to constitute a market into which modernised Latin American manufacturing could sell. Power supplies were too unreliable to build modern factories. Transport networks were so underdeveloped that transport costs were potentially crippling. Three were very few modern factories in the whole of Latin America, and those that did exist were by and large either at the coast to process primary products destined for exports or servicing the handful of main markets. European handicraft industry had become quite sophisticated in its organisation and control by the system usually called proto-industrialisation. It was not impossible for such a system to produce an organised and strategic response to imports from a more modern producer. Proto-industry had not reached Latin America, in large part because the low productivity in Latin American agriculture left the market relatively small. Does all this provide an alternative to the dependency analysis, or is it merely a more sophisticated picture of the economics of Latin America before 1913 but which do not challenge the fundamental belief of the dependency school that the colonial inheritance left Latin America incapable of modernisation? The emphasis on the failure of export-oriented agriculture to develop sufficiently and of the non-export sector of Latin American economies to transform themselves does rely heavily on the unequal distribution of income flowing from colonially-based land-ownership patterns. There is no doubt that the Latin American elite did use capital imports to extend their own interests, even if the relationship between London and Buenos Aires, say, was far more fraught than the dependency school allows. However, the destructive blows against dependency analysis seem to me to reside in the problems of finding evidence for the Singer-Prebisch hypothesis before 1913 and the demonstration that the Latin American economy was short of much more simply than capital. Given that multiple 11 deficiency of factors of production and the knowledge that without the benefits that flowed from the system of multilateral trade before 1913 Latin American incomes would have been much lower and the problems of finding markets for domestic agriculture and industry would have been even more entrenched. The dependency analysts have underestimated both the strengths and the weaknesses of the Latin American economy of 1850-1913. 12