A CASE FOR PHASING OUT THE SUBSIDY ELEMENT: PETROLEUM PRODUCTS, FOOD AND FERTILISERS: A STUDY FOR THE TWELFTH FINANCE COMMISSION BY: Prof. K.S. RAMACHANDRAN Economist & Author Research & Editorial support: Ms. Y. Vijayasri Secretarial Assistance: Mr. K.M. Sinha 1 SL. NO. CHAPTERS 1. Chapter I 2. CONTENTS PAGE No. Terms of Reference 3 Chapter II A Study Outline 4 Chapter II B A Critique of ERC Report 11 Chapter II C The Agenda for end March, 2010 16 3. Chapter III About the Author 19 4. Chapter IV Subsidy Phase-out 20 5. Chapter V The Petroleum Sector 23 6. Chapter VI Food Subsidy 31 7. Chapter VII Fertiliser Subsidy 50 8. Chapter VIII Safety net concepts as evolved by the World Bank 64 9. Chapter IX Subsidies – The International Experience 66 10. Chapter X From Reports of Earlier Finance Commissions 84 11. Chapter XI From Earlier Studies on Central Subsidies 85 12. Chapter XII Winding up 103 2 TERMS OF REFERENCE OF STUDY ON EXPLICIT SUBSIDIES ON PETROLEUM PRODUCTS, FOOD AND FERTILISERS (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) Trends in explicit subsidies given by Central Government. Rationale for subsidies with an analysis of the pros and cons of identification of particular goods for grant of subsidies. International practice in regard to subsidies. Recommendations of the Expenditure Reforms Commission (ERC) on each of the explicit subsidies and the extent of their implementation. Impact of the modification made by the Government while accepting the ERC’s recommendations along with a quantification of the same in terms of the financial implications thereof. Analysis of the methodology and criteria for determination of the quantum of each subsidy. Targeting of subsidies and achievement in this regard – evaluation studies, if any, undertaken in this regard, conclusions thereof and the action thereon. Fertiliser subsidy – advantages of the new pricing policy and its impact on target groups. Extent to which the subsidy has been able to achieve the stated objectives. Whether the new policy has adequate incentives for efficiency. Reforms required in fertiliser subsidy to ensure better targeting and phasing out. Food subsidy – Analysis of the present pattern of the subsidy and whether it meets the objectives as far as target groups are concerned. Feasibility of phasing out of the food subsidy or increasing efficiency through greater decentralization. Reform required in the manner of determination of Minimum Support Price. Road map for decentralization and quantification of its impact. Subsidy on petroleum products, its rationale and road map for its phasing out. Approach followed by earlier Commissions with regard to explicit subsidies. Reasons for the spurt in the level of subsidies in recent years, notwithstanding the views/recommendations expressed and assumptions made by the previous Finance Commissions on the subject. Road map for desirable policy initiatives in regard to subsidy reform. Suggested approach for the Twelfth Finance Commission in regard to explicit subsidies along with the suggestions on making projections of expenditure on account of subsidies during the award period of the Commission. (Rakesh Sharma) Deputy Director (Sectt-II) 15th December, 2003 3 (II A) STUDY OUTLINE A) (i) CORE ISSUES FOOD SUBSIDY a) Narrowing the focus of PDS to only the poorest of the poor – using the Antyodaya Anna Yojana as the basis. Marginalising the public procurement system over a five year period. Introducing a special scheme to take care of small and marginal farmers. b) Marginalising the FCI. c) Phasing out the system of statutory price fixation. d) Accepting the demand made by the developed countries at the forum of WTO for transparency over procurement price as well as operations, and voluntarily giving up the benefit of exclusion of PDS – for the purpose of farm subsidy reforms – available under WTO-related provisions on agriculture. e) The foodgrains stockpile must be reduced to the absolute minimum level necessary to take care of calamities, natural or man-made. Generally, the Government must adopt a policy of buying foodgrains from the open market or importing on an ad hoc basis to take care of emergency requirements. (ii) FERTILISER SUBSIDY I a) In regard to the producer component of it, the subsidy must get transformed into an efficiency booster and stop being used to reward inefficiency and to punish efficiency. 4 b) The unit-wise retention scheme for fertiliser pricing has given way to the group concession scheme, but the principle remains the same – rewarding de-merit and penalising merit. c) This has to change and the plants that cannot stand the real test of competition must be offered for sale to pave the way for their commercial rehabilitation or liquidation. d) Rising global fertiliser prices must stop being offered as a justification for pampering sick units like NFL. II Coming to the consumer component, a limited subsidy must be given but only to poor and small farmers. (iii) OIL SUBSIDY There should be no subsidy on LPG, effective March end, 2005, while subsidised kerosene must continue to be available only to the poorest of the poor – the population segment covered by the Antyodaya Anna Scheme. The principle of import parity prices must apply to all petroleum products. In regard to non-domestic category of LPG, there is a perfectly genuine case for subsidising the supply earmarked for poor hawkers and small shopkeepers. The latter should stop being treated on par with proven commercial users of LPG like hotels and restaurants. (iv) POVERTY CRITERION This must be strictly in terms of nutritional standards, not income. The time has come to differentiate between population that is deemed to be below the poverty line on the basis of income levels and those close to destitution. Subsidies must be targeted at the latter. In favouring nutritional standards, we must refuse to proceed on the basis that the poor, along with the better – off sections of the community are voluntarily 5 opting for low nutrition food articles. Indeed, if such is the consumer preference among people near the level of destitution, it is all the more reason why efforts towards poverty alleviation should focus sharply on propagating consumption of cheap goods but with the required level of calories. Table I Estimate of incidence of poverty in India Year Poverty ratio (%) Number of poor (million) Rural Urban Combined Rural Urban Combined 1973-74 56.4 49.0 54.9 261.3 60.0 321.3 1977-78 53.1 45.2 51.3 264.3 64.6 328.9 1983 45.7 40.8 44.5 252.0 70.9 322.9 1987-88 39.1 38.2 38.9 231.9 75.2 307.1 1993-94 37.3 32.4 36.0 244.0 76.3 320.3 1999-00 27.1 23.6 26.1 193.2 67.1 260.3 2007* 21.1 15.1 19.3 170.5 49.6 220.1 * Poverty projection for 2007 Source: Tenth Five Year Plan, Vol. 1, Planning Commission. B) EXPLAINING THE FOCUS With the Centre having formally committed itself, under the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management (FRBM) Act, to wiping out the revenue deficit by end March, 2008, a time bound plan of action has to be thought out to drastically contain the open (and acknowledged) subsidies – as well those that are hidden / implicit – of the Centre and simultaneously those of various state governments. A study sponsored by the 12th Finance Commission recommending an end to universal subsidies on food, fertilisers and petroleum products and its replacement by selective relief targeted exclusively to the economically weakest sections of the community should hasten fulfillment of this critical aspect of economic reform. The Commission is entirely justified in undertaking this task given the harsh reality of 85 to 90 percent of its constitutional non-plan revenue 6 transfers to states going towards funding the wage bill of the respective governments, and thereby leaving virtually no resources for developmental activities. By its sharp thrust on an effective reform of explicit subsidies, the Commission places itself in a position from where it can put a lot of pressure on policymakers as well as administrators at the Central as much as the state level to address clinically the removal of the massive subsidies that are hidden and go unacknowledged and unreported. The Commission would, thus, contribute to bringing to the limelight a long neglected part of the reform effort, the unfinished agenda. C) THE REAL PROBLEM: AN APPRAISAL While a major component of non-plan expenditure of the Central Government – defence – is outside the reform agenda and is more or less beyond the control of the administration, the other two, interest payments and subsidies, not only are controllable but also demand strong counter-action. In recent years, successive Finance Commissions have sought to weaken the internal debt trap – representing a situation, that emerged, according to RBI, in fiscal year 1991-92, where fresh market borrowings were sufficient merely to take care of the interest liabilities, unlike in the past when new loans had been raised in a somewhat mechanical fashion to pay off the old debts – by easing the indebtedness of state governments. In recent months, a plan involving use of additional market borrowing and small savings by state governments has emerged to facilitate retirement of high interest bearing debts and recourse to cheaper, new loans – benefiting thereby from the present low interest regime – and this should reduce the debt service burden for the present. Yet, this is no lasting solution to the fact that Central and state governments cannot any longer treat market borrowing as a net resource. This must receive serious attention in the light of the compelling demands of the FRBM Act. 7 Obviously, an efficient management of the economy and the fiscal regime duly reflected in (as well as by) a sharp reduction in open as well as hidden subsidies can (and should) soften the strains of debt servicing by facilitating normal (as against a contrived mechanism that is in force now) retirement of debts and by postponing new loans and also scaling these down. However, this is not the goal of the study undertaken. Here, I only seek to work out a feasible remedy to the mounting subsidies. The impact this will have is not going to be ignored, but this will get only passing notice. In regard to food, I propose to argue against an indefinite retention of the system of public procurement of foodgrains on the basis of a perpetually rising price structure as much as the continuation of an universal system of public distribution sustained by a truly massive stockpile. While the budget provision for this purpose (Rs.21,200 Crore during 2002-03 and Rs.27,800 Crore in 200304) is itself cause for considerable worry, what is even more disturbing is that procurement prices are raised arbitrarily over and above what are recommended by the requisite authority. More importantly, do we need a PDS targeted towards all? This is a question that concerns not only the Central and state governments but also constitutional bodies like the Finance Commission entrusted with the delicate task of outlining the distribution of the nation’s resources between the Centre and states and among the various states themselves. It is in the overall interest of sound national finances that a mechanism should come into being which provides easy and economical access to food to only the most needy among the nation’s population. The Antyodaya Anna Yojana should be strengthened to provide such access. Simultaneously, the system of public procurement and statutory price fixation must be phased out and a special scheme formulated for small and marginal farmers. On fertiliser, a subsidy amounting to around Rs.4,100 per tonne of urea sold to farmers is borne by the Government which added up to a total Rs.7004 crore for 8 2002-03 (B.E.). But, this is not all. The total subsidy was Rs.11,009 crore in 2002-03 (R.E.) and the budget estimate for 2003-04 has been Rs.12,720 crore. There are two aspects of the fertiliser subsidy: inefficient producers are rewarded even as indiscriminate or overuse of fertilisers is encouraged. Despite well over a decade of reform, efforts to introduce an element of discrimination in the distribution of subsidies have not made any significant headway. Here, the goal for the current Finance Commission would be to introduce a pricing mechanism that would help promote efficiency in fertiliser production and rid the industry of weak performers. The Commission cannot, obviously, accept an approach to disinvestments that shows undue haste – for the shortsighted fiscal reason of easing the strains on Central revenue – in respect of excellent players in the oil segment like BPCL and HPCL (held up by the Supreme Court though for entirely different reasons). It cannot also endorse the reluctance on disinvestments of poorly functioning fertiliser plants like NFL. The Government has replaced the unit-wise retention price scheme with the group concession scheme but this is only a compromise of sorts. That expediency is still the guiding factor emerges easily from the fact that the high price of fertiliser in the global market is being opportunistically used by the Government to paper over the operational weaknesses of domestic plants. The Commission must ask for a pricing policy that rewards efficient producers and expedites the exit of those consistently in the red. As regards price incentives to consumers, these must be limited to the small and marginal farmers only. Coming to petroleum products, with the Central subsidy projected at Rs.8,116 crore in 2003-04 (reduce to Rs. 6,300 crore in the revised estimate by passing on the burden to the petroleum companies), the interim budget for 2004-05 mooting a further reduction to Rs. 3,500 crore, again with the oil PSUs picking up the tabs, and the Minister for Petroleum having publicly declared that the subsidy in respect of cooking gas and kerosene would be retained till February 2007, a case has to be strongly made for doing away with the subsidy on cooking gas 9 altogether while keeping the subsidy on kerosene only in respect of the economically most vulnerable sections of the community. Policy-wise, we have accepted parity between international and domestic prices. This must be fully in force, subject to the essential softening needed for the economically weakest members of the community. The Commission must press for a poverty criterion that is free from undue tinkering. Since the income norm always threatens to become a populist instrument – with a former minister of the Delhi Government, demanding on the eve of the elections to the legislature, a hike for the purpose of PDS coverage – the Commission must stick to the nutritional norm as prescribed by the Lakdawala Committee constituted by the Planning Commission, with due allowance being made for the escalation in the cost of providing essential levels of nutrition. Every expert panel on subsidies has proceeded on the basis that subsidised access to fertilisers indiscriminately to all farmers, regardless of their economic status, was unavoidable in the interests of national self-sufficiency in foodgrains. This study contests this and argues for growers of foodgrains other than those in the small and marginal category absorbing the market cost of fertilisers along with all other farm costs calculated on the basis of market-determined prices. 10 (II B) A CRITIQUE OF ERC REPORT The recommendations of the Expenditure Reforms Commission on food and fertiliser subsidies and the Government’s follow-up action. 1. WHAT THE ERC WANTED a) Food Subsidy While the Expenditure Reforms Commission (ERC) had expressed strong views on food and fertiliser subsidies and advocated drastic changes in the Governments’ approach, the official response has been one of neglect – even repudiation – in respect of various matters bearing on food subsidy and tokenism on issues of fertiliser pricing. The ERC wanted a food security buffer stock of six million tonnes of rice and flour million tonnes of wheat only (as against the present stockpile of 30 million tonnes of rice and 40 million tonnes of wheat). The Commission’s assessment of the average stock needed for managing the PDS was only seven million tonnes annually. The ERC had put the total average stock necessary at 24 million tonnes. The fact that the total stockpile of foodgrains (rice and wheat) presently is 70 million tonnes is nothing but a repudiation of the Commission’s wisdom. The Commission’s demand for a freeze of the Minimum Support Price (MSP) for wheat and paddy was also rejected. The Commission had been critical of excess stocks and, even more so, of what it called the “very generous” MSP-based procurement policy. It pointed out that the elimination of buffer stocks would itself lead to a saving of Rs. 1,300 crore (at 2000-01 MSP obviously) annually by way of carrying costs. This saving will be more at 2004-05 MSP. The Commission was concerned about leakages in the PDS and demanded a concerted effort to target the subsidies to the poorest of the poor. This concern has also been ignored. In a bitter attack 11 on the system of support prices, this august body noted that the minimum support price was, in fact, becoming the maximum support price and that the FCI had become the buyer of the first resort instead of being the buyer of the last resort as it should be. It advocated moderation of the annual increase in price as a step towards bringing in state governments and the private sector back into the picture. The Commission wanted the Government to announce in advance that in the event of a drop in foodgrains production in any year it would resort to imports to meet the requirements. The Expenditure Commission duly acknowledged that the cost of holding stocks in excess of food security and PDS requirements could appropriately be called the producers subsidy as it was the direct off-shoot of price support based procurement operations. It wanted “the cost of holding these stocks to be considered a subsidy to the producers and reflected as such in the budget”. This has been overlooked by the Government. The Commission, no doubt, did not seek to narrow down the ambit of PDS to a critical sub-sector of the poorest strata of population but its calculations on the average stock necessary signalled a narrowed thrust of the PDS. The Government did not heed this signal also. The Commission asked for changes in the calculation of the economic costs. This also has been ignored. b) Fertiliser Subsidy Coming to fertiliser subsidy, the Commission recommended the dismantling of the control system in a phased manner, leading at the commencement of the fourth stage, (1/4/2004) to a decontrolled fertiliser industry, which can compete with import, albeit with a small level of protection and a feedstock cost differential compensation to naphtha / LNG based units to ensure selfsufficiency. The transition, however, was to be gradual. The transition was to begin with the discontinuation of the RPS with effect from February 1, 2001 and introduction of a group wise concession scheme. The number of groups was to 12 be reduced from five to two by April 1, 2006. At that stage all units except those based on naphtha / LNG were expected to be viable at the price of about Rs. 7,000 per tonne of urea. For naphtha / LNG-based units, a Feedstock Differential Cost Reimbursement (FDCR) of Rs. 1,900 per tonne of urea was to be given. The Government responded to this recommendation by deciding that by the end of the eighth pricing period of the RPS on March 31, 2003, a new pricing policy for urea units based on the ERC package would come into effect. After the commencement of stage I and also beyond stage II, there was to be neither any reimbursement of the investment made by a unit for improvement in operations nor any mopping of the gains of the units as a result of operational efficiency. The declared goal of the changed fertiliser policy was to promote efficiency in production through measures of cost saving and efficient economic practices at par with international norms by the domestic urea producers. A beginning was also made towards greater decontrol and liberalisation. Allocation of urea under the Essential Committee Act, 1955 was limited to 75 and 50 per cent of the installed capacity (as re-assessed) of each unit in kharif 2003 and rabi 2003-04 respectively. Thereafter, the units are free to sell the balance urea at the designated MRP. During stage II commencing April 1, 2004, urea distribution is to be totally decontrolled after an evaluation of the performance in stage I. The ERC noted, “The fertiliser policy needs to be reformed. The goal of the new policy should eventually be to bring fertiliser prices charged to farmers to the level of the import parity price. It should protect small farmers’ real incomes, but not lead to a slump in food production and also promote a balanced use of N, P and K.” However, the Commission acknowledged, “A sudden increase in farm-gate of urea to import parity price, without increasing procurement prices, could lead to a fall of 13.5 million tonnes of foodgrains production. This, thus, is 13 not a feasible option”. The Commission pointed out, “if procurement prices are raised along with farm-gate prices of fertilisers, the fall would be much smaller”. 2. WHAT THE ERC FAILED TO SAY The Commission wanted to protect the small and marginal farmers, “for whom self-consumption is a large part of their output” and who “would suffer a loss in their real incomes”. The Commission, obviously, was in a dilemma whether to avert a possible fall in foodgrains production or cut the fertiliser subsidy. Ultimately, it let itself be guided by the expert view that a hike in the real price of fertiliser would lead to a decline in fertiliser consumption and, thereby, in foodgrains production. Significantly, the NIPFP study by Prof. D.K. Srivastava and Dr. Tapas K. Sen (1997) cited an estimate made in 1991 by Sidhu & Sidhu that a 30 per cent hike in the real price of fertiliser would lead to a 18 per cent decline in fertiliser consumption, and thereby, a 5.4 per cent fall in foodgrains production. This must have weighed heavily with ERC. Otherwise, how can one explain the recommendation that all cultivator households should be given 120 kgs of fertiliser at subsidised prices? No doubt, large farm holders would have found the concessional supply grossly inadequate and would have had to buy much of their requirement outside the concessional scheme. But then, fertiliser is heavily underpriced as per calculations by the Fertiliser Association of India. These are as follows: Farmer Subsidy = Farm Gate Cost of imported fertiliser minus the price paid by the farmer multiplied by the quantum of fertiliser consumed Producer Subsidy = Budget allocation minus farmer subsidy 14 Notified Cost (Maximum Retail Price) of Urea : Rs. 4,830 per tonne Farm Gate cost of imported urea (Delivered cost) (CFR – cost of freight) = $ 200 – Rs. 9,000/- per tonne dealer’s margine Rs. 180/- handling charge Rs. 1,200/__________ Rs. 10,380/__________ Indigenous price = Average cost of indigenous urea = Rs. 9,000/- per tonne Producer subsidy is, therefore, negative (minus Rs. 1,380/- per tonne) 15 (II C) THE AGENDA FOR END MARCH, 2010 In response to the Finance Commission’s D.O.NO.TFC-12025/14 – 10154 of 5/4/2004 1. FOOD SUBSIDY To be targeted only to two crore households covered by the Antyodaya Anna Yojana: As of 1/4/2005 :Rs. 6,300 crore – based on a monthly supply of 35 kgs wheat and rice per household at an average price of Rs. 2.50 per kg. The explanation is provided in Chapter – VI. As of 31/3/2010 :Rs. 6,300 crore Assumptions: 1) Coverage under the Antyodaya Anna Yojana 2 crore families. 2) The average price of wheat and rice of Rs. 2.50 per kg 3) Monthly supply of 35 kgs of wheat. These assumptions represent no change from 1/4/2005, consistent with the discipline on subsidy that is necessary for fiscal rectitude. While a higher price, a lower quantity supplied under the yojana and a reduced coverage should have been projected, if only fiscal discipline had remained an exclusive goal, this has been eschewed in the light of the concern voiced by the 12th Finance Commission for the most needy and deserving segments of the population. In Chapter-VI, reference has been made to the interest charged on credit provided to FCI for food procurement and to the subsidy element in interest rate relief given to the Corporation. Given the imperative of reining in subsidies, 16 explicit as well as implicit, the 12th Finance Commission should recommend that the interest charged on food procurement credit should be on par with FCI’s credit rating based on its collateral and not because it is a PSU. 2. OIL SUBSIDY The subsidy on LPG should be removed effective 1/4/2005. There should be no subsidy on LPG supply on 31/3/2010. On kerosene, as discussed in Chapter-V the total subsidy on supply under PDS to 6.05 crore BPL families would out to Rs. 2,178 crore. This must be narrowed to 2 crore households covered by the Antyodaya Anna Yojana. On the basis of a subsidy of Rs. 3 per litre of kerosene and a supply under PDS of 10 litres every month, the annual subsidy for 2 crore Antyodaya Anna Yojana families work out to Rs.720 crore. We propose retention of this arrangement as of March 31, 2010, again consistent with the worry voiced by the Commission over the most needy and deserving of the population. 3. FERTILISER SUBSIDY The ERC was concerned about the small and marginal farmers but this was out weighed by fears of foodgrains production falling because of reduced fertiliser consumption. As I mentioned earlier (under the Chapter II B, “A Critique of ERC”), the Commission recommended a concessional supply to all farm households. My calculations in the same chapter show a negative producer subsidy and a consumer subsidy that is more than half the landed cost of imports of urea. Logically, since small and marginal farmers do not have a role in national food security (they generally produced only for self-consumption) there can be no case for extending the preferential treatment to the economically weaker strata recommended in regard to food and oil subsidies to fertiliser. The ERC was committed to total decontrol of urea distribution during stage II starting April 1, 2004. Consistent with this, there can be no rationale for 17 retention of the user subsidy in the case of fertiliser. The 12 th Finance Commission should assume an end to the subsidy by end March, 2010. 18 (III) ABOUT THE AUTHOR Mr. K.S. Ramachandran has served as Senior Consultant, Indian Council for Research in International Economic Relations (ICRIER), Senior Editor, Financial Express, Secretary, Steel Furnace Association of India, Director of Research & Publications, Institute of Cost & Works Accountants of India and Senior Research Assistant, National Atlas Organisation. He was also associated with the Institute of Management Technology, Ghaziabad as Chief, Project Research Work and had besides held the Fellowship of the Institute of Advanced Studies and the Geographical Society of India. Mr. Ramachandran has authored over 40 books as well as research studies. Some of his works are: Capital Mirage (1988), Inflation: Critical Issues (1991), Power of Motivation (1993), Challenge of Fiscal Management (1995), Subsidies: Piercing the Veil (1997), Development Under Transition (1999), Managing Global Economic Reform (2001), Managerial Challenges in Banking (2002), Politics of Economics & Economics of Politics (2002) and India Incorporated – The Missing Link (2003). One more book, “India Farm Inc.: A Realistic Agenda?” will be out shortly and another, “Rural uplift: From Government to Corporates” is to follow. He brought out six research studies for the Institute of Management Technology. 19 (IV) SUBSIDY PHASE-OUT: WHY THE FINANCE COMMISSION SHOULD DO THIS: THE DEMANDS OF THE COMMISSION’S OWN AGENDA In pursuance of the provisions of Article 280 of the Indian Constitution and those of the Finance Commission (miscellaneous provisions) Act 1951, the Twelfth Finance Commission was constituted. The Commission is mandated to make recommendations on the distribution of the divisible pool of net proceeds of taxes between the Union and the states and the allocation between the states of such proceeds, principles governing grants-in-aid of the revenues of the states out of the Consolidated Fund of India and grants under Article 275 of the Constitution and the measures needed to augment the consolidated fund of a state to supplement the resources of panchayats and municipalities. The Commission is required to review the state of finances of the Union and states and to suggest a plan by which the governments collectively and severally may bring about a restructuring of public finances, restoring budgetary balances, achieving macro-economic stability and debt structuring along with equitable growth. Besides, the Commission has to review the fiscal reforms facility introduced by the Central Government on the basis of the recommendations of the Eleventh Finance Commission and suggest measures for effective achievement of its objective. The agenda set for the Commission is such that a tough process of time-bound de-subsidisation is implicitly laid down. It is obvious that this constitutional body has been entrusted with the authority to incorporate a specific plan for phasing out the explicit subsidies on petroleum products, food and fertilisers in its recommendations, and, in doing so, put the nation firmly on course towards minimisation of the implicit subsidies as well. In fact, subsidy reforms are mandated to be built into the computation of the divisible pool and its distribution between the Centre and states and among the different states 20 effective April 01, 2005. The quenquennial period ending March 03, 2010 should be a critical phase of the reform effort with subsidies cut to the bare minimum. The various projections must be subject to subsidies (open and declared) being progressively brought down from April 01, 2005 onward, with the end of fiscal year 2009-2010 marking the minimisation – to the barest level and targeted only the most needy as well as the most deserving – of the subsidy burden. Table II Aggregate Expenditure of the Centre 2003-04 (BE) 2002-03 (BE) 1 Total Expenditure (1+2=3+4) 1. Non-Plan Expenditure 2 4,38,795 (16.0) 3,17,821 (11.6) 3 4,04,013 (16.3) 2,89,924 (11.7) Interest Payments 1,23,223 (4.5) 65,300 (2.4) 49,907 (1.8) 1,20,974 (4.4) 3,66,227 (13.3) 72,568 (2.6) of which Defence Subsidies 2. Plan Expenditure 3. Revenue Expenditure 4. Capital Expenditure RE: Revised Estimates Note: Figures in brackets are percent of GDP. 21 (Rupees Crore) Variation (2 over 3) Amount percent 4 5 34,782 8.6 27,897 9.6 1,15,663 7,560 (4.7) 56,000 9,300 (2.3) 44,618 5,289 (1.8) 1,14,089 6,885 (4.6) 3,41,648 24,579 (13.8) 62,365 10,203 (2.5) BE: Budget Estimates. 6.5 16.6 11.9 6.0 7.2 16.4 Table III Central Expenditure on Subsidies by Major Heads Year 1 1990-91 Food 2 2,450 (0.4) 2,850 (0.4) 2,800 (0.4) 5,537 (0.6) 5,100 (0.5) 5,377 (0.5) 6,066 (0.4) 7,900 (0.5) 9,100 (0.5) 9,434 (0.5) 12,060 (0.6) 17,499 (0.8) 24,200 (1.0) 27,800 (1.0) Fertiliser Interest Petroleum 3 4 5 4,389 379 0 (0.8) (0.1) 1991-92 5,185 316 0 (0.8) (0.1) 1992-93 6,136 113 0 (0.8) 1993-94 5,079 113 0 (0.6) 1994-95 5,769 76 0 (0.6) 1995-96 6,735 34 0 (0.6) 1996-97 7,578 1,222 0 (0.6) (0.1) 1997-98 9,918 78 0 (0.7) 1998-99 11,596 1,434 0 (0.7) (0.1) 1999-2000 13,244 1,371 0 (0.7) (0.1) 2000-01 13,800 111 0 (0.7) 2001-02 12,595 210 0 (0.5) 2002-03 (RE) 11,009 765 6,265 (0.4) (0.3) 2003-04 (BE) 12,720 179 8,116 (0.5) (0.3) RE: Revised Estimates. BE: Budget Estimates. Note: Figures in brackets are percent of GDP. Table IV Central Subsidies (April-September 2003) April - September Subsidies 2003 2002 Food 16,006 11,595 Urea 5,576 3,916 Decontrolled fert. 1,126 1,246 Petroleum 3,730 Total subsidies 26,495 16,751 * Net direct tax collections 38,758 32,674 * Refunds 18,633 13,978 * April to October 22 (Rupees crore) Total Subsidies 7 12,158 (2.1) 12,253 (1.9) 10,824 (1.4) 11,605 (1.4) 11,854 (1.2) 12,666 (1.1) 15,499 (1.1) 18,540 (1.2) 23,593 (1.4) 24,487 (1.3) 26,838 (1.3) 31,207 (1.4) 44,618 (1.8) 49,907 (1.8) Others 6 4,940 (0.9) 3,902 (0.6) 1,775 (0.2) 876 (0.1) 909 (0.1) 520 633 644 1,463 (0.1) 438 867 903 2,379 (0.1) 1,092 - % Change 38 42.3 -9.6 58 18.6 33.3 (Rs. Crore) (V) THE PETROLEUM SECTOR A major step forward in reforms in the petroleum sector was the dismantling of the Administrated Pricing Mechanism (APM) on April 1, 2002. Under the amended regime: (i) the pricing of indigenous crude oil and petroleum products, except for PDS kerosene and domestic LPG, were to be market–determined. The oil pool account and the oil coordination committee were to be wound up. (ii) Subsidies on PDS kerosene and domestic LPG were put on a specified flat rate basis on April 1, 2002, to be covered by the Consolidated Fund of India. These were to be phased out in 3 to 5 years from the date of termination of APM. As long as the subsidies were in force, after adjusting the flat rate of subsidy, the retail prices of PDS kerosene and domestic LPG were to fluctuate in accordance with the price of crude oil in international markets (iii) PDS kerosene and domestic LPG supplied in far flung areas were to get a freight subsidy (iv) The private sector was to be allowed to market transportation fuels subject to specified guidelines and (v) There was to be a regulator in place to oversee the downstream petroleum sector. However, it is very doubtful if the crucial part of the reform – the phase out of the subsidy on PDS kerosene and domestic LPG between 2005 and 2007 – is really on. The Union Cabinet when it met in September, 2003 did not declare itself on the phase out date. Contrary to the Petroleum Minister, Mr. Ram Naik’s claim that the deadline was set at March, 31, 2007, the Cabinet had only okayed the Ministry’s proposal that the oil companies be directed to share the increase in subsidies instead of hiking the retail prices of both LPG and kerosene. For the record, the Finance Ministry early in 2003 had told the Petroleum Department that although the Cabinet had approved a time frame of three to five years for the subsidy phase out, the actual implementation would be in three years’ time i.e., by 2004-05. The combined subsidy had been projected at Rs.4,495.8 crore 23 for 2002-03. With the spurt in crude prices in October, 2002, the Finance Ministry approved a flat subsidy rate of Rs.67.75 per cylinder for LPG and Rs.2.45 per litre in kerosene. This was later reduced to Rs. 45.17 per cylinder of LPG and Rs. 1.64 per litre of kerosene. Despite the outgo being estimated at around Rs.2,200 crore, no extra provision had been made in the revised estimate for 2002-03. In the 2003-04 budget, a provision of Rs.8,116 crore was made. This was reduced to Rs. 6,300 crore in the revised estimate, with the oil PSUs sharing the burden. In the interim budget for 2004-05, the provision is Rs. 3,500 crore, again with the public sector petroleum companies accepting an enhanced share of the subsidy burden. However, there was a freeze of LPG and kerosene prices in September 2003, for a year. A Committee was set up soon after to work out the modalities of subsidy-sharing between oil producing and marketing firms as well as look into the losses accruing from the price freeze in the face of rising costs. Clearly, the intention was to hold down the fiscal subsidy. One obvious option in the burdensharing mechanism was that two-thirds of the cost could be borne jointly by the Oil and Natural Gas Commission, the Oil India Limited – the two upstream producing firms – and by the Indian Oil Corporation Limited, Hindustan Petroleum Corporation Limited and Bharat Petroleum Corporation Limited – the downstream retailing companies – with the balance being made up by way of margins on other petroleum products. Another was that the costs could be divided equally between the Oil & Natural Gas Commission, the Oil India Limited and the Gas Authority of India Limited on the one hand and the Indian Oil Corporation Limited, Indo-Burma Petroleum (IBP) the Bharat Petroleum Corporation Limited and the Hindustan Petroleum Corporation Limited on the other. Recently, there have been other policy developments that were no less grave. The Union Cabinet put off at its meeting on January 7, 2004 a proposal by a ministerial panel to raise natural gas prices by Rs. 350 per thousand cubic 24 metres – a move that would have, no doubt, pushed up the prices of cooking gas, fertiliser and electricity as well as auto, bus and taxi fares. When the Government in September 2003 announced a freeze of LPG and kerosene prices for a year, it was not wanting in concern over the fiscal repercussions. But by passing the buck on to the oil sector PSUs, it was only papering over the cracks. Even as Dr. C. Rangarajan, Chairman of the 12 th Finance Commission pressed for hard decisions at the conference on “Issues before the 12th Finance Commission” held on September 28, 2003, and referred pointedly to the ‘distant’ target of reducing the Central revenue deficit to one percent by 2004-05 and the overall deficit to 6.5 percent set by the Eleventh Finance Commission, the oil PSUs were being asked to bail out the Centre for an indefinite period. Reliance was kept out of this arrangement as it bought crude at import parity prices from ONGC and sold LPG to oil marketing companies at import parity prices. For the future also, things are going to be tough on oil PSUs, with pressure mounting on the oil marketing companies to take a hit on the marketing margins on petrol and diesel. Knowing that private players in the oil sector like Shell, Essar and Reliance can never be dictated to in that fashion, any squeeze on margins on products like petrol and diesel (which have risen from Rs. 250 to Rs.950 a kilolitre, following the dismantling of the administered price regime) to keep the petro subsidies out of the budget will not only make a mockery of deregulation of the petroleum sector but also defeat a major priority of the 12th Finance Commission – instilling true discipline into fiscal policy and management. The confirmation on October 8, 2003 by the Union Petroleum Minister that the IOC, HPCL, BPCL and IBP would together lose Rs. 8,300 crore during 2003-04 because of not hiking domestic cooking gas and kerosene prices despite the rise in cost was virtually a declaration of defiance targeted not only against the Indian Parliament that had, after a lot of persuasion, adopted the Fiscal 25 Responsibility Bill but also the Twelfth Finance Commission entrusted, as part of its constitutional duties, with the task of injecting the much needed restraint in the management of Central and state finances. International price parity would have meant pushing up the LPG price by Rs.105 per cylinder and the kerosene price by Rs.3 per litre. Even with a Government subsidy of Rs.45.17 per cylinder of LPG (this is to be extended to private sector companies on par with the PSUs, Indian Oil Corporation, IBP, Bharat Petroleum Corporation and Hindustan Petroleum Corporation) and Rs. 1.64 per litre of kerosene, oil companies are selling LPG at Rs.105 per cylinder below the cost and kerosene at Rs. 3 per litre below the cost. The agenda of the Twelfth Finance Commission stands to suffer with this continuing act of expediency. In respect of LPG, large investments were made after it was put on OGL in the hope that a commercial return would make good the investment. No investor could have anticipated the kind of situation that emerged subsequently of continuing subsidies on the one hand and large scale diversions of domestic LPG to non-domestic establishments on the other. No investment can be commercially worthwhile if the product is vastly under-priced. There can be no raison det’re for LPG being heavily subsidised for consumers from the affluent sections of the community. The logic of excluding income tax payers from the facility of below cost supply of kerosene necessarily has to be extended to subsidised supply of LPG as well. There can be no escape from this if the Commission is to be able to make possible a meaningful distribution of resources between the Centre and the states and among the various states themselves. Apart from critical questions of good fiscal management, there can be no room in a reforming economy for goods in short supply – and paid for in foreign exchange and on terms that are fully dictated by market conditions – being kept open for ready access at prices that are not just consumer-friendly but reflect undue pampering. While the Government itself shells out market prices to ensure easy availability, it makes 26 for a sound economic policy to treat the consumer – unless he or she is economically depressed – likewise, with a pricing policy that the market legitimately demands. The Government should stop asking oil producers and retailers to take on the burden and assuming in the process that it has taken care of this part of the subsidy problem. With consumption and demand mounting, the subsidy element will only grow and, going by the present dispensation, the margins of the oil PSUs will progressively fall, precisely at a time when private competition is emerging strongly. It is true that unlike earlier oil producers in the oil sector will share the burden with the marketing PSUs, but the fact to be faced is that private rivals like Reliance which take crude from the ONGC at import-parity prices will remain free to sell LPG to the oil marketing outfits in the public sector again at import parity prices, and not on the same subsidised terms that the latter themselves have to supply to the consumer. The debate over the delay in disinvestment is not entirely futile when we consider that the two concerned PSUs, the Hindustan Petroleum Corporation Limited and the Bharat Petroleum Corporation Limited would be enjoying a level playing field with Reliance if only the Supreme Court had not stood in the way. While the fiscal fall-out is by no means negligible, the reasoning that is being advanced that with their huge profits, the oil companies can take care of the burden on the (not so) common man is truly preposterous. This is populism that, obviously, is justified on electoral grounds, but runs entirely counter to the mechanics that the 12th Finance Commission is quite rationally pressing for. There is really no valid basis to justify the subsidy, all the more one that is targeted indiscriminately towards that strata of the nation’s population which can very well afford to pay the globally dictated market price. The amount of oil subsidy could, indeed, turn out to be quite staggering by the targeted deadline for re-focusing the subsidy on kerosene and LPG to the poorest of the poor if 27 only we leave out the impact of the Government’s expedient transfer of the burden to the oil producing and retailing companies in the public sector. This alone would do to justify the targeting of the subsidy on LPG as well as PDS kerosene to the people covered by the Antyodaya Anna Scheme as against the present system of support for those coming under the BPL category in respect of kerosene and the universal subsidisation of LPG supply. A distinction is also necessary between a poor hawker or a small shopkeeper and a rich non-domestic user of cooking gas. Knowing that nondomestic LPG is very expensive, there should be no parity between a poor commercial user and others like hotels and restaurants. The 12 th Finance Commission, obviously, would not recommend ways to ensure making heavily subsidised domestic LPG available to the poorest of the poor, but it would certainly see that there is a substantial price reduction for the supply of nondomestic LPG to poor hawkers and small traders. A much stronger case can be legitimately made for the narrowed focus in defence of the essence of deregulation, which should demand a total commitment to the dismantling of the Administered Price Mechanism (APM) on April, 1, 2002 on the one hand and parity in the treatment of oil PSUs and private oil companies on the other. The entire subsidy could be brought down to a fiscally manageable order of Rs. 720 crore. The accompanying statement explains the calculation of the saving. THE EXPLANATORY STATEMENT The beneficiaries of the Antyodaya Anna Scheme: Total number of households on the verge of destitution: 1.5 crore, effective April 1, 2003 The targeted public distribution system (TPDS) covers 6.05 crore below poverty line (BPL) families. The total subsidy on TPDS kerosene supplied to BPL families works out to as follows: 28 Rs. 3 per litre for 6.05 crore families or Rs.18.15 crore for supply of kerosene of one litre to each of these families. On the basis that annually 120 litres are sold to every BPL household, – with a strength of 5 members – (the five member household norm is assumed consistent with the austerity on family welfare demanded for purposes of subsidy management) the total subsidised sale every year works out to 780 crore litres for all the 6.05 crore BPL families together. At Rs.3 per litre, the combined subsidy bill is of a staggering order, Rs.2,178 crore. PDS sale of kerosene is closed to income tax payers as well as those households with access to LPG supply. One must presume that the beneficiaries of the Antyodaya Anna Scheme are so poor that they rely only marginally on PDS kerosene supply and also that their economic vulnerability cannot legitimately permit LPG connections. Among the remaining segments of the BPL households also, it would be rational to assume that only a few use cooking gas since even the heavily subsidised price could be beyond their limited means. Here, it is a moot question – whether the Antyodaya Anna households do have to be provided PDS kerosene as well as LPG at still more concessional prices. While it may seem harsh to decide in favour of retaining only the availability of PDS kerosene and leaving out provision of still cheaper (in terms of energy used) LPG for those coming under the Antyodaya Anna Scheme, such an omission is justified in the overall context of economic discipline. Admittedly, the human face cannot be allowed to become much too human. LPG prices should be allowed to rise as per the diktat of the April 1, 2002 reform. As for PDS kerosene, this facility must be confined only to the 2 crore households and be shut out for the remaining 4.05 crore BPL families coming under TPDS. This should minimise the total oil sector subsidy to a level (Rs. 720 crores annually) where there will be no need for the Government to tax the oil PSUs, leaving the latter to enjoy a level playing field with the private sector players in this sector. The 12th Finance Commission would want such parity since the margins that the public sector get 29 on their sales consequent on the closure of the ARM would be duly reflected in enhanced tax revenue to the Government and, thereby, in a larger divisible pool. 30 (VI) FOOD SUBSIDY There is an equal justification, if not more, for the food subsidy to be focused on the most needy among the poor – those coming under the Antyodaya Anna Yojana. The reform, in fact, must go deeper than this. The foodgrain stockpile must be gradually minimised to the level needed to take care of the Antyodaya Anna Yojana beneficiaries and emergencies. The procurement scheme must be phased out, so should the system of statutory fixation of farm goods prices, and as for the small and marginal farmers they should be helped out through a limited price support policy, financed by a small subsidy, with the whole operation being confined only to a few selected mandis. Such a policy can be extended to the main as well as supplementary crops, provided there are safeguards against misuse. The cost of the facility of subsidised supply of rice/wheat to 1.5 crore beneficiaries (household) of Antyodaya Anna Yojana annually can be projected at Rs. 4,725 crores. This will go up to Rs. 6,300 crore during 2004-05 with the beneficiaries of the scheme being raised to two crore household effective April 1, 2004. The process is explained as follows: During WTO negotiations on farm subsidy reduction, transparency in public procurement operations has justifiably received some attention. India has to be explicit on the major beneficiaries of the procurement price/support mechanism. Clearly, if farm subsidies in the European Community and the United States have to go over a limited time frame, then India must also get ready to phase out procurement as well as price support and limit these facilities only to the economically vulnerable among growers. It would be logically acceptable to pick out crop producers among families in the BPL and APL (above poverty line) categories for this benefit. How do we segregate the producer segment? We can, with reason, leave out farmers who are covered by the Antyodaya Anna Scheme on the presumption that their proximity to a condition of destitution would rule out their meaningful occupation even as small/marginal farmers. 31 Presently, the subsidy incurred on the supply of foodgrains through the PDS at below FCI’s economic cost constitutes the consumer subsidy, while the producer subsidy is the direct offshoot of the price supportbased procurement operations of the Government. The producer subsidy together with the cost of maintaining the buffer stock accounts for the cost of buffer stock operations. The consumer subsidy together with the buffer carrying cost constitute the food subsidy. This has to be narrowed on the lines suggested here. In this context, reference must be made to the recommendations of the Johl Committee set up by the Punjab Government, particularly that if one million hectares of land is switched from wheat and rice to other crops there will be a cut in subsidy of Rs.3,800 crore. In the event of a third of this amount going to foodgrain growers in Punjab alone by way of an incentive not to cultivate wheat and rice, the national subsidy on foodgrains would be less by Rs.3,800 crore annually. The Central Food Ministry recently adopted a non-populist posture about continued public procurement of foodgrains being the villain in subsidy growth. Addressing the 63rd Annual General Meeting of the Roller Flour Mills Association of India on September 27, 2003, the Minister in charge, Mr. Sharad Yadav rhetorically conceded – but without obviously meaning it, as, we will see later – that the monopolisation of the procurement operations by the Central and state government agencies had institutionalised inefficiency and pointed out that private sector participation in procurement and, not just storage and movement, of foodgrains, would not only cut the overall food subsidy bill but also improve the quality of wheat for the milling units. But, the political realities are such that the proclaimed villain in subsidy acceleration will remain and even gain added strength until the next Lok Sabha poll is over. The Ministry is conveniently entertaining fears of grain buffer stocks falling below the minimum required and even contemplating a ban on grain exports. Ironically, exports have been taking place hitherto on the basis of subsidised prices – even below BPL supply rates for 32 inferior varieties of wheat (This should rule out private purchases for grain export, a measure of liberalisation designed to put a stop to the system of FCI sale to exporters at less than the cost of public procurement. Even though the Government is moving towards WTO-compatible subsidies on par for both public and private procurement, exporters of grains are quite unlikely to give up the cushion that goes with FCI). Any meaningful reform package on subsidies should incorporate domestic market – determined prices for supplies within and global prices for export sales. Such a package, however, should rule itself out knowing the electoral compulsions, and it is left to the Twelfth Finance Commission to insist on an early adoption of the package. In this bleak scenario, what could really trigger the much needed reform in this respect is the growing support for contract farming, which could indeed form the basis of yet another green revolution. First launched in 1989 by Pepsi Co. in Hoshiarpur, Punjab in 1989 this is now the core of decentralisation efforts in key procurement states, possibly paving the way for substantial savings in foodgrains procurement. Recourse to liberalised land lease agreements and formation of land share companies through an amendment of the Companies Act have come up for serious consideration. With the Indian Tobacco Company’s efforts towards direct procurement of crops on the net – courtesy e-choupal initiative already having made substantial headway, there are others breaking into the farm economy and the list of corporates taking up farming is encouraging, if not staggering, Escorts, Graintec, Rallis, Pepsi Co, Mahindra and Mahindra and DCM Shriram. Such a measure of corporatisation is designed to facilitate growth of private procurement of commercially viable crops including foodgrains. When this takes place, support prices will inevitably be de-linked from state procurement. Krishi Bhawan, in projecting a truly stupendous scale of farm credit, Rs.7,36,570 crore, during the Tenth Plan period has given priority to financing of contract farming by the banking system. In a paper submitted for discussion at a workshop organised some time ago by the Rural Development 33 Institute, Seattle, the Ministry of Agriculture called for a paradigm shift from subsistence farming to market-oriented commercial agriculture, with the participation of industry and small and marginal land holders. It was explicit on the direction of reform: “Unless we promote contract farming (as opposed to corporate farming) and legalise land leasing, the much desired vertical integration leading to rural transformation is unlikely to come about in India”. Obviously, the 12th Finance Commission should not remain insensitive to people coming within the Antyodaya Anna Yojana, a scheme introduced on December, 25, 2000. Targeting one crore (and 50 lakhs more since April 1, 2003) poorest of the poor families coming under the Targeted Public Distribution System (TPDS) – a measure taken earlier to make PDS more focussed – under the scheme, the beneficiaries are provided 35 kg foodgrains per family monthly at a highly subsidised price of Rs. 2 per kg for wheat and Rs. 3 per kg for rice. The targeted population cannot and should not be left to the uncertain mercy of the free market. The Commission must endorse a scheme of continued protection to the poorest of the poor families and even tread cautiously on official claims on the success of poverty alleviation measures and take a close look at data implicitly or explicitly suggesting a drop in the number of people classified as the beneficiaries. The cost of maintaining this scheme is worked out as follows: Since April 1, 2003 the number of households covered by the scheme has risen to 1.5 crore. At a monthly rate of 35 kg, the annual supply is 420 kg/per family. At an average of Rs. 2.50 per kg of wheat and rice, the cost per family will be Rs. 1,050 every year. For the 1.5 crore beneficiaries of the Antyodaya Anna Yojana, the cost works out to Rs. 1,575 crore. This will rise to Rs. 2,100 crore with the number of households covered by the scheme rising to 2 crore effective April 1, 2004. Assuming an average market price of Rs. 10 per kg for both rice and wheat of the cheapest category, the cost will be four times what the beneficiaries pay, Rs. 8,400 crore. After deducting from this the payment made by 34 the beneficiaries, the cost to the Government on the scheme should be Rs. 6,300 crores. Compare this with the burden that the exchequer bears on behalf of all the people under the BPL coming within the purview of PDS numbering 6.05 crores and the APL (above poverty line) families on the one hand (this constitutes effectively the consumer subsidy) and the producer subsidy paid to wheat and paddy growers, equivalent to the total subsidy of Rs. 27,800 crore (the budget estimate for 2003-04). If we subsidise foodgrain supplies only to those coming within the Antyodaya Anna Yojana, we could save Rs. 23,075 crore during 2003-04 after deducting the net cost to the Government of Rs. 4,725 crore incurred on 1.5 crore households covered up to March 31, 2004. Since under reform the producer subsidy must be restricted only to small marginal farmers we could save considerably by ending the public procurement/support price mechanism in respect of the rich/middle income farmers. The Expenditure Reforms Commission in its report in 2000 assumed that the funds required to protect the small/marginal farmers would be 38.5 per cent of the total budget subsidy for fertilisers. In 1998-99, the Commission noted that there were about 105 million cultivator households in the country, of which, apparently, 40 million could have been classified as small/marginal farmers. What the latter produced should only be covered by public procurement / price support operations. The producer subsidy for 2002-03 for wheat was Rs. 137 per quintal (this is discussed with reference to the minimum support price (MSP) and cost concepts in Chapter-VI). The subsidy is defined as MSP minus C2 (includes all expenses in cash and kind incurred in production by the actual owner plus rent paid for leased land plus the imputed / value of family labour plus interest on the value of owned capital assets – excluding land – plus rental value of owned land – net of land revenue). Such generosity even the small and marginal farmers do not deserve. No wonder, the Expenditure Reforms Commission assailed the whole approach in these blunt words: “As the excess stocks are solely due to the very generous minimum support price-based procurement price policy 35 being followed by the Government the cost of holding these stocks could be considered a subsidy to the producers and reflected as such in the budget”. There has to be a review not only of the cost computation but also the costs forming the basis of MSP. All farm inputs must be market price-determined – fertiliser, irrigation water, electricity, diesel and credit – and these costs must be absorbed by the bigger growers. Rebates, if any, should be available only to small and marginal farmers. Imputation of costs demands a drastic re-appraisal and we should not have a situation where all manner of costs are thrown in under an expansive MSP. Discrimination must become the core of the food subsidy scheme. A strong line has to be taken also on non-food subsidies, direct as well as indirect. The Central package of market borrowings of Rs. 1,885 crore and soft loans bearing a rate of interest of four percent (with an initial moratorium of three years and repayable in three years) amounting to Rs. 678 crore totalling Rs. 2,563 crore to be provided to UP, Uttaranchal, Haryana, Punjab and Bihar to clear sugarcane arrears for 2002-03 must be strongly objected to. Maharashtra has maintained a monopoly cotton procurement scheme for no economically justifiable reason – the only concession the State Government has made to market reform has been the stoppage for the second consecutive year of payment of bonus over the minimum support price to cotton growers as fixed by the Centre – and, likewise, sugarcane growers have been pampered – and sugar mill managements harassed – leading to a pile of surplus stocks of sugar that is quite as irrational as the foodgrain stockpile. pampering. If food subsidies have to go so should all this The statutory minimum price for the sugarcane is itself quite generous to growers and unfair to sugar manufacturers and consumers. Yet, there was more generosity and greater unfairness by way of the states’ advised price (SAP). The Commission on Agricultural Costs & Prices (CACP) had recommended that the cane support price should be freezed, but the Centre chose to hike the price to Rs. 73 per quintal at a recovery rate of 8.5 percent for 36 2003-04 against Rs. 65.50 mooted for the last season. Rightly, the sugar mills have pressed for a freeze at Rs. 65.50 per quintal. The question has never been asked whether sugarcane should not yield place to other commercial crops like oilseeds as well as pulses, even in the face of a grim reminder of a severe glut in the 1978-79 sugarcane crushing season when retail prices had plunged to as low as Rs. 1.50 a kilo. Along with the food subsidy being phased out, the sugarcane regime must be brought down to earth – with a thud – and the Maharashtra monopoly cotton procurement scheme must exit as well. When a serious effort is on to divert wheat and paddy growing fields to other crops, this effort must include a similar treatment in respect of sugarcane and cotton (in Maharashtra) also. We cannot, obviously, have a situation where food subsidies are being addressed effectively while other aberrations are allowed to pass muster. The reform of food subsidy would be incomplete without the Government – Central and State – seeking not to maximise efficiency in the working of various poverty alleviation and employment-oriented schemes. The goal should be to minimise largesse in any form. It is true that in sharp contrast to floods whose impact is limited to one crop season, the adverse effect of drought is felt over three successive seasons until a good monsoon intervenes to normalize the crop cycle. The drought-affected people have to go through four months of the kharif season (July-October), followed by another four months of the rabi season (November-March) and lastly, the next four kharif months up to October. The various Yojanas are critical to the poor – and not the poorest of them alone – not turning into destitutes. No reform, however meaningful it is, can be blind to the harsh reality of poverty (Indeed, we would do well to remember that the BPL and APL population is only marginally better off than the segment covered by the AAY. Yet, for purposes of subsidy, only the poorest strata should be in focus). The known and acknowledged fact that the magnitude of poverty gets weakened with liberal – even indiscriminate – drought relief to the extent of some pockets of the population moving above the poverty line, 37 albeit temporarily, only underscores the gravity of poverty and, equally so, the imperative of well focused employment schemes against the backdrop of a time-bound action plan to narrow the ambit of the food subsidy. No reform can gloss over rural economic disparities. The revelation of the RBI rural debt and investment survey released in early 1977 that the assets of the richest in the rural milieu were 164 times those of the poorest is history all right, but we must remember that rural India has not turned egalitarian in the quarter of a century that has followed. Clearly, the various poverty alleviation and employment generation programmes have to be strengthened. These are: The Swarnajayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojana (SGSY), Sampoorna Grameen Rozgar Yojana (SGRY), Pradhan Mantri Gramodaya Yojana (PMGY), Pradhan Mantri Gramodaya Yojana (Gramin Awas), Pradhan Mantri Gramodaya Yojana-Rural Drinking Water Project, Pradhan Mantri Gram Sadak Yojana (PMGSY), Antyodaya Anna Yojana, Annapurna, Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY), Jai Prakash Rozgar Guarantee Yojana (JPRGY), Swarna Jayanti Shahari Rozgar Yojana (SJSRY) and Valmiki Ambedkar Awas Yojana (VAMBAY). Simultaneously, these schemes must be given a sharper edge. The offtake of foodgrains – wherever these are provided – must be improved, subject to thorough checks on utilisation. Such special schemes are: Annapurna, Earthquake, World Food Programme, Sampoorna Grameen Rozgar Yojana, Indigent People, Nutrition programme, Hostel SC/ST/OBC, food for work and mid-day-meal. Returning to the foodgrains stockpile, we must just keep enough supplies to take care of the needs of these schemes. We should remember that the buffer requirement was 16.8 million tonnes, while the actual stock as of January 2003 was 48.2 million tonnes (the level later was as much as 63 million tonnes). We do not have to go into the various measures taken to reduce the stocks over the last few years. What matters is that even as the stockpile is at an unmanageable level, more and more is being added at a huge cost to the Government. This 38 has to be truly liquidated and stocks must be kept only at a level needed to cater to the requirements of the various welfare schemes and the Antyodaya Anna Yojana (AAY) only. (The Expenditure Reforms Commission had called for a food security buffer stock comprising six million tonnes of rice and four million tonnes of wheat.) The latter, as we noted earlier, provides 35 kg of foodgrains per family per month at heavily subsidised prices. The offtake under the designated welfare schemes was 74.58 lakh tonnes only during 2002-03(up to December, 2003). Even in the event of all BPL (below poverty line) families continuing to be provided for, at 6.05 crore families (inclusive of two crore AAY families), the stocks needed would be well below the buffer stock norm of 16.8 million tonnes in January, 2003 and 15.8 million tonnes in April, 2003 (see Table VII, in Chapter-VI). The real villain is public procurement on an indiscriminate basis. This must stop. To start with, procurement must be confined to production by small and marginal farmers only. The stocks must be, in phases, brought down to the norm and then cut to the level needed for AAY families, also in phases. This could be completed in ten years starting April 1, 2004. After the conclusion of this period, only the AAY families should be targeted by PDS. As for procurement, the Government must stop price support/procurement operations from the Kharif season of 2004-05, starting July 2004. The PDS has long been used as a convenient excuse for price support/public procurement operations. This mockery must stop and India must go through the rigours of WTO’s regime of transparency on PDS. The temptation to circumvent the post – 1995 global trading discipline – by claiming that PDS for the poor could only be maintained with an indiscriminate public procurement of wheat and rice – must be stoutly resisted. But, all this would demand the strongest political will, which, unfortunately is not in evidence, judging by the Union Food Ministry’s plan to enhance public procurement of wheat and rice on the customary ground of production rising; the plan tells its own story and needs no elaboration. 39 Even as a strong case exists for drastically cutting the foodgrains stockpile and phasing out public procurement, the Centre remains firmly on course on retaining the massive stockpile and the subsidy. The Food Ministry, despite proclaiming its interest in private procurement, has projected for 2004-05 a public procurement of wheat of the order of 20 million tonnes (4.2 million tonnes more than in 2003-04) consistent with an estimated increase in production. As for rice, the procurement in 2003-04 is estimated at 22 million tonnes. The earlier position on Central stocks is truly alarming: 20.7 million tonnes of wheat and 7.12 million tonnes of rice, against a total buffer stocking norm of 15.8 million tonnes (April, 2003) (the opening stock of foodgrains as of June, 2003, as per the RBI annual report was 39.8 million tonnes). With an estimated procurement of 22 million tonnes of rice in the 2003-04 kharif season and 20 million tonnes of wheat in the rabi season of 2004-05, the stocks of rice and wheat could be 29 and 40 million tonnes respectively. The Centre had drawn up a plan of reducing the food subsidy by as much as Rs. 12,000 crore annually through a farm income insurance scheme. Since the insurance cost was estimated at Rs. 15,000 crore there should have been a saving of this order in the subsidy bill which is budgeted at Rs. 27,800 crore for 2003-04. Insurance was to be provided against any possible fall in the price of farm produce compared to the previous year, instead of the Government purchasing all the produce on the basis of full price support. This would be an ideal way of de-subsidisation but then, state governments have yet to fall in line with the Central proposal. The result was that the subsidy bill would have been of the staggering order budgeted, but for another act of policy intervention. One aspect of the food subsidy arrangement is the commercial bank credit provided to the FCI for food procurement operations. While as a PSU entrusted with the task of food security the FCI could claim a credit rating on par with triple A rated borrowers and secure its needs at a rate of interest of around 7 40 percent, the consortium of banks headed by the SBI has been charging a rate only marginally less than 11 percent (10.95) and in the process pushing up the food subsidy cost by nearly Rs. 1,800 crore. The Government earlier mooted a bond issue by the FCI and on January 9, 2004, it confirmed the arrangement – but less to help out FCI and more to help itself – by way of a cut of Rs. 2,000 crore in the food subsidy, in terms of an interest saving on the funding of FCI’s buffer. (The banks reduced the rate to 9.45 percent immediately thereafter, besides approving a bond issue by FCI for Rs. 5,000 crore). Here, the wider issue is whether the FCI is entitled to either a sovereign rating or a commercially prime rating. After all, the FCI has to fight things out and should not take shelter under the Government’s umbrella and even more so, under the pretence of supporting PDS. In fact, any interest rate relief provided to FCI must be treated as an addition to what the Government has to bear by way of food subsidy. Table V Food subsidy (Rs. Crore) 6,066 7,900 9,100 9,434 12,060 17,612 21,200 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 (BE) Source : Budget documents 41 Table VI Procurement of wheat and rice (Central Pool) (Million tonnes) Marketing Year Wheat Rice (April – March) (Oct – Sept) Qty. Percent change Qty. Percent change 1995-96 12.33 3.9 9.95 -25.7 1996-97 8.16 -33.8 12.22 22.8 1997-98 9.30 14.0 14.33 17.3 1998-99 12.65 36.0 11.84 -17.4 1999-00 14.14 11.8 17.27 46.5 2000-01 16.35 15.6 19.10 10.6 2001-02 20.63 26.2 21.28 11.4 2002-03* 19.03 12.23 * As on February 5, 2003 Source: Department of Food and Public Distribution. Table VII Management of Food Stocks Month 1 April 2002 May June July August September October November December January 2003 February March April May June Openi Buffer ng Stocking Stock Norm $ of Foodgrains 2 51.0 62.6 64.8 63.1 59.9 55.4 51.4 53.6 51.5 48.2 40.1 36.2 32.8 41.3 39.8 3 15.8 24.3 18.1 16.8 15.8 FoodStocking Procurement 4 14.3 6.1 2.5 0.2 0.2 0.6 7.1 1.3 1.3 2.0 1.4 0.9 13.1 3.6 1.0 Foodgrains off-take PDS OWS 5 1.2 1.5 1.6 1.5 1.8 1.5 1.8 1.5 2.0 1.8 2.1 1.9 1.4 1.8 1.2 6 0.4 0.8 1.3 0.6 0.5 0.5 1.2 0.8 1.2 1.3 1.1 1.7 0.9 1.6 2.5 42 OMS Exports (excluding Exports) 7 8 0.2 1.0 0.2 1.2 0.2 0.9 0.4 1.1 1.1 1.5 0.7 1.4 0.7 0.9 0.4 0.8 0.4 0.9 0.8 0.8 0.4 0.9 0.3 1.1 0.2 0.6 0.1 0.9 0.2 1.1 (Million Tonnes) Closing Food Food Stock Credit Subsidy @ # 9 62.6 64.8 63.1 59.9 55.4 51.4 53.6 51.5 48.2 40.1 36.2 32.8 41.3 39.8 35.2 10 52,484 60,669 61,008 59,077 56,400 53,362 52,705 54,346 51,947 49,784 50,227 49,479 44,589 51,047 50,066 11 1,754 1,632 1,703 2,490 1,734 2,283 2,601 1,924 2,653 2,261 23 3,117 1,462 2,209 2,830 $ Represents the total minimum stocks to be maintained by public agencies on the first day of the quarter under buffer stocking policy with effect from October 30, 1988. @ Outstanding in Rupees crore as on the last reporting Friday of the month. # Monthly expenditure on food subsidy in Rupees crore. PDS: Public Distribution System. OWS: Other Welfare Schemes. OMS: Open Market Sales. Source: Ministry of Food, Consumer Affairs and Public Distribution; Ministry of Finance, Government of India. Table VIII Minimum Support Prices: A historical perspective The price policy of the Government is directed at providing insurance to agricultural producers against any sharp fall in farm prices. The minimum guaranteed prices are fixed to set a floor below which market prices cannot fall. Till the mid 1970s, the Government had in force two types of administered prices: (i) Minimum Support Prices (MSP) (ii) Procurement Prices The MSPs served as the floor prices and were fixed by the Government in the nature of a long-term guarantee for the investment decisions of producers, with the assistance that prices of their commodities would not be allowed to fall below the level fixed by the Government, even in the case of a bumper crop. Procurement prices were the prices of kharif and rabi cereals at which the grain was to be domestically procured by public agencies (like the FCI) for release through PDS. It was announced soon after harvest began. Normally, the procurement price was lower than the open market price and higher than the MSP. This policy of two official prices being announced continued with some variation upto 1973-74, in the case of paddy. In the case of wheat, it was discontinued in 1969 and then revived in 1974-75 for one year only. Since there were too many demands for stepping up the MSP, in 1975-76, the existing system was evolved in which only one set of prices was announced for paddy (and other kharif crops) and wheat being procured for buffer stock operations. 43 Table IX FCI’s economic cost of rice and wheat Rice A. Acquisition cost (i) Pooled cost of grain (ii) Procurement incidentals B. Distribution cost Economic cost (A+B) (Rupees per quintal) 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 887.30 831.24 56.06 187.50 1074.80 1014.04 930.41 83.63 166.43 1180.47 1052.66 961.16 91.50 151.61 1204.27 1072.69 981.01 91.68 133.68 1206.37 2003-04 (BE) 1248 Wheat A. Acquisition cost 685.51 716.60 739.13 757.64 (i) Pooled cost of grain 518.08 580.66 571.93 585.76 (ii) Procurement incidentals 117.06 135.94 167.20 171.88 (iii) Carry over charges to 50.37 State Governments B. Distribution cost 202.00 141.66 132.17 121.52 Economic cost (A+B) 887.51 858.26 871.30 879.16 921 Source: Food Bulletin, Department of Food and Public Distribution, Economic Survey 2002-03 Table X Foodgrains allocation and offtake under Public Distribution System (Million tonnes) Wheat Rice Year Allocation Offtake Allocation Offtake 1992-93 9.25 7.47 11.48 9.55 1993-94 9.56 5.91 12.41 8.87 1994-95 10.80 4.83 13.32 8.03 1995-96 11.31 5.29 14.62 9.46 1996-97 10.72 8.52 15.10 11.14 1997-98 10.11 7.08 12.83 9.90 1998-99 10.11 7.95 12.94 10.74 1999-00 10.37 5.76 13.89 11.31 2000-01* 11.57 4.07 16.26 7.97 2001-02* 13.14 5.68 17.23 8.16 2002-03* 29.45 6.12@ 27.35 7.39@ * including Antyodaya Anna Yojana @ upto December, 2002 Source: Department of Food and Public Distribution, Economic Survey, 2002-03 44 Table XI Surplus foodstocks – Fundamental resource for drought relief During 2002-03, 17 major states including Andhra Pradesh, Chattisgarh, Haryana, Himachal Pradesh, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu and UP faced a drought like situation. Unlike floods where the impact is limited to only one season, the impact of drought lasts not only through the four months of kharif (July-October) but also through rabi (November-March) and the next kharif upto October when the new harvest arrives and incomes begin to accrue. Distress due to drought, therefore, lasts three seasons. Fortunately, in 2002-03, the Economic Survey, 2002-03 pointed out, the country’s godowns were overflowing with surplus stocks of foodgrains, which constituted the fundamental resources for providing timely relief to the states under the various welfare schemes of the Government. The total stock of foodgrains as on January 1, 2003 was 48 million tonnes as against a minimum norm of 16.8 million tonnes. The surplus stock helped mitigate the adverse effects of the drought, according to the survey. Further, FCI and its agencies had adequate foodgrain stocks located in the drought-affected states where there were 3.04 lakh fair price shops, the survey noted. Table XII Offtake of foodgrains (rice+wheat) under welfare schemes Welfare schemes Annapurna Earthquake World Food Programme Sampoorna Grameen Rozgar Yojana Indigent People Nutrition Prog. Hostel SC/ST/OBC Food-For-Work Mid-Day-Meal Total 2000-01 2001-02 0.25 10.72 0.05 0.33 0.00 0.18 0.00 5.44 14.93 31.91 0.93 0.12 0.50 18.83 0.17 1.35 0.83 28.36 20.76 71.85 (Lakh tonnes) 2002-03 (upto Dec. 2002) 0.87 0.00 0.32 54.76 0.08 1.22 1.02 1.18 15.11 74.58 Offtake under the various welfare schemes picked up considerably during the current year and was 7.46 million tonnes upto December, 2002. Offtake under SGRY and Mid Day Meal Scheme had been very good. Surplus stocks of foodgrains were well utilised to provided relief to the drought-affected states. Source: Economic Survey, 2002-03 45 Table XIII CACP’s methodology for cost calculation The minimum support prices for major agricultural products are announced each year after taking into account the recommendations of the Commission for Agricultural Costs and Prices (CACP). The CACP, while recommending prices takes into account all important factors including cost of production, changes in input prices, input/output price parity, trends in market prices, inter-crop price parity and demand and supply situation, parity between prices paid and prices received by farmers. Among these multiple factors that go into the formulation of support price policy, the cost of production is the most significant. Thus, for making the support price policy functionally meaningful, the minimum guaranteed price ought to cover at least the reasonable cost of production in a normal agricultural season obtained from efficient farming. The CACP analyses the cost of production data for various states in respect of various commodities in consultation with the states. After a meeting of the State Chief Ministers, the MSP/procurement prices are declared. With costs of production for the same crops varying between regions and also across within the same region and for different producers, the level of costs that could be accepted as a norm poses enormous difficulties. Cost concepts In fixing the support prices, CACP relies on the cost concept, which covers all items of expenses of cultivation including the imputed value of inputs owned by farmers such as rental value of owned land and interest on fixed capital. Some of the important cost concepts used by CACP are the C2 and C3 costs. C2 cost C2 cost includes all actual expenses in cash and kind incurred in production by the actual owner plus rent paid for leased land plus the imputed value of family labour plus interest on the value of owned capital assets (excluding land) plus rental value of owned land (net of land revenue) C3 cost Cost C2+10 percent of cost C2 to account for managerial remuneration to the farmer. Costs of production are calculated both on a per quintal and per hectare basis. Since cost variations are large over states, CACP recommends that MSP should be considered on the basis of C2 cost. However, increases in MSP have been so substantial in case of paddy and wheat, that in most of the states MSPs are way above not only the C2 cost but the C3 cost as well. For instance, the weighted average of C3 costs of eight wheat growing states is presently only Rs. 532 per quintal while the weighted average of C2 cost is Rs. 483 per quintal as against which the CACP recommended MSP 2002-03 is Rs. 620 per quintal. The producer subsidy at C2 cost is, therefore, Rs. 137 per quintal (MSP minus C2 cost) and Rs. 88 per quintal at C3 cost (MSP minus C3 cost). 46 Table XIV Central foodgrain stocks and minimum buffer stock norms (Million Tonnes) Wheat Rice Beginning of the Min. Actual Min. month norm Stock Norm January-1996 7.7 13.1 7.7 April 3.7 7.8 10.8 July 13.1 14.1 9.2 October 10.6 10.5 6.0 January-1997 7.7 7.1 7.7 April 3.7 3.2 10.8 July 13.1 11.4 9.2 October 10.6 8.3 6.0 January-1998 (P) 7.7 6.8 7.7 April 3.7 5.1 10.8 July 13.1 16.5 9.2 October 10.6 15.2 6.0 January-1999 8.4 12.7 8.4 April 4.0 9.7 11.8 July 14.3 22.5 10.0 October 11.6 20.3 6.5 January- 2000 8.4 17.2 8.4 April 4.0 13.2 11.8 July 14.3 27.8 10.0 October 11.6 26.9 6.5 January-2001 8.4 25.0 8.4 April 4.0 21.5 11.8 July 14.3 38.9 10.0 October 11.6 36.8 6.5 January-2002 (P) 8.4 32.4 8.4 April 4.0 26.0 11.8 July 14.3 41.1 10.0 October 11.6 35.6 6.5 January-2003 (P) 8.4 28.8 8.4 (P) Provisional Source: Department of Food and Public Distribution. 47 Actual Stock 15.4 13.1 12.9 9.3 12.9 13.2 11.0 7.0 11.5 13.1 12.0 9.0 11.7 12.2 10.6 7.7 14.2 15.7 14.5 13.2 20.7 23.2 22.8 21.5 25.6 24.9 21.9 15.8 19.4 Total (Wheat and rice) Min. Actual norm Stock 15.4 28.5 14.5 20.9 22.3 27.0 16.6 19.8 15.4 20.0 14.5 16.4 22.3 22.4 16.6 15.3 15.4 18.3 14.5 18.2 22.3 28.5 16.6 24.2 16.8 24.4 15.8 21.9 24.3 33.1 18.1 28.0 16.8 31.4 15.8 21.7 24.3 42.2 18.1 40.1 16.8 45.7 15.8 44.7 24.3 61.7 18.1 58.3 16.8 58.0 15.8 50.9 24.3 63.0 18.1 51.4 16.8 48.2 Table XV Minimum support/procurement price of wheat and paddy (Rs/quintal) Wheat Paddy Crop year MSP Percent Common Percent Fine Super Grade ‘A’ change change fine 1992-93 330 20.0 270 17.4 280 290 1993-94 350 6.1 310 14.8 330 350 1994-95 360 2.9 340 9.7 360 380 1995-96 380 5.6 360 5.9 375 395 1996-97 475 25.0 380 5.6 395 415 1997-98* 510 7.4 415 9.2 455 1998-99 550 7.8 440 6.0 470 1999-00 580 5.5 490 11.4 520 2000-01 610 5.2 510 4.1 540 2001-02 620 1.6 530 3.9 560 2002-03 530 $ 0.0 $ 560 $ * Effective 1997-98, MSP is fixed for only two varieties of paddy, common and grade-A. $ One Time Special Drought Relief of Rs. 20/- per quintal has been given in case of paddy in 2002-03 over and above the existing MSP. Source: Ministry of Agriculture Year 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 BPL APL 1998-99 BPL APL 1999-2000 BPL APL 2000-01 BPL Table XVI PDS issue price of wheat and rice (Rs. per quintal) Wheat Percent Rice Percent change change 234 289 280 19.7 377 30.4 280 0.0 377 0.0 330 17.9 437 15.9 402 21.8 537 22.9 402 0.0 537 0.0 402 0.0 537 0.0 250 450 - 350 700 - 250 650 0.0 44.4 350 905 0.0 29.3 250 682 0.0 4.9 350 905 0.0 0.0 415 66.0 565 61.4 48 APL 830 21.7 2001-02 BPL 415 0.0 APL 610 -26.5 2002-03 April BPL 415 0.0 APL 510 -16.4 July BPL 415 0.0 APL 610 19.6 BPL- below poverty line; APL-above poverty line Economic Survey – 2002-03 49 1130 24.9 565 830 0.0 -26.5 565 730 0.0 12.0 565 830 0.0 13.7 (VII) FERTILISER SUBSIDY Presumably, the subsidy policy in regard to fertilisers has been prompted by two considerations: providing an essential input to farmers at economic prices and ensuring an adequate return on investment to producing plains. During the Eighties, kharif crops had accounted for nearly a third of the total fertiliser consumption in the country, but rabi crops accounted for a much larger share. In recent years, however, consumption has been evenly spread between the two sowing seasons, possibly reflecting an enhanced availability of irrigation water during the kharif season. In 1980-81, the rabi season’s share was 61.2 percent, while the kharif season accounted for only a modest 38.8 percent. By 2000-01, the kharif season reported an application of 48.1 percent as compared to the rabi season’s 51.9 percent. This proportion was, more or less, kept in 2001-02, with 46.6 percent for kharif and 53.4 percent for rabi. Between 1980-81 and 1999-2000, the consumption of fertilisers rose by more than three times from 5.5 million tonnes to 18.07 million tonnes. In 2000-01, however, the consumption fell to 16.7 million tonnes, which the Government attributed to inadequate rainfall in many parts of the country, but rose significantly in the following year to 17.36 million tonnes, thereby increasing the per hectare fertiliser consumption to 90.12 kg in 2001-02 from 86.71 kg in 2000-01. A higher increase in the consumption of phosphate (3.96 percent) and potassic fertilisers (3.57 percent) in 2001-02 was perceived as a welcome trend towards a balanced use of nutrients. Table XVII Consumption of fertiliser in nutrient terms Fertilisers 1997-98 Nitrogenous Fertilisers 10,901 Phosphatic Fertilisers 3,914 Potassic Fertilisers 1,373 All Fertilisers (NPK) 16,188 Percentage increase 13.14 Source: Ministry of Chemicals & Fertilisers. 1998-99 11,354 4,112 1,332 16,798 3.77 50 1999-00 11,592 4,799 1,678 18,069 7.57 (‘000 tonnes of nutrients) 2000-01 10,920 4,215 1,567 16,702 -7.56 2001-02 11,310 4,382 1,667 17,360 3.90 Table XVIII Per hectare consumption of fertilisers for cropped area during 2001-02 S. No. State / U.T. 2001-02 1. Andhra Pradesh 143.46 2. Karnataka 101.48 3. Kerala 60.72 4. Tamil Nadu 141.55 5. Gujarat 85.52 6. Madhya Pradesh* 39.96 7. Maharashtra 78.24 8. Rajasthan 38.88 9. Haryana 155.69 10. Himachal Pradesh 41.40 11. Jammu & Kashmir 64.55 12. Punjab 173.38 13. Uttar Pradesh** 130.44 14. Bihar 87.39 15. Orissa 40.91 16. West Bengal 126.82 17. Arunachal Pradesh 2.88 18. Assam 38.81 19. Tripura 30.45 20. Manipur 104.94 21. Meghalaya 17.16 22. Nagaland 2.13 23. Mizoram 13.72 24. Sikkim 9.72 All India 90.12 * Includes Chhatisgarh ** Includes Uttaranchal Source: Ministry of Chemicals & Fertilisers Table XIX : Season-wise consumption of fertilisers (‘000 Tonnes of nutrients) Percent share Year Kharif Rabi Total Kharif Rabi 1970-71 830 229 629 1980-81 2,138 3,378 5,516 38.8 61.2 1990-91 5,741 6,805 12,546 45.8 54.2 2000-01 8,034 8,668 16,702 48.1 51.9 2001-02 8,085 9,275 17,360 46.6 53.4 Source: Ministry of Chemicals and Fertilisers 51 In 2002-03, fertiliser production in the country (nitrogen & phosphates) was projected at 15.23 million tonnes (11 million tonnes of nitrogen and 4.23 million tonnes of phosphate). As for potash (murate of potash MOP), the entire requirement is imported, as the country has no commercially exploitable sources of MOP. The farm-gate price of urea was fixed at Rs.4,830 per tonne in 200203. On an average, a subsidy amounting to more than Rs.4,100 per tonne is presently borne by the Government on every tonne of urea sold to farmers. The subsidy in 2002-03 (BE) was Rs. 7,004 crore. Coming to phosphatic and potassic fertilisers, one must recall the decontrol effected on August 25, 1992 and the sharp rise in prices as well as an equally sharp fall in consumption that followed it. The price concession (subsidy) was consequently enhanced and by a substantial margin. It is under this facility that the Government announces the indicative maximum retail price (MRP) for DAP, MOP and complex fertilisers. As for the MRP of SSP, this was left to the respective state governments, leading to price variations. At the outset, we mentioned the dual reasoning behind the subsidy policy. In outlining the core areas of the research study, reference was made earlier to the imperative of policy makers putting an end to the regime of rewarding inefficiency and punishing efficiency. It was, in fact, acknowledged by the Government that the individual retention price scheme (RPS) for urea producers had led to certain aberrations. Over the years, primarily, the scheme contributed to the adoption of a cost-plus approach in reimbursing the cost of production to the urea producers. This was reinforced by the Expenditure Reforms Commission. Invariably, the approach generated no compulsion for producers to improve their efficiency. This should be our basic objection, given the thrust of this study for the Twelfth Finance Commission. 52 Table XX Fertiliser production, imports and subsidies Imports* Subsidy Year Production* Imported Domestic Decontrolled Nitrogen Phosphate N+P+K Urea Urea Fertiliser (‘000 tonnes) (Rs. Crore) 1960-61 98 52 419 1970-71 830 229 629 1980-81 2,164 841 2,759 335 170 1990-91 6,993 2,052 2,758 659 3,730 2000-01 10,962 3,743 2,090 1 9,480 4,319 2001-02 10,768 3,860 2,398 47 8,257 4,504 2002-03 (BE) 10,876 4,356 1,004* 505 6,499 4,224 (BE) Budget estimate *Upto 31/10/2002 Source: Ministry of Chemicals & Fertilisers. P&K Total Rightly, policymakers concluded that the RPS was totally out of tune with economic reality, characterised by a thrust on international competitiveness, global marketing, import liberalisation, import price parity and free trade. The decision was taken that by end of the eighth pricing period of the RPS on 31st March, 2003, a new pricing policy for urea units based on the recommendations of the Expenditure Reforms Commission (ERC) would come into effect. A key goal of the amended policy regime is to gradually move in the direction of parity with international prices based on the use of the most efficient feedstock and state of the art technology. The policy is in the form of a group-based concession scheme. The urea units have been placed in six groups based on vintage and feedstock. The scheme is being implemented in three stages. Stage I covers the fiscal year 2003-04. Stage II would be for two years ending March 31, 2006. The concluding stage will come into effect on April 1, 2006 and the modalities are to be decided by the Department of Fertilisers (DoF) before April 1, 2006 after a review of the implementation of stages I & II as well as the prospects of availability of gas and LNG to be supplied by public/private sector companies. The changed dispensation has been designed to promote efficiency in production through measures of cost saving and efficient economic practices 53 505 4,389 13,800 12,808 11,228 at par with international norms by the domestic urea producers. Further, a beginning has been made towards greater de-control and liberalisation. Allocation of urea under the Essential Commodities Act, 1955 is to be restricted up to 75 percent and 50 percent of the installed capacity (as reassessed) of each unit in kharif 2003 and rabi 2003-04 respectively; thereafter, the units will be free to sell the remaining urea at the designated MRP. During stage II commencing 01/04/2004, urea distribution will be totally decontrolled after an evaluation of the performance in stage I. This is to be done in consultation with the Ministry of Agriculture. The ERC scheme is designed to make farmers pay market-determined prices but the process spelt out is hardly re-assuring on this aspect. The Commission does not dare say that farmers can consume fertiliser on commercial terms and still suffer no disincentive to add to the nation’s production of foodgrains without the helping hand of the Government. The same reluctance is noticeable in the reports of other expert bodies. This study advocates a firm shift to unsubsidised use of fertiliser by all farmers except those in the small and marginal strata. 54 FERTILISER SUBSIDY: ANNEXURE 1. CHANGE IN PRICING POLICY FOR UREA MANUFACTURERS The Government approved on January 30, 2003 a new pricing policy for urea units to replace the Retention Price Scheme and to come into effect from 1.4.2003.Salient features of the policy as also the modalities for implementation of the Scheme were as follows: The primary consideration and goal of the new pricing policy is to encourage efficiency parameters of international standards based on the usage of the most efficient feedstock, state-of-art technology and also ensure a viable rate of return to the units.The new scheme will come into effect from 1.4.2003 and will be implemented in stages.Stage-I would be of one year duration, from 1.4.2003 to 31.3.2004.Stage-II would be of two years duration, from 1.4.2004 to 31.3.2006.The modalities of Stage-III are to be decided by the Department of Fertilisers (DoF) after review of the implementation of Stage-I and Stage-II. There will be six groups based on vintage and feedstock for determining the group – based concession under the new Scheme, namely, pre-1992 gas based units, post-1992 gas based units, pre-1992 naphtha based units, post-1992 naphtha based units, fuel oil/low sulphur heavy stock (FO/LSHS) based units and mixed energy based units.The mixed energy based group shall include such gasbased units that use alternative feedstock/fuel to the extent of more than 25 percent as admissible on 1.4.2002. Classification of units among different groups so determined shall remain unchanged during Stages-I and II. During Stage-I, the following measures are to be put into effect: Rates of concession for the units in each group to be determined in two steps. In Step-I, the weighted average retention price and the dealer’s margin of the units 55 in the respective group as applicable on 1.4.2002 would be computed. Units having an exceptionally high or low retention price, i.e. deviation of 20 percent and above with reference to the group average computed in Step-I are to be treated as ‘outliers’ in their respective groups. In Step-2, the final weighted average group retention price after excluding the ‘outliers’ will be computed. The group concession rate on 1.4.2003 would be computed on the data of the units on 31.3.2003 as applicable. To determine that, the retention prices as notified for the half year up to 30.9.2002 are to be taken as the base and the adjustment on the basis of 8th pricing period for the remaining period, i.e. 1.10.2002 to 31.3.2003, to be made before the end of financial year 2003-2004. Effective 1.4.2003, the units in each group are to receive the concession after adjustment on account of escalation/de-escalation in the variable cost related to changes in the price of feedstock, fuel, purchased power and water. The modalities for this purpose are to be worked out by DoF for Stage-I and Stage-II on the basis of group energy data and efficient consumption patterns of the units keeping in view the data of 8th pricing period. Those units which have a lower retention price than the weighted group average (estimated after excluding the ‘outliers’ as final group retention price) are to get the concession as per their individual retention price. The remaining units (excluding ‘outliers’) are to get the concession based upon the weighted group average retention price computed after excluding the outliers. This basis is to be valid for Stage-II also. After the commencement of Stage-I and also beyond Stage-II, there is to be neither any reimbursement of the investment made by a unit for improvement in operations nor any mopping up of gains of the units as a result of operational 56 efficiency. The parameters outlined in the new scheme are to be the inputs for computation of concession. The ‘outliers’ having a retention price higher than 20 percent or more from the group average in their respective group are to be granted an adjustment phase of one year, i.e. Stage-I.During Stage-I, the ‘outliers’ are to get a rate of concession based upon the group weighted average (after excluding ‘outliers’) and a structural adjustment – 50 percent of the difference between their respective retention price and the group average computed as Step-II – mentioned in para 3.1. Group concession rates are to be calculated excluding the incidence of sales tax on inputs to be computed and compensated on the basis of rates effective on 1.4.2002 for each unit. However, the compensation is to be proportionately reduced if the rates are reduced by any state. During Stage-II, i.e. from 1.4.2004, the following measures are to be put into effect : There will be no special treatment for the ‘outliers’ and all the units are to get the group rate of concession as outlined earlier for Stage-I.The units having a lower concession rate than the group average are to continue to get the concession as per their individual concession rate. The six groups are to remain as in Stage-I. The concession rates are to be adjusted for reduction in capital – related charges. Further, the group energy norms are to be enforced on efficiency considerations. The Department of Fertilisers is to take into consideration the recommendations of the Gokak Committee in determining the group energy norms. The scale of reduction on account of capital – related charges (CRC) are 57 also to be finalised by the Department of Fertilisers. Thus, the adjustments on account of CRC and group energy norms effective in Stage-II are to be made known to the units so that they have reasonable time for making necessary technological and other structural adjustments. Under the new Scheme, there is to be no capping on production of urea. The use or sale of by-products such as ammonia, CO2 etc. is to be permitted if considered surplus beyond the reassessed capacity for urea production. The final concession is to be determined on the reassessed installed capacity. The additional production beyond the installed capacity is to receive a concession if it is mopped up under the ECA (Essential Commodities Act 1955) allocation. The feedstock/fuel ratio for the entire production is to be taken into consideration for assessing the concession. PHASED DECONTROL OF UREA DISTRIBUTION/MOVEMENT In Stage-I, i.e. from 1.4.2003 to 31.3.2004, the allocation of urea under the ECA is to be restricted up to 75 percent and 50 percent of installed capacity (as reassessed) of each unit in kharif 2003 and Rabi 2003-04, respectively. The Department is to be left free to make necessary adjustments in determining the ECA allocation in case of the estimated/actual production during the year being below the reassessed installed capacity. The remaining urea production is to be available to the manufacturers for sale to the farmers at MRP anywhere in the country. Manufacturers are to be entitled to sell urea to complex manufacturing units on the principle of import parity price or to export, with the condition that no subsidy/concession will be payable on that quantity and it will be computed towards the quantity permitted for decontrolled sale. (Urea export has potential, more so now with domestic prices ruling at $ 170 a tonne against $ 200 globally. The few low cost plans alone can capitilise on the opportunity, those operating 58 on gas as feedstock. Those using naphtha do not stand much of a chance. Exports this year can touch 5 lakh tonnes if controls are eased on trade). The DoF is to reserve the authority to make suitable adjustments, in view of demandsupply positions in the ECA allocation, and de-controlled urea up to 15 percent over and above the reassessed installed capacity in case their applicable concession rate is financially and economically efficient thereby contributing to a reduction in the subsidy burden. During Stage-II, urea distribution is to be totally decontrolled after having evaluated the Stage-I and with the concurrence of the Ministry of Agriculture. (Quite clearly, fertiliser should cease to be in the ambit of ECA, under a reform of subsidies). FREIGHT During 2003-04, equated freight is to be worked out for the urea quantity under ECA allocation on the basis of average normative lead and rail-road mix of each unit for the last three years i.e. 2000-01, 2001-02 and 2002-03. Suitable adjustments are to be granted in the event of rail freight revision during the course of 2003-04. Secondary freight will remain the same as fixed for the 8 th pricing period. For the quantity outside ECA allocation, a reduction of Rs. 100 per metric tonne is to be made from the equated freight. The same levels of payment are to be made in Stage-II as well. Regarding the road component of the primary freight, appropriate adjustments are to be made as per annual increase/decrease in the wholesale price index of diesel in the previous year for the fuel part and indices of other components are to remain unchanged in the composite index. The existing scheme for special freight subsidy is to continue for supplies to the North Eastern States and Jammu & Kashmir. The Government also is to have the right to issue a special movement order under the EC Act as per the demand – supply situation, particularly for difficult and remote areas. 59 The chief executives of various urea manufacturing companies were to execute an undertaking in a prescribed proforma to confirm their participation in the amended scheme. 2. ENERGY NORMS, RAW MATERIAL MIX AND MECHANISM FOR PROVIDING ESCALATION/DE-ESCALATION IN PRICES OF INPUTS FOR UREA UNITS. On January 30, 2003 the Government had stated that the group energy norms would be enforced on efficiency considerations during Stage-II of the new pricing scheme (NPS). Accordingly, the following decisions were taken with regard to energy norms, raw material mix (feedstock, fuel, purchased power and water) and the mechanism for providing escalation/de-escalation in the prices on inputs for urea units during Stage-II commencing from 1.4.2004. Pre-set energy norms for urea units during Stage-II of NPS are to be as given in Table XX. As regards the raw material mix during Stage-II, the actual ratio/proportion of the mix of each unit will be considered, subject to a ceiling of the pre-set energy norms as indicated while computing the escalation/de-escalation in the components of variable cost related to feedstock, fuel and purchased power. As regards water, the consumption norms fixed for the 8th pricing period will continue. During Stage-II, escalation/de-escalation on the cost of the components of variable cost will be worked out by the Fertiliser Industry Co-ordination Committee (FICC) exclusive of sales tax. The sales tax will be calculated to the 60 level of pre-set energy norms and paid separately as per the formula contained in the policy statement of 30.1.2003. Escalation/de-escalation will be carried out on a quarterly/annual basis. However, if the actual energy consumption of a unit is lower than the pre-set energy norms, the resultant excess would be valued for escalation/de-escalation at the basic rate (excluding sales tax, transportation cost etc.) of the cheapest input, as per the existing practice followed by the FICC. There is to be no reworking of the concession rates for urea units determined as on 1.4.2003 (i.e. beginning of Stage-I of NPS). In Stage-II, beginning 1.4.2004, the concession rates are to be adjusted only for the pre-set energy norms and escalation/de-escalation in the components of variable cost based on pre-set energy norms as indicated below. Table XXI Pre-set energy norms for urea units during Stage II of New Pricing Scheme S. No. Name of the urea unit Pre-set energy norm (Goal/MT of urea) Group-I: Pre-1992 Gas 1. BVFCL-Namrup-III 9.264* 2. IFFCO – Aonla-I 5.938 3. INDOGULF – Jagdishpur 5.874 4. KRIBHCO-Hazira 5.952 5. NFL-Vijaypur-I 5.952 6. RCF-Trombay-V 9.569* Group-II: Post-1992 Gas 1. NFCL-Kakinada-I 5.712 2. CFCL-Gadepan-I 5.712 3. TCL-Babrala 5.507 4. OCFL-Shahjahanpur 5.712 5. NFCL-Kakinada-II 5.712 6. IFFCO-Aonla-II 5.660 7. NFL-Vijaypur-II 5.712 Group-III: Pre-1992 Naphtha 1. SFC-Kota 7.847 2. DIL-Kanpur 7.847 3. IFFCO-Phulpur-I 7.847 4. FACT-Cochin 9.529* 61 5. MCFL-Mangalore 7.356 6. MFL- Chennai 8.337* 7. SPIC-Tuticorin 7.475 8. ZIL-Goa 7.585 Group-IV: Post-1992 Naphtha 1. IFFCO-Phulpur-II 5.883 2. CFCL-Gadepan-II 5.678 Group-V: FO/LSHS 1. GNVFC-Bharuch 7.989 2. NFL-Nangal 9.517* 3. NFL-Bhatinda 10.203* 4. NFL-Panipat 9.654* Group-VI: Mixed Feedstock 1. GSFC-Baroda 6.935 2. IFFCO-Kalol 6.836 3. RDF-Thal 7.004 * These norms are on the basis of the lowest of energy consumption achieved in 2000-01, 2001-02 and 2002-03 or the 8th pricing period norms. The data of 2002-03 are provisional and the final data could influence the pre-set energy norms. 3. Reduction in rates of concession during Stage-II As per the Fertiliser Department’s policy statement of 30.1.2003, the concession rates payable during Stage-II of NPS, i.e. w.e.f. 1.4.2004, were to be adjusted for reduction in capital – related charges. Accordingly, on August 6, 2003 it was decided that the concession payable on account of reduction in capital-related charges would be reduced as given below during Stage-II of NPS, w.e.f. 1.4.2004: S.No. 1. 2. 3. Table XXII Name of the units/groups Three units of pre-1992 gas–based group (i) Indo Gulf Fertilisers Ltd. Jagdishpur (ii) National Fertilisers Ltd., Vijaipur-I (iii) Indian Farmers Fertilisers Cooperative Ltd. – Aonla-I All units of post-1992 gas–based group (seven units) All units of post-1992 naphtha–based group (two units) 62 Rate of reduction (Rs./MT of urea) 120 170 170 There is to be no reduction in concession rates on account of reduction in CRC during Stage-II on NPS in respect of the remaining twenty units. The Government’s package of incentives announced in January, 2004, for urea producers should facilitate feedstock utilisation on a more rational basis and cut down costs. The policy thrust is acceleration of a shift to natural gas from high cost naphtha. This could explain the Union Cabinet’s shelving of a proposal by a ministerial panel to raise natural gas prices – see Chapter-V - , but the urea plants should not forever subsist on props of one kind or the other. Yes, urea alone is globally price competitive and DAP, SSP and MOP can hardly ever lure buyers abroad. But, this should justify less, not more, of subsidies. 63 (VIII) SAFETY NET CONCEPTS AS EVOLVED BY THE WORLD BANK THE TRUTH ! As per WTO regulations, direct income transfers, not related to production, will fall in the green box (exempted category). However, in India, food subsidy is production-related, although because of costs and other issues, till recently, food subsidy calculations according to WTO norms were negative. WHY SUBSIDIES ? Subsidies are often chosen as an alternative to (or to supplement) income transfers: ï‚· Through pricing, to shift demand patterns towards socially acceptable norms and to ensure consumption of basic minimum needs – food, health, education etc. Apparently, this may also facilitate more decision making by women with subsidies rather than income transfers. ï‚· Politically expedient (middle class with voting power will also benefit). Also difficult to dislodge because of interest groups. ï‚· Administratively convenient ï‚· Lack of faith in the “hidden hand” of Adam Smith – commodity markets (black marketing/hoarding etc) as also poorly developed markets. However, subsidies often distort production incentives in unintended ways without consideration of true economic costs (E.g. growing rice in Punjab, which requires huge quantities of water – available at zero cost, and probably, thus, not available to other needy states for household consumption or for irrigating other less water-hungry crops.). 64 WHO BENEFITS FROM FOOD SUBSIDIES? In India, are subsidies producer subsidies or consumer subsidies? Effectively, food subsidies in India are production subsidies, not really consumer subsidies. If they were consumer subsidies, you would be subsidising retail purchase/ consumption, not FCI procurement. ï‚· One reason peculiar to India is that producer subsidies were intended for (a) national self-sufficiency (and not depend on foreign food imports in an open economy) and provide base support for farmers (b) provide a net for poor monsoons. But, in that case, the minimum support price should be a support price marginally below the “fair” market price, and the FCI should be a ‘procurer’ of last resort, not as is the case now, where it is the first resort for non-premium rice and wheat from Punjab. ï‚· How is leakage / diversion to be measured, let alone tackled ? What about political will e.g. there was a move to make household kerosene blue in colour, but that would have made it more difficult to sell on the black market – not so far accepted. (This has been accepted and the kerosene that is for non-PDS sale is, indeed, blue in colour. The World Bank must change its safety net concepts accordingly – KSR) ï‚· Who benefits from producer subsidies – rich, medium or poor producers? ï‚· In terms of rationing, consumption is rationed, but are producer subsidies similarly rationed within and across states? Why do Punjab and AP corner the vast majority of food subsidies? ï‚· If nothing else, restriction of ration cards for the poor brings down the total volume available for purchase, but does it do so for procurement? ï‚· Are energy subsidies justified? How are they targeted? Electricity, kerosene and LPG in the Indian context – different targets. [Taken from the report of the World Research Institute] 65 (IX) SUBSIDIES: THE INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCE (Taken from “Price and tax subsidization of consumer goods”, June-2002, World Research Institute) Generalized Consumer Subsidies Whenever a commodity or service is subsidised in a manner that does not impose quotas, there is an implicit, or de facto, targeting of the benefits. These benefits accrue to a household in proportion to the amount of that good that the household purchases. For those commodities that are what economists term normal goods (defined as goods with income elasticities – income elasticity measures the percentage change in the commodity purchased with a one percent change in income – between zero and one), the wealthier the household, the greater the absolute value of the subsidy it receives. However, with commodities in this category, the poorer the household, the larger the subsidy is as a share of household income. Most commonly consumed grains tend to fall in this group. However, occasionally a Government chooses to subsidise goods for which the income elasticity is greater than one. This is the cut-off by which luxuries are commonly defined. Despite the term “luxury,” many commodities that are considered part of a normal diet such as meat and dairy products often fall in this category. The economic definition of a luxury, however, implies that the amount spent on the good increases as a share of total consumption as income rises. This also means that the amount transferred by a subsidy on a good is both absolutely and relatively greater for the well off than for the poor. In contrast, there may be goods that are consumed in greater amounts by the poor than by other segments of the population. While technically these commodities are referred to in economic literature as inferior goods, this designation pertains to the purchasing pattern (or negative income elasticity) 66 and not the physical attributes of the commodity. Thus, in some circumstances coarse grains may be inferior goods in the sense that the absolute as well as the relative value of the benefit of a subsidy is greater for the poor than for the nonpoor. Nevertheless, from the standpoint of the nutritional qualities of these grains, they are considered superior to the more popular highly polished or refined grains. Subsidies on commodities with low and, ideally, negative elasticities, if such commodities are available, will be progressive. Subsidies on such commodities are often referred to as self-targeted. Self-targeting can also be used for services such as subsidised clinics and—via wages—for determining who takes up public work opportunities. This targeting can also be achieved if there are grades of the subsidised good that consumers recognise as distinct. For example, coarse (high extraction) flour is more likely to be consumed by the poor while consumption of low extraction flour may be more evenly distributed through a population. However, as purchases of a commodity are disaggregated into different grades, each good will represent a comparatively small share of a consumer’s budget. This small share poses a limit on the amount of income that can be transferred via a self-targeted commodity subsidy. If the incidence of subsidy benefits were determined wholly by purchases in integrated markets (and, as discussed below, it often is not), the amount of subsidy going to households in different income quartiles would parallel consumer demand and could be identified in advance using consumer expenditure surveys. Most countries have consumer expenditure surveys that can provide a reasonable guide to the distribution of general subsidies. Indeed, such analysis can often be undertaken prior to a policy change to anticipate its likely impact. 67 While the discussion so far has indicated some well-known patterns in the relative magnitude of demand elasticities—for example, that grain consumption is more evenly distributed across a population than is the consumption of meat— there are few general patterns across all consumer groups. For example, sugar and cooking oil may be consumed in virtually equal amounts across income groups in a given country or region or they may be regarded as luxury commodities. Studies of subsidies in Egypt have found that the poor consume more sugar and subsidised bread than the well-off do and that flour and cooking oil consumption increases slightly with income (Ali and Adams, 1996 and Adams, 2000). An earlier study found that the value of subsidised flour and bread consumed by the poorest urban quartile in 1982 was 15 percent less than that purchased by the rich. At that time, the poorest rural quartile bought 20 percent less from subsidised government channels than did the richest rural quartile, whose consumption was nearly the same as the urban poor (Alderman and von Braun, 1984). This implies that the former distribution was slightly biased towards the well-off (although it contributed more to the poor as a share of income). A decade later, government subsidies were somewhat more targeted to the poor. In the interim, the government had implemented a policy that restricted subsidies on refined flour and the bread made from such flour and concentrated on bread made from high extraction flour. This contrasts with how the subsidies on flour in Algeria were distributed among income groups. In 1991, eight percent of subsidies on flour went to the poorest quintile, while 36 percent went to the richest (Grosh, 1994). However, semolina (couscous), for which the benefit ratio of 9:11 was more equitable, was the principal staple in the economy rather than flour. The importance of the context of the subsidy can also be illustrated by comparing the distribution of rice and 68 wheat in urban Belo Horizante, Brazil with the same commodities in Sri Lanka prior to the introduction of a targeted programme in Sri Lanka in 1978. In Brazil, the poor and the rich consumed similar amounts of the commodities and, thus, the subsidy was only slightly regressive. In Sri Lanka, however, the poor consumed only half as much wheat as the well-off. This is probably because in Sri Lanka rice is the main staple for the majority of the population. Thus, urban non-poor households as well as the comparatively few poor estate workers who ate bread were the primary beneficiaries of the untargeted wheat subsidy. MARKET ACCESS AS A DETERMINANT OF THE INCIDENCE OF SUBSIDIES The use of budget shares to subsidise commodities as an indication of the distribution of benefits presumes that all segments of the population use the same market channels. Otherwise, the redistributive nature of the subsidy will differ according to whether the consumer purchased the good from the channel that was subsidised rather than a parallel channel or consumed the good out of home consumption. While rural residency is not synonymous with participation in agriculture or, indeed, with self-sufficiency in production, a substantial share of the rural poor do not benefit from consumer subsidies since they either produce their own food or obtain what they need by direct trade with and purchases from neighbours. This is not an insurmountable barrier to using subsidies as a component of rural social protection; both Sri Lanka and Egypt have managed to include the rural population in their subsidy systems. Nevertheless, it is an obstacle that must be considered. The poor also may be precluded from benefiting from subsidies by cash constraints. If subsidised commodities are pre-packaged or only available for a few days a month, the poor may be unable to make the scale of purchase necessary to take advantage of the subsidy. This was the case with a rice 69 subsidy in urban Burkina Faso (Delgado and Reardon, 1988) and is often presumed to limit utilisation of the subsidised public distribution system (PDS) in India. A recent study has provided evidence that supports the contention that the need of the poor to make small purchases influences which market channels they choose. The study in question documented the small size of purchases made by the poor in south India and the relatively higher prices that they paid due to this cash flow problem (Rao, 2000). Are Energy Subsidies Substantially Different from Food Subsidies? Many of the justifications for energy subsidies are similar to those outlined above for food subsidies. Indeed, in many countries, energy subsidies may utilise far more resources than are currently devoted to food or other commodities. This is currently the case in the countries of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe (World Bank, 2000b). There is also a tendency to subsidise energy when a country is an exporter of gas or oil, often ignoring the opportunity cost of the gas or oil. In other words, countries neglect the forgone export revenues that the oil would otherwise bring in when they choose to set the domestic price of energy. Azerbaijan, for example, a country that falls into both of these categories, devotes 13 percent of its GNP to energy subsidies (World Bank, 2000c). Energy subsidies are frequently examined independently from other subsidies such as food, partly because of the scale and partly because the range of instruments for subsidising energy differs from food subsidies. However, it is useful to highlight some key similarities and differences. As with food prices, the incidence of energy subsidies and a first-order approximation of their impact on welfare can be derived from a consumer survey that indicates expenditures on the commodity by income group. Alderman and del Ninno (1999), for example, used such an analysis to find out whether a VAT exemption 70 for kerosene in South Africa would be progressive. In contrast, a kerosene subsidy in Indonesia favoured well-off consumers since the commodity is a necessity rather than an inferior good in urban areas and is virtually unavailable in rural communities (Pitt, 1985). Similarly, in most low-income countries, electricity subsidies would be largely skewed to the well-off since poor households are not connected to the national grid in many areas. This is not the case, however, in much of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe (World Bank 2000b), where energy subsidies can, thus, be more equally distributed. Indeed, where connections to the grid are available, subsidies on electricity usage can be rationed with prices increasing as the amount of electricity used increases. In other countries, governments have set different prices for different neighbourhoods depending on their level of prosperity. While these subsidy mechanisms have counterparts in the area of food subsidies, other means of providing energy subsidies—for example, by abstaining from suspending service for non-payment in the case of poor households or by subsidising connections but not usage—have no such parallel. Other characteristics of energy subsidies, such as the fact that these subsidies may go to producers rather than consumers, are not unique to that sector; yet these are potentially more important in the design of an effective safety net than in the case of other subsidies. As with any general subsidy, there is a danger that untargeted production subsidies may dominate public expenditures on consumer subsidies for the poor. Moreover, the distortions that such subsidies entail give interest groups a reason to oppose such reforms. HOW MUCH DO SUBSIDIES CONTRIBUTE TO STABILISATION? In addition to lowering the cost of food, price subsidies generally reduce price fluctuations as well. Indeed, many governments have stabilisation as their stated 71 objective for introducing subsidies and ration programmes, though few, in fact, concentrate only on price variability without also attempting to lower the mean price. In many economic calculations, the value is low of reducing the variance of prices while preserving the same average price. However, the value of stability may reflect imperfections or frictions in the market. For example, producers acquire and utilise new information at a cost. Similarly, consumers’ habits may make it easier for them to adjust to a price decrease than to a price rise. Moreover, as price fluctuations increase the risk of making investments, they may lead to less than optimal investment in production and storage. Finally, as Timmer (1991 and 1996) has argued, the preference for such stability is revealed in the political marketplace. In many circumstances, a general subsidy can moderate fluctuations in the cost of living. However, in principal, a subsidy that reduces the cost of a good can increase the variability in its price. For example, if a commodity is currently subsidised at half the international price, a 25 percent increase in the world price would lead to a 50 percent increase in the local price if the fluctuation was passed through—that is, if the per unit subsidy remained constant. In contrast, a fixed price, whether generalised or rationed, would stabilise the nominal cost to consumers, but would pass on the instability to the budget. Thus, the potential gains from stabilising wholesale and retail price may be offset by instability transmitted to the macro-economy (Scobie, 1988). A similar situation arises with price stabilisation programmes that use market purchases and releases to keep prices within a given range. It is difficult to provide the operating ministries with an annual budget for these activities since, if run effectively, their costs will be unpredictable. In order to justify keeping prices within this range, ministries must make storage agents commit to buying whatever quantity of the good would be necessary to keep prices above the trigger point. Similarly, storage agents must commit to selling as much as is 72 demanded at the ceiling price that they need to defend. Unlike private traders, they are not able to offset losses that they incur when prices do not rise sufficiently high to cover their storage costs with profits earned in other years. Often, when governments cannot defend a price floor, they often put in a de facto or de jure quota system with the inevitable result that a two-tier market emerges to the disadvantage of smaller producers. Similarly, there have been situations when budgets have been insufficient to produce as much grain as needed for price stabilisation. In these cases, not all traders (or food processors) were given access to stocks in the post-harvest season; instead, access was granted preferentially to middle-income consumers. For example, in Zimbabwe, maize in government storage is more likely to be processed in roller mills than in the cheaper hammer mills. Thus, the cheaper source of maize becomes scarce both as the post-harvest season lengthens and when the amount of domestic production decreases. Thus, the weighted average cost of meal (from both roller and hammer mills) is more volatile than the cost of the grain itself. This is not to say that all stabilisation attempts assist only those fortunate enough to benefit from quotas. Pakistan, for example, has maintained a programme that handles a large share of the marketed surplus and of the wholesale demand for wheat. The government’s storage policies—as well as relatively low variability in production due to an extensive irrigation network— have contributed to comparatively low price variability (Pinckney, 1989). Accepting the desire for inter- as well as intra-annual price stability, Pinckney then indicates the fiscal costs of policies that aim to achieve a desired level of stability. Indonesia has also been among the few countries that have been successful in stabilising prices through its procurement and sales through its logistics agency, BULOG (Timmer, 1991 and 1996). Unlike Pakistan, however, BULOG has traditionally avoided getting involved in direct distribution to households. 73 Instead, it has used the open market. Periodically, it injects supplies of rice into urban markets to put downward pressure on prices. Indonesia’s experience also differs from other countries in that it has at various times imported a sufficiently large share of the rice traded on the world market so that its policies actually affect international prices. Dawe (1998) used the Indonesian Government’s market interventions following the drastic devaluation of the rupiah in 1997 as an illustration of the potential for price stabilisation. Timmer (1996) argued that this kind of stabilisation enhances equity since it provides an environment that encourages investment and this contributes to the macro-economy. However, the interplay of consumer price stabilisation and macro-economic growth is a controversial issue with little empirical evidence, in part because few countries have been successful at stabilising prices. Indeed, to summarise, the benefits of stabilisation are far harder to quantify than are the costs. Nevertheless, there may be substantial macro-economic benefits to finding more efficient ways to achieve a certain degree of price stabilisation. Having said this, even Indonesia had to abandon its use of open market sales to stabilise prices in the wake of the 1997 devaluation. Subsidising rice at well below import prices proved fiscally unsustainable and encouraged smuggling and re-export. However, Indonesia subsequently managed to implement a fairly well targeted safety net consisting of the provision of a quota of subsidised rice to poor households on the basis of a simple formula. Thus, changes in its exchange rate that turned a policy geared to producer subsidies into one that required consumer subsidies prompted Indonesia to institute targeting to achieve its food pricing objectives. THE POLITICS OF SUBSIDY REFORMS Who advocates food policy reform and who resists? (Among the few published case studies or reviews of the process of subsidy reform are Bienen, and 74 Gersovitz (1986), Nelson (1985), Alderman (1988), Tuck and Lindert (1996), Adams (1998), and Chowdhury and Haggblade (2000).) While a few countries have introduced general food subsidies in recent years, many countries have reformed their existing systems. The nature and timing of such reforms depend on many factors, including the interplay of diverse interests expressed by local groups and international agencies. For example, often support for subsidy reform comes from Ministries of Agriculture, which represent farmers’ interests, as opposed to Ministries of Food (or Supply), which represent consumers’ interests. However, these two interests are often allies in lobbying for subsidies as this is an option that allows the reduction of implicit taxation of farmers (or increased subsidies) without increasing consumer prices. Finance Ministries, however, are more likely to see these explicit costs as destabilising the national budget. Other key groups in promoting or resisting food policy reform are food processors and marketers. In the USA, food retailers and processors joined with farm groups in opposition to changing the food stamp programme to an income transfer. The retailers and processors stood to lose 14,000 to 25,000 jobs together with the loss of 3,000 to 6,000 farm sector jobs if there were a 20 billion dollar reduction in total food stamp programme benefits (Kuhn et al, 1996). An early, unsuccessful reform attempt in Bangladesh was stymied by millers. In 1955, the then province of East Pakistan attempted to eliminate rural rations and to lay off the employees of the Civil Supply Department (CSD), only to reverse its decision the following year. Interest groups, such as the CSD workers, are often able to coordinate their efforts since their stake in perpetuating government distribution is comparatively large and their numbers are sufficiently small that each worker can envisage the personal benefits that may accrue from a joint, well-organised response. Yet, the small numbers in each interest group often also implies that these interest groups have to seek allies. In the case of the 75 1955 attempted reform, the CSD workers were able to recruit wider support when the harvest failed and prices began rising. This contrasts with successful reforms in Bangladesh in the 1990s and in Pakistan in the 1980s. In these examples, new coalitions between supply department workers and the general public were formed to oppose the reforms because consumers were receiving few benefits due to poor administration and other leakages and, thus, found little reason to defend their stake (Adams, 1998 and Alderman, 1988). Also, in Bangladesh, the urban ration was curtailed because of a lack of supplies of the subsidised good at the local level. This meant that there was only a narrow margin between the subsidised good and alternative goods, which, again, reduced the value of the programme to consumers, who were, thus, even less inclined to fight to keep it. Market reforms can pre-empt consumer resistance by providing direct benefits that offset the fact that consumers will no longer benefit from the lost subsidies. Zimbabwe’s experience in removing subsidies on roller maize meal in 1993 is one example of this. When the Zimbabwean Government cut its subsidies on roller milled maize, it simultaneously liberalised private milling and trade. The net result was that the cost of meal for poor consumers was lowered since they were able to switch to cheaper hammer-milled meal (Jayne and Jones, 1997). This separated the millers’ interests from those of the wider population and contributed to the public’s acceptance of the reforms. Mismanaged food price reforms weaken governments and often destroy the careers of their advocates. While violent responses occur in the wake of only a minority of food policy reforms and widespread consequences follow in even fewer, most governments are well aware of the potential for this to happen. The riots following a selective raising of commodity prices in Egypt in 1977 are particularly well known; more recently, in 1997, food riots occurred in the wake 76 of currency devaluation (and subsequent increases in the costs of traded commodities) in Indonesia and Zimbabwe. Yet, because these are rarely relative to the number of price changes and systematic reforms that have been introduced, policymakers have an interest in assessing what contributes to public acceptance of reforms. A few general patterns emerge from country experiences. First, the public is more likely to accept a policy change if they are told the rationale behind it, perhaps through advanced publicity. For example, they could be told that the government is seeking to make fiscal savings (presented in concrete terms such as the share of oil revenues, overall taxes, or the number of schools that could be built) or to minimise economic costs such as corruption and the burden on farmers. Early publicity in this regard may prevent some interest groups from hiding their self-interested aims by arguing that the reform will impose hardships on a wider community. To various degrees, this strategy has been used in Bangladesh, Pakistan, and Zimbabwe. The Government of Egypt, which failed to prepare the public for its abolition of subsidies in 1977, regularly compared the cost of the subsidy in the 1980s to the overall size of revenues from the Suez canal in order to impress its magnitude upon the population. Similarly, in Tunisia, which has a history of violent protests against subsidy cuts, the government preceded the reforms in the 1990s by a public relations campaign. The campaign stressed the cost of the system and the services—such as the number of hospital beds—that could be purchased with the same resources. Alternatively, an intense media campaign can be used during the first months of a programme. In Jamaica, generalised food subsidies were replaced by food stamps almost immediately after this change was announced by the 77 Government. In the following six months, an extensive media campaign was run using radio, television, handbills, a public address system, and a series of inserts in a major national newspaper to announce and explain the system and to publicise how the public could sign up for food stamps. Second, Governments can mute opposition to subsidy reform from coalitions of the poor and ideologically motivated groups by introducing credible policies to protect the most vulnerable groups. This does not necessarily have to be in terms of food subsidies as cash transfers can have a similar, or greater, impact on poverty. Nor does it have to consist of direct compensation to all individuals for the costs of the reforms. Indeed, compensation as opposed to redirecting funds is ill-advised; if all groups who lose out as a result of a policy change are compensated fully for their loss, not only will there be no fiscal savings but any mistargeting will be perpetuated. Public acceptance is likely to be enhanced if the Government introduces safeguards for the poor that are perceived to be equitable as well as credible. If the safety net programme is in place at the time when the inefficient programme is reformed, then the Government’s credibility is guaranteed. Constituents can then assess the fairness of the benefits of the safety net as well as the impact of the market reforms. Credibility can also be enhanced if the programme is part of a popular mandate or election manifesto. In some countries, such as Jamaica and Sri Lanka, the reform of untargeted price subsidies was debated in election campaigns. In other countries, the new Government has used the grace period that often follows an election to make reforms in keeping with the party’s election platform. Third, these coalitions of public support may be needed to offset opposition from interest groups who benefit from the subsidies that are due to be abolished. This suggests that Governments need to pay particular attention to institutions and 78 merchants who have a vested interest in the economic distortions that many subsidy programmes create. This is a very different issue than protecting poor consumers who will see their real income decline when food prices rise. Small interest groups tend to be able to mobilise to protect their concentrated benefits. Whenever possible, Governments should try to change administrative structures to shift the economic rents that these groups receive to the general population, even if there are no obvious savings to the treasury. Similarly, reducing many price distortions and indirect subsidies will not yield explicit budgetary savings although the economic gains may be appreciable. Fourth, changes in international prices will influence the costs of a subsidy programme. Often when world prices are low, a food subsidy provides little benefit to the population. This may be an opportunity to change market structures and, thus, allow the Government to consider other options including targeted programmes or income transfers should prices rise. (In India, the Government, evidently, takes no notice of global price movements in dealing with food subsidy – related issues even in respect of foodgrains exports. Ironically, exports take place at prices that are on par with PDS rates for BPL buyers or even less, regardless of a global buoyancy – KSR) The Albanian Government failed to take advantage of one such opportunity in the mid-1990s. While it eliminated many price subsidies and instituted a targeted income transfer in its place as it opened its economy, it neglected to remove administrative price ceilings on bread. For a few years, these ceilings were moot as they were higher than the market price. However, when world grain prices shot up in 1995, in order to defend the ceiling on bread prices, the Government had to put restrictions on flour prices and to provide subsidised wheat to millers. This entire series of interventions were unplanned and expensive. The system of setting prices was eventually scrapped when prices reverted to trend. Had the Government taken this step earlier, it would have been able to compensate poor 79 households for the sharp price through its targeted public assistance programmes. There is less of a consensus on a fifth issue, the pace at which food policy reforms should be introduced. Egypt has been able to reduce the overall costs of its subsidies by making gradual changes in unit costs as well as in the number of products that it subsidises. Whether this can be applied in other contexts, however, is questionable. Some policymakers favour making small price changes because these are too incremental to be likely to provoke organised protests and can be accommodated by comparatively minor adjustments in household budgets. However, repeated price changes may convey the impression that the Government has no plan, or capacity, to hold the line. Thus, the credibility of the Government may be called into question. Moreover, if merchants anticipate price changes, they may withhold their products until the changes are implemented. Also, it is difficult to introduce incremental changes in a targeting system or in the method of distribution. However, there are some steps that can be taken to phase in the overall reform package. As mentioned above, this includes ensuring that there is initial publicity spelling out the rationale for the reform. Similarly, in many circumstances, a new targeted poverty programme can be introduced, or at least piloted, prior to the abolition of the general subsidies. Finally, there is a global tendency to assume that two-tier price structures lead to two tier accounting, in other words, that, over time, ways are found by producers and rent seekers to divert lower priced goods into higher priced channels. Thus, reforms that separate the Government’s role as financier from the market’s role of providing services have the potential to be the most effective reforms and, perhaps for that very reason, are often resisted by an entrenched bureaucracy. If, in addition, Governments recognise that food policy objectives are often achieved more effectively by delivering income support without any direct or 80 indirect ties to food commodities, reforms can be separated from the consumption of a given commodity or use of a given market channel. This increased flexibility often allows for better targeting as well as an increased likelihood that the transfers will result in the poorest beneficiaries being lifted out of poverty. THE PROCESS OF SUBSIDY REFORM IN TUNISIA In Tunisia, fiscal pressures from a food subsidy bill that reached four percent of GDP in 1984 made the food subsidy programme unsustainable. An initial attempt to reduce the budgetary costs of the programme was made in 1984 and subsidies on several food items were eliminated, effectively doubling their prices. Violent riots erupted in response to these sudden reform efforts, forcing officials to rescind the measures and delaying the adoption of significant reforms until the end of the decade. Disturbed by the violent responses to earlier cuts in the programme, the Tunisian Government adopted an innovative approach in 1990 to reduce the budgetary costs of these transfers in a manner that was politically acceptable and that protected the purchasing power and nutritional status of the poor. These reforms self-targeted the food subsidies by (a) shifting subsidies to items that were perceived by consumers as "inferior" (though their nutritional value was preserved) and were, thus, consumed primarily by lower-income groups; and (b) liberalising the sale of unsubsidised higher-quality varieties that appealed to the more well-to-do, who would then consume less of the subsidised foods. Rather than drastically reducing subsidies all of a sudden, the Government introduced the self-targeting reforms (and associated subsidy cuts) gradually by raising the prices of certain goods in some months and others in other months. Also, subsidies on the most sensitive products were reduced during the summer when the students (who were pivotal in the earlier riots) were not in school. The Government also used a media campaign to prepare Tunisians in advance for the 81 reforms and introduced compensating measures to ease political pressure and the impact of adjustment on the poor. The results of these reforms have been impressive. Self-targeting had halved the cost of the programme by 1993 (from four to two percent of GDP). It also improved the incidence of the programme – subsidies benefited the richest groups two times more than the poorest groups in 1985 but by 1993 the poor benefited 1.1 times more than the rich. Self-targeting also protected recipients’ nutritional (caloric) intake more than comparable across – the – board subsidy cuts would have. Finally, widely publicised polls showed that most Tunisians understood, accepted, and agreed with the necessity of the reforms. Source: Tuck and Lindert (1996) Table XXIII An International Comparison of Leakage from Food Subsidy Programmes Type of Programme Country Untargeted Food Subsidies Egypt (early 1980s) Morocco, Tunisia, Yemen Untargeted Food Subsidies Brazil Untargeted Food Rations (i.e., ration shops) India, Pakistan Ration Shops Targeted Geographically Brazil, India Self-targeting Food Rations Bangladesh (sorghum), Pakistan Food Stamps – Targeted by Income Colombia, Sri Lanka (post-1979), United States Food Stamps – Targeted by Health Status Colombia, Indonesia, Honduras Targeted Feeding Programmes Dominican Republic, Colombia, Pakistan Supplementation Schemes – On-site or Take- India, Indonesia home, Preschooler plus Mother Supplementation Scheme – On-site, most India, Tamil Nadu Vulnerable Group Targeting Supplementation Schemes – Take-home, India Nutritionally Vulnerable 82 Leakage to Nonneedy High (60-80%) High (81%) High (50-60%) Low (5-10 %) Low (10-20%) Low-Moderate 30%) (10- Low (3-10%) Negligible Low Moderate (30-60%) Low (3-10%) Low Food-for-work Programmes Bangladesh, India, Low-Moderate (3-35%) Indonesia Targeted Food for Education Programme (free Bangladesh Low (7%) ration for school enrollment of children) Targeted Vulnerable Group Development Bangladesh Low (8-14%) Programme (free ration for training of destitute women) Sources: Subbarao et al (1997), Ahmed (2002), Kennedy and Alderman (1987), Mateus (1983). Types of Price and Tax Subsidies ï‚· Unlimited direct price subsidies ï‚· Tax and VAT exemptions ï‚· Unlimited indirect price subsidies ï‚· Dual exchange rates Export taxes Producer quotas Subsidies on transport and storage Domestic sales below international opportunity cost ï‚· Rational subsidies (quotas) Untargeted parallel market channels for the general population Targeted access to subsidised goods Coupons, vouchers, and stamps [It is certain that as and when – if at all – several drastic changes are made in the food subsidy programme, this will encounter strong resistance from several vested interests – the bureaucracy, farmers and the intended beneficiaries and even more so, those people who take out the benefits in the name of those targeted, ironically because of the latter’s lack of purchasing power. Since 1991, when reforms started the political resistance to subsidy cuts have ensured exclusion of this aspect from the reform agenda itself. India’s comparable experience is nothing to boast of because policy makers have not even dared test the waters – K.S.R.] 83 (X) FROM REPORTS OF EARLIER FINANCE COMMISSIONS NINTH COMMISSION (SECOND REPORT) Subsidies in the Central Budget have been rising rapidly. Subsidies might have to be targeted in future towards the poor only, and with only a moderate rate of inflation it would be possible to adjust issue prices (for foodgrains) when procurement prices are raised. The manner in which the fertiliser subsidy is being determined and granted should be re-examined or else the fertiliser subsidy would become unbearable in the near future. Food, fertiliser and export subsidies account for a major share in the total subsidies in the Central Budget. TENTH COMMISSION There is no justification that can be reasonably adduced for power and irrigation rates to be so heavily subsidised. The Commission recommends that a national consensus on irrigation and power rates should be evolved sooner rather than later, to stem the rot in these sectors. ELEVENTH COMMISSION A major item of expenditure that had grown steadily in the eighties were subsidies. Apart from the subsidies implicit in underpricing of public services, Government budgets also provide subsidies in an explicit form. These formed 1.98 percent of GDP and 18.6 percent of the Centre’s net revenue receipts in 1991-92. Although the level of subsidies had come down to less than 1.5 percent of GDP during 1999-2000, these still formed 14.3 percent of the Centre’s revenue receipts. 84 (XI) FROM EARLIER STUDIES ON CENTRAL SUBSIDIES 1. REPORT OF THE EXPENDITURE REFORMS COMMISSION (A) FERTILISER SUBSIDY 1. Fertiliser subsidies have grown dramatically and continue to increase rapidly. The green revolution technology is now widely accepted and the need to subsidise fertilisers to induce farmers to increase their usage has gone down. 2. The Retention Price Scheme (RPS) has led to the development of a large domestic industry and near self-sufficiency. However, the unit wise RPS is a cost plus scheme. It results in high cost fertilisers, excess payments to industry and provides no incentives to be cost efficient. Moreover, it is extremely difficult, if not impossible, to administer it without these disadvantages. 3. The fertiliser policy needs to be reformed. The goal of the new policy should be to eventually bring fertiliser prices charged to farmer to the level of import parity price. It should protect small farmers’ real incomes, but not lead to a slump in food production and also promote a balanced use of N, P and K. At the same time, the RPS needs to be dismantled and replaced by an easily enforceable system that provides incentives to manufacturers to be cost efficient, and ensures a desired level of self-sufficiency with minimal support from the Government. 4. A sudden increase in farm-gate price of urea to import parity price, without increasing procurement prices, could lead to a fall of 13.5 million tonnes of foodgrains production. This is, thus, not a feasible option. 85 5. If procurement prices are raised along with farm-gate prices of fertilisers, the fall would be much smaller. However, small and marginal farmers, for whom self-consumption is a large part of their output, would suffer a loss in their real incomes. They should be protected. Two possible ways are: (a) Introduction of a dual price scheme under which all cultivator households are given 120 kgs of fertilisers at subsidised prices and (b) Expansion of Employment Guarantee Scheme and rural works programmes to provide additional incomes to small farmers. If such rural programmes are directed towards improvement of land and development of minor irrigation schemes, they will in addition to providing wage income, increase productivity of land and income to farmers even when fertiliser prices are increased. 7. A complete decontrol of the producer price for urea would have been possible, were all our plants based on natural gas as feedstock. Unfortunately, only 56 percent of domestic capacity is gas-based, 22 percent naphtha-based, 9 percent fuel oil-based and 12 percent is mixed feedstock-based, mostly naphtha and natural gas. 8. A sudden freeing of the urea industry could lead to most naphtha-based units having to close down, as even their short run variable costs would be higher than the import price. The resultant surge in the demand for imports would push up import prices to levels which would lead to a much higher quantum of subsidy than now, if the demand is to be maintained at 21 million tonnes of urea. 9. Since availability of natural gas is limited, a good proportion of the production has to be based on other feedstock if a certain level of self-sufficiency is to be maintained. These plants would have to be compensated for their higher cost of feedstock. 86 10. The best possible alternative at present is imported liquefied natural gas (LNG). 11. In the circumstances, the Commission recommends the dismantling of the control system in a phased manner, leading at the commencement of fourth stage, to a decontrolled fertiliser industry, which can compete with import, albeit with a small level of protection and a feedstock cost differential compensation to naphtha/LNG based units to ensure self-sufficiency. The transition, however, has to be gradual. 12. The transition begins with the discontinuation of the RPS with effect from February 1, 2001, and introduction of a group-wise concession scheme. The number of groups is reduced from five to two by April 1, 2006. At this stage, all units except those that are based on naphtha/LNG would be viable at a price of about Rs. 7,000 per tonne of urea. For naphtha/LNG – based units, a Feedstock Differential Cost Reimbursement (FDCR) of Rs. 1,900 per tonne of urea will be given. The details of the various stages are as follows: (i) In the first phase beginning February 1, 2001, the following will be done: (a) The existing units will be grouped into 5 categories – pre-1992 gas based units, post – 1992 gas based units, naphtha – based units, FO/LSHS – based units and mixed feedstock units. The individual retention price scheme will be scrapped and in its place a Urea Concession Scheme with a fixed amount of concession for each of these groups will be introduced. At the same time, plants would be free to get feedstock from wherever they want including imports. (b) The distribution control mechanism will be done away with. 87 (c) The maximum retail price arrangement will be continued, the concessions for each group being so calibrated as to enable the units to sell at the stipulated maximum retail price. (d) Having regard to the large fluctuations in the import prices of feedstock, it will be necessary to re-determine the concession to these groups of units every three months with reference to the prevailing import prices. When there is a reduction in the import parity prices of this feedstock, the concession payable to the units would go down. It may be noted that this, however, is done only group-wise and not plant-wise. Whenever there is an increase in the import parity prices of this feedstock, the additional costs should be passed on to the consumers through a suitable increase in the maximum retail price so that the total amount payable by way of concessions does not go up significantly. The revision in issue price to farmers, however, should be done every season rather than every three months. (ii) In the second stage, beginning 1st April 2002, the concessions are reduced to reflect the possibility of reasonable improvement in feedstock usage efficiencies and reduction in capital-related charges. (iii) The third phase will begin on 1st April 2005 and reflects the feasibility of all non-gas based plants to modernise and switch over to LNG. For plants, which do not switch over to LNG as feedstock, only the level of concession that the unit would have been entitled to if it had switched over to LNG would be allowed. (iv) The fourth phase begins on 1.4.2005 when the industry is decontrolled. The Commission recommends a 7 percent increase in the price of urea in real terms every year from 1.4.2001. This way the open market price will reach Rs. 6,903 by 1.4.2006, a level at 88 which the industry can be freed from all controls and be required to compete with imports, with a variable levy ensuring availability of such imports at the farm-gate at Rs. 7,000 per tonne of urea. While no concessions will be necessary from this date onwards for gas-based, FO/LSHS and mixed feedstock plants, existing naphtha plants converting to LNG, as also new plants and substantial additions to existing plants, will be entitled to a feedstock differential with that for LNG plants serving as a ceiling. The schedule of concessions are shown in the Table XXIV. Table XXIV: Schedule of concessions Feedstock 1st stage concession (Rs./MT) Based on Savings existing RPS import II Stage at Net IV Stage 1.4.2002 to 1.4.2005 to from Parity concession and domestic Price 1.2.2001 to Price 31.3.2002 of III Stage Inputs 31.3.2005 31.3.2006 1.4.2006 (Rs./MT) 1 2 3 4 5 6 Pre-1992 1,300 0 1,300 1,050 800 0 Post-1992 2,900 0 2,900 2,450 2,000 0 Naphtha 8,400 1,900 6,500 5,800 3,900 1,900 FO/LSHS 6,400 3,250 3,150 2,200 2,200 0 Mixed feedstock 4,000 600 3,400 3,000 2,450 0 Natural Gas New Plants: Non-gas based new plants or substantial additions to existing plants would be given appropriate feedstock differential subject to the feedstock differential for LNG plants acting as the ceiling. 89 NOTES: (a) The concessions in column (1) are so determined that along with the net receipt of Rs. 4,000 from the farm-gate price of Rs. 4,600, the concession gives nearly the weighted average retention price to each group. (b) Column (3) shows the savings that can result in stage I, if feedstock is at import parity prices. Freeing of imports will ensure that plants get the feedstock at such prices by February 1, 2001. (c) The reduction in column (4) compared to column (3) reflects change in feedstock use efficiency in stage II. Modest achievable targets have been assumed and plants are expected to attain them by 31st March, 2002. (d) Column (5) reflects the concession in the third stage, incorporating the further reduction on account of non-gas based units switching over to LNG as feedstock. (e) Column (6) reflects the concession, by way of feedstock differential, only in the fourth stage commencing 1.4.2006 when the industry is decontrolled and imports are made available at Rs. 7,000 per tonne at the farm-gate. (f) In all the three stages, the final concession levels, as determined, also take into account the progressive reduction in capital recovery charges. 90 (g) The Commission has recommended a price increase of seven percent per annum from 1.4.2001, reaching Rs. 7,000 on 1.4.2006. To the extent of price increase in earlier years, the concession indicated in columns 3, 4 and 5 would stand reduced. 14. The schedule of subsidy outlay under various stages is given in Table XXV. Table XXV: Urea subsidy outlay in different phases (Rs. Crores/year) a) No increase in issue 2000- 2001- 01 02 2002-05 2005- Apr. 1,2006 06 onwards price Farm-gate price – Rs./mt of urea 4,600 4,600 4,600 4,600 4,600 Concession to Industry 9,155 7,204 6,159 4,656 5,837 Farm-gate price – Rs./mt of urea 4,600 4,922 5,267 to 6,030 6,452 7,000 Concession to industry (net) 9,155 6,556 4,817 to 3,280 927 1,004 270 560 1,556 2,016 b) Increase in issue price @ 7% p.a. c) Cost of coupon system: Coupons to 105 million farmers At 80 kgs of urea per family to be supplied at Rs. 4,600 per Mt to - 1,201 PHOSPHATIC AND POTASSIC FERTILISERS: 15. The farm-gate prices of nitrogenous, phosphatic and potassic fertilisers should be set to promote a desired balance of fertiliser use. In the circumstances, the ERC will only suggest that once the urea price is redetermined every six months, the prices of potassic and phosphatic fertilisers should be suitably adjusted, as advised by the Ministry of Agriculture, to ensure the desired NPK balance. It will be useful if the Government could announce in 91 advance the formula to be adopted for fixing the prices of P & K fertilisers with reference to a given urea price. 16. Phosphatic fertilisers are already decontrolled and operated with a concession scheme. With one more unit commissioned in 2000 for the manufacture of 1.5 million tonnes of DAP based on imported rock phosphate and sulphur, the proportion of DAP manufactured – based on imported ammonia and imported phosphoric acid – will go down sharply. The appropriateness of continuing with the present arrangement of giving an uniform rate of subsidy to all the units, with reference to the cost of production of DAP – based on imported ammonia and imported phosphoric acid – needs to be examined preferably by the Tariff Commission. GENERAL 17. The arrangements for the payment of concessions to industrial/importing firms need to be streamlined so as to ensure payment of the amounts due to the units within three to four weeks from the time of sales. Once such arrangements are in place, then in the case of urea also the payment of concessions could be shifted from ‘despatch’ to ‘sales’. 18. As it is basically a question of dealing with industrial units – at least in the case of DAP – these subsidies should appropriately be administered by the Ministry of Chemicals and Fertilisers, along with the concessions for the urea units. The Ministry of Agriculture will continue to have a major role in the fixation of the maximum retail/indicative prices for all types of fertilisers, be it N or P or K. 19. The Commission recommends that if a state government imposes any additional burden, by way of excessive levies on the inputs or on finished 92 fertilisers manufactured/sold in the state, then these costs should be passed on to the farmers in the state. TO CONCLUDE: 20. The Commission wishes to emphasise that the suggested scheme to take the fertiliser industry on to a liberalised competitive set-up: - Retains self-sufficiency - Preserves viability of existing units - Protects small farmers - Reduces subsidy outlay and - Is implementable. (B) FOOD SUBSIDY 5. While examining the food subsidy bill, which has increased from Rs. 19.91 crore in 1948-49 to Rs. 9,200 crore in the Revised Estimates for 1999-2000 and to Rs. 8,100 crores in the 2000-01 budget, it would, therefore, be necessary to undertake the study in a disaggregated manner adopting the following structure: (a) Consumer Subsidy – i.e. subsidy incurred on the supply of foodgrains through the PDS at below FCI’s economic cost. (In this report, the budgetary concept of subsidy has been adopted in preference to that of determining the subsidy as the difference between world trade prices and the PDS sale price). (b) Cost of buffer stock operations – (i) Of this, one part is the cost related to maintaining a minimum level of buffer stock as dictated by the national food security requirements; (ii) Cost of holding stocks in excess of the food security and PDS requirements is the 93 second part. This could appropriately be termed the producers’ subsidy, as it is the direct off-shoot of the price support – based procurement operations; and (c) The inefficiencies of the FCI, i.e. costs in excess of the permissible limits in its various operations, which, thanks to the present full cost reimbursement arrangements, translates into higher costs to the consumer and to the Government. 6. The need for such a disaggregated analysis becomes self-evident when one looks at the emerging requirements. First, at the 2000-01 sale price to the BPL population, the consumer subsidy bill could go up to Rs. 7,500 crore when the off-take reaches 14 million tonnes. Second, with the total stock levels touching 44 million tonnes, the average buffer stock 2000-01 could be around 17 million tonnes imposing a carrying cost burden of around Rs. 3,100 crore on the Government, even when estimated on the basis of the present methodology. Third, the cost incurred by FCI on transport, storage, interest, staff overheads etc. will be a staggering Rs. 6,500 crore, a level at which even if some savings could be effected in each of the operations the net result will be a substantial saving for the PDS consumer and for the Government. 7. The foodgrains production level of over 200 million tonnes, stocks of around 44 million tonnes with the FCI, and a comfortable foreign exchange balance, all taken together provide a window of opportunity for a thorough examination of the food policy package, in the quest for containing the burgeoning food subsidy bill within acceptable levels. 8. As far as consumer subsidy is concerned, commencing from the statutory rationing system that prevailed at the time of Independence, there have been major changes in the PDS. For most of the period, and until 1992, the PDS was 94 a general entitlement scheme at a slightly subsidised rate to all consumers without any specific target. Then came the revamped public distribution scheme in 1992 under which foodgrains were made available with a higher element of subsidy to people in tribal, drought prone and desert areas spread over 1,775 blocks. This scheme was replaced in 1997 by the Targeted PDS, under which 10 kg. of foodgrains was allotted per family per month for the below poverty line (BPL) population at highly subsidised rates while the foodgrains supplied to the above poverty line (APL) population also carried an element of subsidy, though at a much reduced level. From 2000-01 onwards, the sections of the population below the poverty line are to be given 20 kg. per family per month at half the economic cost while the sale to all others is to be only at the economic cost. In other words, the subsidy is limited to only supplies made to the BPL population. When the total off-take on this account reaches 14 million tonnes, then the total consumer subsidy works out to about Rs. 7,500 crore. The Government has announced fairly liberal allocations of foodgrains to be sold to below the poverty line as well as above the poverty line population in the drought affected areas at half the economic cost. If such an allocation is also taken into account, the consumer subsidy could go up to Rs. 8,000-8,500 crore depending on the offtake. The two major policy changes from the past are the targeting of the subsidy to only the below poverty line sections and indexing the sale price to these sections as a proportion (50%) of the economic cost. 9. More important than the total subsidy is the question whether this subsidy actually reaches the intended beneficiaries in full. To start with, the difference between the sale price to the BPL population and others being quite large – 50% - the tendency for diversion of these stocks could increase. Then, there is considerable unevenness in the reach of the PDS among the States. More importantly, while the below poverty line population is estimated for the country as a whole and for each state and region on the basis of consumption surveys, the attempt at the state level is to identify these categories only on the basis of 95 incomes. Further, the efforts under the PDS in many states is to cater to as large a section of the population as possible with emphasis on metropolitian and urban areas, instead of limiting the subsidised supplies only to the targeted sections. A major, independent survey conducted recently has come up with the finding that “the PDS is untargeted”, that “it has an urban bias”, that “in rural India 17 percent do not own ration cards”, that “18 percent of the below poverty line households do not own ration cards” etc. Possibly, it is a politically sensitive area as any attempt to give subsidies to only certain targeted sections of the people, however poor and deserving they may be, could well alienate large sections of the people who may be only slightly better off. Given the limitation of resources, there has, however, to be a concerted effort to target the subsidies to the poorest of the poor even if large sections of the population are to be considered to be poor. Seeking to cover much larger sections of the population, at highly subsidised rates, might appear an easier option, but is definitely not a sustainable proposition even in the short term. It is necessary not only to constantly refine and update the estimate of the size of the population below the poverty line in each state, so that the Centre has better estimates for allocation of foodgrains to meet the requirements of these sections in full in all the states but also build a consensus at the political level that subsidies need to be better targeted and administrative arrangements devised to ensure that the subsidised supplies do in fact reach the targeted sections. The Food-for-Work Programme and the Employment Guarantee Schemes possibly secure better targeting, but their coverage tends to be inadequate because of limitation of resources. Total coverage of those tribal, drought prone and desert areas, where the proportion of the below the poverty line sections is significantly high, say over 80 percent, could be another element of such an action plan. The association of grassroots level empowered bodies like Gram Sabhas and NGOs with a proven track record in the task of identifying the poorest of the poor and in supervising the actual delivery of benefits to the targeted sections might help. Giving wide publicity to the arrival of the 96 foodgrains at the local PDS outlet is a method successfully adopted in some states. It is only when a fully targeted delivery system is in place, would this subsidy stand fully justified on merits. 10. Thus, in the final analysis, there is no escape from identifying the BPL population family-wise, giving each a ration card, have a PDS that reaches every village and putting in arrangements, like supervision of actual distribution by Gram Sabhas, NGOs etc, to ensure that the targeted sections do actually get the foodgrains allotted for them and at the prices announced by the Government. This responsibility rests squarely with the state governments. The Government of India, on its part, should extend all assistance to the states in the early completion of the above tasks, say within the next two years. Equally important, the Government of India also needs to ensure that adequate stocks of foodgrains are available at all FCI depots to meet the allocations made for the BPL population in full. There is considerable variation among the states in the yardsticks adopted for defining the poorer sections of the population eligible for subsidised foodgrains through the PDS. Throughout this report, the term ‘BPL population’ is used as defined in the Lakdawala Committee report and adopted by the Government of India when announcing in the 2000-01 budget that such families would be allocated 20 kg. of foodgrains per month at half of FCI’s economic cost. 11. As far as the supplies to BPL population are concerned, there is a need to ensure that these sections get these at the same price throughout the year and in whichever part of the county they are located. For this purpose, it becomes necessary to first determine the economic cost for the year as a whole, ironing out the differences that crop up due to differences in transport cost, storage and interest costs. However, as far as the open market operations of the FCI are concerned there could be a case for having some flexibility in determining the sale price. Likewise, when there is pressure on open market prices, the FCI 97 would be undertaking bulk sales and auctions. Such sales should be at the “economic cost” only, without there being any attempt at making a profit, taking advantage of the situation. Similarly, with a view to liquidating excess stocks the FCI could seek to export or sell domestically large quantities at prices below the economic costs. It is but appropriate that all these stocks which are sold at some point or other at prices, lower than the economic cost, are considered part of buffer stocks and not as part of distribution stocks when determining the economic cost, at 50% of which foodgrains are to be issued to the BPL population. The Expenditure Reforms Commission would, therefore, suggest that only the quantities to be sold through the PDS to the BPL and APL population and at the economic cost (technically, for FCI, the sales to the BPL population are also at the economic cost, with the Government picking up 50 percent of the bill by way of subsidy) be treated as distribution stocks while determining the economic cost. 12. In those states, where a quantity larger than the allocation made by Government of India for the BPL population in that state is distributed through the PDS at prices equal to or less than half of FCI’s economic cost, the Government of India could well make available to the states the cash equivalent of the subsidy involved in distributing foodgrains to the BPL population at half the economic cost. This way the state government would be free to take the foodgrains required for the BPL population either from the FCI or procure it directly or through traders either in its own state or from outside. This flexibility is recommended as there is a widely held perception that FCI’s overheads are quite high, thus pushing up the economic cost. To the extent a state government is able to procure at lower than FCI’s economic cost and use it for meeting the requirements of the BPL population, it would be able to effect savings in the subsidy amounts made available by the Government of India. This should serve as an incentive to the states to undertake procurement in their own 98 account and such ‘competition’, in turn, would also force FCI to improve its efficiency and reduce costs. 13. However, in the case of states where the PDS sales to BPL population are currently below the quantities earmarked for, the present arrangement of making available the foodgrains required, based on the consumption norms in the earlier year, should be continued along with strict monitoring on the one hand to guard against misuse or diversion of foodgrains to other sections and encouragement on the other to secure better coverage of the targeted sections. The moment the PDS coverage exceeds the quantities as required for the BPL population and it is established that the sale price is at or below half the FCI’s economic cost, then these states could also be made entitled to the arrangement suggested of receiving, in cash, the amount equivalent to the subsidy involved in providing foodgrains at half the FCI’s economic cost to the BPL population in their jurisdiction. 14. The second major element in the total food subsidy bill is the cost of carrying buffer stocks. This consists of two parts. The first part relates to buffer stocks so very necessary for providing a food security cover the country, particularly given the vagaries of the monsoon. The estimate of the buffer stock to be so held has, however, varied from time to time. The Technical Group constituted in 1981 by the Department of Food under the then Food Secretary recommended that the size of the buffer stock to be maintained by the public agencies should be 10 million tonnes (5 million tonnes each of wheat and of rice), which would be in addition to the operational stocks required for the PDS. A more recent study (July 1999) by Prof. Kirti Parikh of the Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai, confirmed that a buffer stock level of around 10 million tonnes could be considered adequate from the National Food Security angle even today, notwithstanding the increase in population in the last two decades. The level of stocks could be considered as “insurance 99 requirement”. Unfortunately, the picture gets confused as FCI, in its documents, uses the phrase ‘buffer stock’ in the larger context which includes the base stocks (about 1 million tonnes or so distributed in small quantities over a large number of depots and which cannot be accessed quickly for meeting the requirements at any one point of time or place), the operational stocks estimated at 1/3rd of the total required for distribution, mostly through the PDS and the balance of stocks which is also termed ‘buffer stocks’. Given the large proportion of people depending on the PDS and also given the vagaries of the monsoon, the Expenditure Reforms Commission would strongly recommend that a level of 10 million tonnes (4 million tonnes of wheat and 6 million tonnes of rice) be always kept as food security buffer stock. The Commission further noted: “As the excess stocks are solely due to the very generous minimum support price-based procurement policy being followed by the Government, the cost of holding these stocks could be considered a subsidy to the producers and reflected as such in the budget”. The report of the Commission was critical of the sharp increases in support prices annually and pointed out that the minimum support price was becoming the maximum support price and that the FCI had become the buyer of the first resort instead of being, as was originally intended, the buyer of the last resort. 2. CAG REPORT ON PDS According to the report covering the period 1992-99, the PDS had several short comings, the most significant being targeting inefficiencies. Leakages were widespread. In effective implementation, poor administrative arrangements and a blurred accountability structure impaired the effectiveness of delivery. The distribution infrastructure and the quality of foodgrains supplied needed significant improvement. Besides, under PDS, the per capita entitlement was in adequate and per capita off-take was still worse. It delivered food at a highly 100 subsidised cost to the poor in the states, which provided additional subsidy, but state governments, which had the highest population of the poor and incidence of poverty, did not fully utilise PDS. This impacted on the efficiency of PDS. This was its assessment. 2. GOVERNMENT SUBSIDIES IN INDIA By Prof. D.K. Srivastava and Dr. Tapas K. Sen, NIPFP, 1997. The thrust of the background study prepared for the discussion paper brought out by the Union Ministry of Finance in May 1997 (later updated into this book) was on merit and non-merit subsidies. It drew attention to the massive draft Government subsidies in India constituted on the nation’s budgetary resources. The study noted that even if a reduction of five percentage points in the nonmerit subsidies to GDP ratio was brought about, the fiscal deficit to GDP would be brought to a level below two percent. Specifically on petroleum subsidies, the study observed that apart from the huge volume of subsidy, differential rates of subsidy over the entire range of petroleum products also induced distortions in the relative use of different petroleum products having serious implications for allocative efficiency. On food subsidy, the study pointed out that the PDS was poorly targeted and the magnitude of the subsidy actually enjoyed by the poor was very small. It drew attention to extensive leakages and to the fact that the operation of procurement, storage, transportation and distribution was quite costly and had become more inefficient over time. Dealing with the fertiliser subsidy, the study took note of the fact that the burden was considerable. Yet, it recognised that a reduction in the use of fertilisers might have a serious adverse impact on agricultural production. It cited an estimate made in 1991 by Sidhu & Sidhu that a 30 percent hike in the real price of fertiliser would lead to a 18 percent decline in fertiliser consumption and, thereby, a 5.4 percent fall in foodgrains production. The study noted that in the Central budget, explicit subsidies accounted for only 101 30 percent of the total Central subsidies during 1994-95, pointing to the massive magnitude of hidden/implicit subsidies that the exchequer had to bear. 4. CENTRAL BUDGETARY SUBSIDIES IN INDIA By Prof. D.K. Srivastava & Dr. H.K. Amarnath of NIPFP (2001) The study suggested that subsidy reduction could be approached through (i) reducing Government participation in the provision of a service (ii) improving targeting and (iii) increasing recoveries and reducing inefficiency, thereby reducing per unit cost. 5. SUBSIDIES: PIERCING THE VEIL By K.S. Ramachandran (1997) This book based on a research project prepared for the Economic & Scientific Research Foundation made projections of both explicit and hidden subsidies for several major heads and set the agenda for phasing out both kinds of subsidies over a limited period. 102 (XII) WINDING UP At the point of concluding, one cannot but feel that this study would have been rendered unnecessary if only the Government had acted on the various recommendations of the Expenditure Reforms Commission, especially those pertaining to the food subsidy and the entire gamut of public procurement operations, the public distribution system and the price support mechanism. The Commission had been blunt in responding to the manner in which issues of food security were handled year after year and all the waste that was encouraged in the name of ensuring easy and economical access to food of the poor segments of the nation’s population. The Commission deemed only 10 million tonnes of foodgrains (6 million tonnes of rice and 4 million tonnes of wheat) necessary for the purpose of food security buffer stock. The average stock needed for managing the PDS, in its assessment, was only 7 million tonnes annually. The total average stock necessary was put at 24 million tonnes. It wanted a freeze of the minimum support price for wheat and paddy. The Commission was critical of excess stocks and even more so of the “very generous” minimum support price-based procurement policy. It pointed out that elimination of buffer stocks would lead to a saving of Rs. 1,300 crore annually by way of carrying costs. The Commission was concerned about leakages in the PDS and demanded a concerted effort to target the subsidies to the poorest of the poor. This concern has also been ignored. In a bitter attack on the system of support prices, this august body noted that the minimum support price was, in fact, becoming the maximum support price and that the FCI had become the buyer of the first resort instead of being the buyer of the last resort as it should be. It advocated moderation of the annual increase in price as a step towards bringing in state governments and the private sector back into the picture. The Commission wanted the Government to announce in advance that in the event of a drop in 103 foodgrains production in any year it would resort to imports to meet the requirements. This study for the 12th Finance Commission looks at the most economically vulnerable segment of the population – the weakest of the weak and the poorest of the poor. The Expenditure Commission acknowledged that the cost of holding stocks in excess of food security and PDS requirements could appropriately be called the producer’s subsidy as it was the direct off-shoot of price support-based procurement operations. However, it did not seek to narrow down the ambit of PDS to a critical sub-sector of the BPL segment, which, indeed, is the thrust of this study. The World Bank shares this perception of the Commission, but it also stops well short of seeking to reduce drastically the reach of PDS. The real problem segment is the one constituted by people at the destitution level, which means that the PDS has to be strongly supported by a mechanism that would provide the necessary purchasing power by way of a sustained generation of employment and income. This is not in the terms of reference of the study. Yet, without effective poverty alleviation, any reform of PDS-related issues may not serve any useful purpose. This has to be underscored. On fertiliser, policymakers do have to address imperative of global cost and quality competitiveness among the different domestic producers, so as to facilitate growth of export orientation over a period, though, quite obviously, the sooner the better. From only subsidising imports, the policy must shift to making exports a serious possibility. There must be both exports and imports depending upon the international price situation. Going back to Chapter-VII, apart from urea which is the prime candidate for regular and growing overseas sale, DAP, SSP and MOP must be given a competitive edge. On imports, who can (or should) gloss over the massive scandal in urea imports perpetrated National Fertilisers Limited in 1994-95? No meaningful reform, obviously, can proceed on 104 the basis of an one-sided trade policy. If exports acquire as much importance as imports the nation’s policy priorities, irregularities should get minimised. K. S. Ramachandran Monday, April 12, 2004 105