The Impact of Cardoso and Faletto’s Dependency and Development Robert R. Kaufman Rutgers University Prepared for conference on “International Inequality: Then and Now,” Watson Center, Brown University, April 4 and 5, 2008 1 Dependency and Development in Latin America, by Fernando Henrique Cardoso and Enzo Faletto, was a seminal work in the scholarly literature on Latin America. It simultaneously challenged two highly influential, alternative bodies of thought. On the one hand, it rejected a key assumption of the “modernization paradigm:” that the development of poor countries would move along paths similar to those already taken by those of the developed world. Like other dependency writers, Cardoso and Faletto (henceforth, C&F) framed their own analysis in terms of Latin America’s role in the international division of labor and on the premise of an unequal relation between center and periphery. “Capitalism,” they argued, “should be studied in the hope, not of finding how its history may repeat at a later date, but of learning how the relation between peripheral and central [countries] was produced.” (23) But C&F also challenged much of the dependency literature itself. In particular, they rejected the idea that the underdevelopment of the periphery was uniformly and irreversibly caused by the exploitation of developed capitalist economies. Dependency and Development focused instead on historical differences in how dependent societies had been integrated into the international economy and on how these differences interacted with domestic political alignments and development opportunities. Relations between center and periphery were unequal, but they were – in the view of C&F – neither uniform nor zero-sum, as much of the rest of the dependency literature had claimed. Directly and indirectly, the research agenda sketched in Dependency and Development exerted a major influence in the literature on Latin America, and to a more limited extent on other developing regions of the world. Yet the originality and importance of its critique of other strands of dependency perspective was never fully 2 understood or appreciated by “mainstream” U.S. comparativists. Consequently, the opportunities for debating how international constraints interacted with domestic political conflicts and coalitions were more limited than they should have been. One reason was the delayed publication of the English-language edition of the book, which did not come out until 1979, fully eight years after the Spanish edition. Lacking direct access to the Spanish version, English-speaking audiences tended to aim their fire (or praise) at much more simplistic and a-historical claims about dependency, most famously associated with the work of Andre Gunder Frank.1 Debate over whether economic integration doomed the periphery to underdevelopment missed the main point of C&F’s contribution, crowding out potentially more useful critical examinations of their complex arguments about the experiences of specific countries or broad differences in national development. The timing of international developments also limited the impact of the book in the United States. By the early and mid-1980s, just a few years after the publication of the English version, Latin America itself had moved on. Military regimes in Brazil, Argentina, and Uruguay were now on the defensive, and the region as a whole became swept up in the “third wave” of democratization. Over the course of the 1980s, concerns about issues raised in Dependency and Development faded and were replaced by a narrower focus on strategic opportunities for democratization, addressed to both scholars and political activists. The shift of attention to transitions from authoritarianism spawned outstanding contributions to our understanding of democratization, but tended to ignore the possible effects of underlying social conditions or international constraints. Frank’s Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. was published in English in 1969. It rapidly became the “voice” of the dependency school in the United States. 1 3 “Ironically,” as Barbara Stallings (1992: 43) noted, “just as international variables became especially important in the 1980s, they disappeared as the key factor from theories of development.” It is also ironic, I think, that much of the current political economy literature focuses on many issues anticipated twenty-five years earlier by Cardoso and Faletto. These issues, as Cardoso notes in his current paper, concern the way internationalized capital markets “condition” democratic struggles for equality; how these struggles are affected by variations in the modes of insertion into the international economy – particularly by relative abundance of factors of production; etc. There are clearly differences in both style and substance between the current literature and aspects of arguments raised by C&F, including specific substantive claims about the effects of foreign ownership, the neo-Marxist language of the text (class struggle, pacts of domination, socialism), and methodological approaches. But there are striking parallels as well. In the remainder of this paper, I want to spell out some of these points of agreement and dispute. But I also want to make a larger, “sociology of knowledge” point: namely, that there is much to be learned from more direct engagement of these very different traditions of analysis. Or, to put it differently, it would be wrong to repeat the errors of an earlier, more ideological era, when practitioners in these different traditions often talked passed each other. Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism; States and Regimes Let me begin by elaborating briefly on the impact of C&F on U.S. scholarship in the 1970s. To illustrate this impact, I refer specifically to two landmark studies of that 4 period that drew heavily on the perspectives pioneered in Dependency and Development. These are : Peter Evans’ Dependent Development (1979), and Guillermo O’Donnell’s Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism (197x). Following C&F, Evans traced the emerging alliance between the state, multinational capital, and large domestic industrial firms, arguing that this new ruling class had created a new pole of development in Brazil and possibly in other new industrial countries. A key contribution of the study was to put empirical flesh on the conceptual bones sketched in C&F. Evans examined in detail the strategies of foreign and domestic corporate investors within different economic sectors, and explored both the complementarities and tensions that accompanied the formation of the new “triple alliance.” At a more fundamental level, Evans pushed beyond C&F in his emphasis on “the state” as a relatively autonomous agent of development . In some circumstances, he argued, the actors controlling the state could play a pivotal role in promoting the political alliances and economic conditions necessary for a push toward industrialization on the periphery. In subsequent decades, this argument in turn contributed (along with Skocpol and others) to a burgeoning political sociological literature that sought to “bring the state back in” (Skocpol, Evans, and Reuschemeyer 1986; Reuschemeyer, Stephens and Stephens 1992; Kohli 2006) as an essential actor in promoting development, the organizing class alliances, and mediating relations with the international political economy. O’Donnell’s work on bureaucratic authoritarian regimes also drew on the C&F notion of dependent development, but spoke more directly to a political science audience. 5 O’Donnell did not view bureaucratic-authoritarian regimes as inevitable outcomes of emerging alliances between the state and international capital; nor did Cardoso. But O’Donnell did argue that there was an “elective affinity’’ between state-led efforts to push beyond earlier, “easier” phases of import-substitution and the emergence of technocratic and profoundly anti-populist forms of authoritarianism in the more advanced industrial societies of Latin America. The pursuit of new developmental projects, in turn, were spurred by political as well as economic pressures: most specifically, by the evolution of Cold War national security doctrines that encouraged the military to assume a more direct and prolonged control of the state in alliance with big business and technocratic elites. O’Donnell’s study, like Evans’s, provided a more systematic conceptual and empirical foundation for some of the ideas elaborated in Dependency and Development, and also sparked a substantial debate in political science circles. Critical analysis of the “O’Donnell model” showed that a number of his initial claims were problematic (Collier 1979; Kaufman 1979). The connection between bureaucratic-authoritarianism and industrial “deepening” – initially emphasized by O’Donnell -- applied primarily to Brazil, but not to the Southern Cone countries which instead moved toward more liberal, exportoriented models during the 1970s. Yet radical authoritarian projects of reform – whether through neoliberal openings or new associations between the state and multinational capital – did imply deep social conflicts with interests and expectations mobilized around previous import-substituting models and national-populist alliances. This in turn arguably contributed to our understanding of the type of authoritarianism which emerged in the region during the 1960s and 1970s. 6 Writers such as Linz and Stepan (1979) and Valenezuela (1979) raised more fundamental questions about the emphasis found in the dependency perspective on structural constraints and class conflicts. Though they did not directly confront the analysis of C&F or O’Donnell, these critics argued that neither economic structure nor economic crises accounted adequately for the breakdown of democracy in Latin America. The more powerful explanations, in their view, lay in the miscalculations of competing political elites and on incentives to polarization embedded in presidential constitutions and electoral institutions. This emphasis on political actors and the institutional incentives that they faced contributed significantly not only to the analysis of democratic breakdowns, but also to our understanding of transitions away from authoritarianism (O’Donnell and Schmitter 1986). Nevertheless, as noted, this literature did not systematically address some of the key claims of the dependent development perspective, and this remained an important shortcoming. The central issue was not whether dependent development “required” authoritarianism; indeed, as Cardoso states in an epilogue to the English edition, “the same fundamental alliance which constitutes a dependent industrial capitalist state may organize itself institutionally within a context of authoritarianism, restricted democracy, or totalitarianism.” (210) Instead, it was whether and how the developmental alliances and economic transformations of that period impeded the emergence of mass democracy and whether it shaped the particular form of exclusionary authoritarianism which was then appearing on the scene. Ex post, it became clear during the 1980s and 1990s that the time of exclusionary B-A regimes had passed, and that mass democracies could in fact survive – indeed, even 7 engineer – “neoliberal” transformations. Yet the eclipse of bureaucratic-authoritarianism – and the survival of democracies -- owed much to the winding down and end of the Cold War, an international change that fundamentally altered the context of the causal arguments that had been advanced by C&F and O’Donnell. In itself, therefore, the eclipse of B-A regimes did not disconfirm their earlier analyses. More important, although most democracies survived the 1980s intact, many failed during that decade to adapt to the new realities of the global economy. These failures in turn contributed significantly to a reversal of democracy in Peru under Fujimori, and to deep political crises in Bolivia and Argentina during the middle and late 1980s, and to a broader tendency for elected presidents to attempt to impose reforms by decree (Haggard and Kaufman 1995). In the new post-1980 context, to be sure, the specific arguments advanced during the preceding decade no longer provided a suitable framework for understanding these developments. But the “democratization literature” might well have been strengthened by closer attention to the way international structural constraints conditioned the opportunities for domestic political coalitions. Indeed, as I will discuss in the final section of the paper, the questions raised in contemporary international political economy have evolved very much along these lines. Modes of Insertion: Colonialism, Inequality, and Underdevelopment What light does the C&F perspective cast on debates about contemporary struggles for equality and democracy? In the next three sections of this paper, I highlight several interrelated ways that their work anticipated current political economy research. The first concerns their emphasis on “modes of insertion” into the international economy 8 and their effects on long-term prospects for development. In both Dependency and Development and in his essay for this conference, Cardoso emphasizes the distinction between enclave economies, in which the export sector was controlled by foreign companies, and locally-controlled export sectors with more extensive backward linkages. These distinctions, argued C&F, helped account for types of responses to later economic shocks of the early 20th century, especially the emergence of national-populist alliances and the changing role of the state in more recent experiences of industrialization. The post-dependency literature on development and underdevelopment places much less emphasis on differences between foreign versus domestic ownership and emphasizes instead the legacy of the colonial period. But a growing body of important research focuses, as did C&F, on the domestic and international power relations that shaped Latin America’s entry into the international system, and their long-term impact on economic and political institutions. Influential articles by Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2001, 2002) and Engerman and Sokoloff (2002) have focused on economic and social conditions at the time of colonization. Acemoglu et al highlight the legacy of differences in the precolonial health climate on both contemporary institutions and economic performance. Low mortality rates at the time of colonization encouraged the establishment of settler societies, and institutions based on property guarantees and checks against state predation. “Efficient” institutions persisted over time, providing the foundation for sustained growth. In areas with high mortality rates, including the Caribbean, Central America, and much of South America, colonial elites were motivated to establish extractive institutions aimed at maximizing opportunities for the exploitation of labor and 9 raw materials, with negative implications for long-term development. Once established, these institutions locked in power relationships that were difficult to change, leading over time to a widening gap between settler societies and those with extractive institutions. Engerman and Sokoloff elaborate a similar argument, but focus on factor endowments of the pre-colonial societies -- particularly, the availability of mineral resources or climates and land suitable for plantation agriculture. Opportunities to exploit such resources created strong incentives for colonial elites to monopolize access to productive resources and to forcibly extract surpluses from the labor of the underlying population. Like Acemoglu et al, they posit a strong tendency for these systems to reproduce themselves and retard economic and social development. As is also the case with Acemoglu et al, a key difference with the analysis in C&F is that the identity of the elites that control these systems – eg., whether they are foreign or domestic – is not considered an important factor. The analysis of Lange, Mahoney, and vom Hau (2006) share more of the spirit, if not the specifics, of C&F. While the nationality of owners is not important in their analysis, the identity of the colonial powers is. Spanish colonial powers were more likely reproduce the full panoply of mercantilist institutions found at home in societies already characterized by dense populations and hierarchical controls, and were less likely to do so where such social infrastructures were lacking. British colonists, conversely, had stronger incentives to reproduce the liberal institutions of the home country in poorer, less populated areas where they would encounter less social resistance, but (unlike the Spanish) tended to prefer indirect colonial rule in societies with wealthier and more complex pre-colonial civilizations. Lange et al show that the type and level of colonial 10 institutions accounted for much of the “reversals” of fortune” in the late 18th and early 19th centuries in which once wealthy colonial societies began to fall behind their poorer counterparts. Despite important disagreements, these authors and C&F converge around key causal assumptions, noted above, about the importance of the power relations and institutions that mediated the integration of Latin America into the international order. Such convergence provides a conceptual foundation for a constructive debate about the types of power relations and the types of institutions – including the nationality of property owners -- that mattered most. The authors also share the view that these arrangements had an enduring impact. Elites that benefited from earlier institutions acquired power resources that allowed them to maintain their dominant position as circumstances changed. History matters! But such claims also highlight how much remains to be done. Neither the contemporary authors nor C&F spell out clearly the way (and extent) to which the formation of early institutions “lock in” elite dominance across the centuries since independence. In Acemoglu et al, for example, inferences about the effects of path dependence are the based primarily on quantitative analysis, which shows a marked statistical relationship between early institutions and contemporary growth rates. This approach is useful, but obviously not fully satisfactory. C&F’s approach, though highly compressed, points to the need for a fuller historical examination of the way the legacies of the past affect the response to new challenges and development opportunities. Unlike the other authors cited, C&F point to a series of turning points or critical junctures in the post-colonial period that can be 11 viewed as important opportunities for change. In deed, throughout the book, the authors show that existing systems of domination are continuously subject to challenge and reordering, and that their continuity cannot simply be assumed. This in turn implies the need for a more extended historical analysis which problematizes the continuity of the “path” of a country’s development as it moves through different historical conjunctures.2 Enclave economies, capital mobility and political radicalism As Cardoso suggests in his current essay, aspects of the dependency perspective he elaborated with Faletto are also highly relevant to differences among the left parties and populist movements that have emerged in the region since the late 1990s. In the late 20th and early 21st centuries, the enclave characteristic of societies like Venezuela, Bolivia, and Ecuador may help to account for the radical, anti-market populism that has swept those countries. These are contrasted with more “social democratic” parties that have emerged in societies with more diversified export sectors and more mobile forms of capital. This argument, like the preceding one, maps closely to a growing number of studies in contemporary political-economy. In highly unequal societies such as most of the ones in Latin America, redistributive conflicts are exacerbated by the predominance of “sticky” assets that are not easy to shift into other sectors of the economy (Boix 2003, Acemoglu and Robinson 2006). The nationality of the owners, as well as differences between public and private ownership, clearly play a role in such circumstances. Where the “enclave” is privately controlled, particularly by foreign companies, sunk investments are hostage to distributive popular-sector and radical nationalist demands. Capitalists associated with 2 Important studies focusing on post-colonial critical junctures are Collier and Collier (1991 ) and Mahoney (2001). 12 these sectors, on the other hand, are more likely to engage in polarizing responses. This has been the case in Bolivia, for example, since the late 1990s. Privatized utility and power companies also face strong popular opposition, particularly from middle-class consumers faced with higher charges (Murillo, Baker). As a consequence, governments often face significant pressures to renationalize. Public companies in the export sector attract less direct opposition, but also encounter major pressures to finance distributive programs, as in the petroleum sectors in Venezuela and Ecuador. Where capital is more diversified and mobile, exit options provide businesses with a second line of defense against radical distributive pressures, and this in turn creates strong incentives for representatives of low-income groups to move toward the center. The best known case here is Brazil after 2002. The PT and Lula had already begun to migrate toward the center in the 1990s, after losses in successive presidential elections seemed to show that they could not win with the radical anti-market appeals of the preceding decade. Lula’s most definitive embrace of the market came, however, during the presidential campaign of 2002 and in the first term of his presidency, in response to economic crisis and the threat of capital flight. Maintaining financial stability meant maintaining credibility with mobile capital, and this in turn motivated the Lula government to sustain and even deepen the strict fiscal discipline pursued by the preceding Cardoso government. Differences in the degree of capital mobility, in short, encourage “left” governments to behave far more cautiously than their more radical populist counterparts in “enclave” economies. How does the threat of exit and the corresponding incentive to adopt cautious macroeconomic policies affect the capacity of governments to address underlying issues 13 of social distribution? The possibility of a regressive “race to the bottom” has been a recurrent theme in the literature on globalization. Yet, as I will elaborate more below, experiences in countries such as Brazil and Chile do not indicate that this is happening. As both the Cardoso and Lula governments have shown, there is room for maneuver even in circumstances of globalization and tight budget constraints. Democratic governments have been able to reallocate scarce fiscal resources and develop social programs in ways that have begun to reduce poverty and incrementally reduce income inequality within the framework of a market economy. Economic openness, to be sure, does place limits on the range of viable choice available to national governments; and there are certainly no guarantees that they will adopt progressive social policies. In large measure, as implied in C&F’s book, this will depend on domestic political forces as well as international constraints. Globalization and constraints on social policies In this final section, we look more broadly at the constraints and opportunities within the new global context. Within the international political system, developed country governments continue to exercise extensive influence over the rules of international trade and finance. But as Cardoso suggests in his current paper, political asymmetries between developed and developing world have diminished considerably. American hegemony, initially thought to be unassailable after the fall of the Soviet Union, has been increasingly challenged by regional great powers such as Russia, China, and Brazil, as well as by oil states and other developed countries. The IMF, while still an important player for many poor countries, no longer wields the extensive influence in Latin America that it did during the debt crisis of the 1980s. Its power has been reduced 14 by alternative sources of international credit, by cross-conditionalities, and by the compliance problems that had always plagued IFI loan agreements (Kahler 1992). The World Bank, though an important source of policy advice, acts more through the diffusion of ideas (a “knowledge bank”) than through the leverage of conditional loans. Despite these changes, the importance of the international constraints facing the countries of Latin America should not be underestimated. More than any single source of political power, these constraints operate through international market forces not directly controlled by governments, forces to which Latin American economies have become increasingly exposed. In general, they face higher levels of volatility than they did during the import-substituting era. Moreover, shallow domestic capital markets and uncertain access to external lending also limits the capacity for fiscal stimuli during periods of downturn (Wibbels 2006); unlike the OECD countries, fiscal policies tend to be pro-cyclical throughout the region, limiting the ability of states to cushion their populations from economic shocks or to sustain comprehensive welfare systems. Liberalization has also altered the balance of economic power among domestic political forces, but in ways more in line with the dependency perspective than with the predications of liberal economic theorists. Early expectations based on the HeckscherOhlin model were that labor, an “abundant factor” relative to capital, would gain from the opening of import-substituting economies. However, such gains did not materialize in the land or mineral rich countries of the region. Nor was this the case in middle-income countries where investment in higher-end industrial production widened the gap between the wages of skilled and unskilled labor. Although the biggest increase in inequality can 15 be attributed to debt and inflationary crises of the 1980s, the liberal reforms of the 1990s did not reduce these inequalities and probably increased them in some cases. As Cardoso and Faletto emphasized over thirty years ago, however, such developments are far from uniform across the region; indeed, they are less so today than ever before. They are affected not only by variations in the domestic economic structure – a point implicit in the preceding paragraph – but by the insertion of governments, and underlying political alliances, into the economy and society. Increasingly, the core causal assumptions sketched out in Dependency and Development have been echoed in much of the contemporary political-economy research on “globalization.” Integration into the international economy conditions (but does not directly determine) the opportunities and incentives faced by domestic political interests; conversely, domestic political choices and institutions can play a major mediating role. One outward sign of these complex influences is that spending on social welfare policies has increased over the last two decades. In the larger welfare states of the region, this has been accomplished primarily through the reallocation of resources away from other parts of the budget – a clear indication of a major shift in political priorities (CEPAL, Social Panorama), particularly in the face of severe fiscal constraints. The shift in categories of social spending – from relatively regressive social security expenditures to more progressive health and education sectors – is still another sign of changing political priorities. Perhaps most important is the evidence of ongoing efforts to establish innovative social programs – such as Bolsa Familia and Progresa that operate within the realities of budget constraints, but have had measurable effects on poverty levels and human capital. 16 Ongoing research continues to explore the international and domestic political influences on such policies; firm conclusions are yet to be reached. Yet it does seem likely that democratization has played an important role. Democratic regimes, to be sure, have had to adapt policy to respond to the more competitive international environment. But electoral competition has also strengthened incentives for political authorities to address the social needs of low-income voters, and this has had an impact on policy. Despite pressures of globalization, for example, health and education expenditures tended to increase more rapidly under democracies than authoritarian regimes (Kaufman and Segura 2001). Democratic regimes have also been found to be more likely to sustain social spending during periods of economic shock (Rudra and Haggard 2005). Political factors other than democracy itself appear to affect not only spending, but more direct measures of social welfare outcomes. For example, a study by Isabela Mares (2005) shows that coverage and generosity of social protections vary with the political strength of groups highly exposed to external risk and with the capability of state institutions (as measured by the “rule of law” index). Studies by Huber et al (2006) show the importance of the long-term strength of left parties in the Latin American countries. Poverty rates and inequality decrease in countries where left parties have enjoyed significant legislative strength for long periods of time. Such studies by no means provide “final answers” to questions posed by either the dependency perspective or contemporary political economy. They do, however, establish at least a rebutable presumption that the effects of globalization are likely to be conditional rather than direct, and that they are highly mediated by the social and political forces within individual countries. 17 A brief note on method The articles cited above use quantitative and/or formal methods to examine contemporary issues of globalization. These, of course, are not the only way such issues can be investigated. Indeed, qualitative approaches to the study of development have grown in the methodological rigor with which they treat issues of case selection, concept formation, and causality. Nevertheless, quantitative and formal methods above represent a growing trend in the political science literature, and it is important to address their potential contributions and limits. In his introduction to the English edition of Dependency and Development, Cardoso raised serious questions about whether such approaches were appropriate to the concepts and complex causal arguments of the dependency perspective. But whatever the merits of his criticism in 1979, I believe it should be reconsidered today. Both formal theory and quantitative method can be highly useful tools for capturing some of the complex causal relations emphasized in the dependency perspective. Formal theory – particularly game theoretic models – address the consequences of individual choices as they respond to the tradeoffs associated with structural constraints and with expectations about the actions of others. Such models are sometimes criticized – often correctly – as overly abstract and a-historical. But this problem is not necessarily built into the approach. On the contrary, in many respects, the emphasis on the interdependence and tradeoffs associated with the choices of individual agents is potentially well positioned to build in parameters which capture the complexities of the post-dependency world. 18 Quantitative analysis in turn has moved away from the simplistic linear arguments of an earlier period to the examination of more complex social interactions. Indeed, in some respects, the causal language and interaction terms introduced into this literature closely parallels the earlier dependency argument: that international constraints condition domestic political conflicts and choices about economic policy – and conversely, that responses to these constraints will be conditioned by domestic society and politics. This emphasis on conditional effects maps closely to the ontological assumptions about causality implicit in the dependency literature. Whatever the utility of these approaches, however, they cannot fully displace more qualitative and historical approaches. Formal models can theorize about political choices, but only systematic historical analysis can determine whether the identity and motivations of the actors have been correctly predicted. Quantitative analysis can demonstrate correlations consistent with theoretical expectations, but can never directly reveal the causal mechanisms behind the correlations. These require case studies and well designed small-n comparisons which allow us to get inside the structure and organization of national states, private actors in the global market place, and groups that challenge or align with them politically. The key point is that, in the early 21st century, what were once rival methodological approaches have become, at least potentially, complementary. Bibliography Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press. 19 Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson 2001 “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review 91 (1369-1401) Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson 2002. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (1231-94). Boix, Carles 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge University Press. Collier, David. 1979. The New authoritarianism in Latin America Princeton, N.J. : Princeton University Press. Collier, Ruth and David Collier (1991). Shaping the Political Arena. Engerman, Stanley L. and Kenneth L. Sokoloff 2002, Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development among New World Economies,“ Economia Vol. 3, (41-88). Evans, Peter B. 1979 Dependent development : the alliance of multinational, state, and local capital in Brazil Princeton, N.J. : Princeton University Press 20 Frank, Andre Gunder 1969. Capitalism and underdevelopment in Latin America; historical studies of Chile and Brazil. New York: Monthly Review Press Haggard, Stephan, and Robert R. Kaufman 1995. The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Huber, Evelyne, Francois Nielsen, Jenny Pribble, and John D. Stephens 2006. “Politics and Inequality in Latin America and the Caribbean, American Sociological Review, Vol. 71 (December: 943-963). Kahler, Miles. 1992. “External Influences, Conditionality, and the Politics of Adjustment,” in Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman, eds. The Politics of economic adjustment : international constraints, distributive conflicts, and the state Princeton, NJ : Princeton University Press. Kaufman, Robert 1979. "Industrial Change and Authoritarianism, A Concrete Review of the Bureaucratic-Authoritarian Model," in David Collier, ed., The New Authoritarianism in Latin America (Princeton University Press, 1979), pp. 165-255. _____ and Alex Segura-Ubiergo 2001. “Globalization, Domestic Politics and Social Spending: A Time-Series, Cross-Section Analysis 1973–1997,”World Politics 53, 4 (July): 553–87. 21 Kohli, Atul 2004. State-directed development : political power and industrialization in the global periphery Cambridge, UK ; New York : Cambridge University Press. Lange, Matthew, James Mahoney, and Matthias vom Hau 2006. “Colonialism and Development: A Comparative Analysis of Spanish and British Colonies. American Journal of Sociology 111: 5 (March): 1412-62. Linz, Juan J. and Alfred Stepan, eds. 1978. The Breakdown of democratic regimes Baltimore : John Hopkins University Press. Mahoney, James 2001. The legacies of liberalism : path dependence and political regimes in Central America Baltimore, Md. ; London : Johns Hopkins University Press. Mares, Isabela 2005. O’Donnell, Guillermo 1973. Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism: Studies in South American Politics. Berkeley: University of California, Institute for International Studies. O’Donnell, Guillermo and Philippe C. Schmitter 1986. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press. 22 O’Donnell, Guillermo, Philippe C. Schmitter, and Laurence Whitehead, eds. 1986. Transitions from authoritarian rule. Comparative perspectives. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press. Rudra, Nita, and Stephan Haggard. 2005. “Globalization, Democracy, and Effective Social Spending in the Developing World,” Comparative Political Studies 38, 9 (November): 1–35. Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens. 1992. Capitalist development and democracy Chicago : University of Chicago Press. Skcopol, Theda, Peter B. Evans, and Dietrich Rueschemeyer, eds. 1985. Bringing the state back in. Cambridge [Cambridgeshire] ; New York : Cambridge University Press. Stallings, Barbara 1992. “International Influence on Economic Policy: Debt, Stabilization, and Structural Reform“ in Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman, eds. The Politics of economic adjustment : international constraints, distributive conflicts, and the state Princeton, N.J. : Princeton University Press Valenzuela, Arturo 1978. The breakdown of democratic regimes. Baltimore : Johns Hopkins University Press. 23 Wibbels, Erik 2006. 2006. “Dependency Revisited: International Markets, Business Cycles, and Social Spending in the Developing World,” International Organization 60, 2 (Spring): 433–68. 24