Ideas, Interests, Institutions and Information: Jagdish Bhagwati and the Political Economy of Trade Policy1 B. Peter Rosendorff Associate Professor of International Relations and Economics, Director of the Center for International Studies, University of Southern California2 In his magnificent little book, Protectionism (1988), Jagdish Bhagwati gives a concise, eloquent summary of the arguments and the 20th century history of free trade and its antithesis, protectionism. Jagdish, in his inimitable way, demolishes the arguments of the anti-globalists in a mere 130 pages. Jagdish uses as a framework in the book what I might call the “Three I’s of International Political Economy”: Ideas, Interests and Institutions. “Ideas”, of course, refer to the scholarly and public policy discussions, and the observed examples, of free trade and its effects; “interests” are about identifying who the gainers and losers are from policy shifts, and the “institutions” are the fora in which negotiations take place (and within which conflict is managed and mitigated) over these policy issues. These three I’s (or some subset of them), identified by Jagdish as crucial in understanding the historical ebb and flow of protectionism in the 20th century have been borrowed by many scholars, both economists and political scientists since then (see, for instance Destler 1992, Garrett and Weingast 1993, Irwin and Krozner 1999, Milner and Rosendorff 1997, Varshney 1988 among many others). In this talk, I want to Highlight some of the insights that Jagdish developed linking the three I’s with observed protectionist/free trade outcomes Offer a brief review of where those sign pointers Jagdish provided have taken us Argue that perhaps it is time to add a fourth I to the list: Information 1 Prepared for presentation at the Conference in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati on the occasion of his 70 th birthday at Columbia University, New York, August 5-6, 2005. 2 Center for International Studies, University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA 90089-0037. Ideas, Interests, Institutions, Information: Rosendorff I. Bhagwati’s Three I’s The three legs of the tripod interact with each other in crucial ways, and much of Jagdish’s work has been to highlight the role of ideas, as they interact with interests and institutions to address the core questions of the research program. Jagdish has without doubt been an extraordinary contributor to the “ideas” part of the story. His contributions on welfare effects of lobbying and other “Directly Unproductive Profit-seeking” (DUP) activities (1982) are now well-known. The key insight here is that lobbying activities designed either to extract a protective device (tariff-seeking), or to have any revenues from protection awarded to the lobbyers (revenue-seekers) expend resources that might otherwise have gone to more productive activities, and hence are socially wasteful; the crucial caveat here of course, is that if there is a pre-existing distortion is in place, the shadow price of the withdrawn resources could be negative, leading paradoxically to a social welfare improvement (1980, with T.N. Srinivasan). While this is probably a curiosity, the overall impression is that lobbying in international trade policymaking is socially harmful. In a clever piece (1982 with Rob Feenstra), an institutional norm is added to the mix – if there is a rule that commits the government to give any tariff revenues earned back to the import-competing industry then the efficient lobby will pressure for a lower tariff than otherwise, and welfare may improve if tariff revenues exceed lobbying costs. Nevertheless, the overall impression one draws from this work is that lobbying efforts are more likely than not socially harmful even if they are beneficial to those interests engaged in the efforts. The Bhagwati approach takes the interests of the players (lobbyists want protection and revenues, governments want social welfare maximization) as given, and interacts these interests with rules that govern lobbying (the institutions) to understand the policy outcomes and their attendant welfare effects. Later work focused more closely on the institutions leg of the tripod – here the institution of concern is the multilateral negotiating arena of the GATT, later to become the WTO, and its relationships with the regional and other preferential trading arrangements. Others will talk in more detail about the Jagdish’s study of these institutional arrangements, but Jagdish clearly reserved his most crucial policy advice on the design and architecture of the international trade policymaking institutions, highlighting the need to keep policymaking insulated from protectionist interests, while at the same time creating the optimal environment for multilateral and sometimes Page 2 of 8 Ideas, Interests, Institutions, Information: Rosendorff unilateral tariff reduction. (1990, 1991). And of course, Jagdish has led the charge in the debate as to whether joining a regional trade agreement helps or hinders the goal of multilateral free trade (1993). II. The Age of Bhagwati (Samuelson 1996) Jagdish’s students and colleagues embellished this agenda by providing further analytical detail to the three I’s and their role in explaining the variables of interest – welfare effects, level and type of protection and identifying the beneficiaries of protection. Bhagwati offers a number of ways of conceptualizing the objective function of the policymaker, which mirrors the approaches now taken in the American Politics literature. The “Puppet” government is the pure social welfare maximizing government, parroting the often shrill claim of the economist – liberalize, do not succumb to special interests, and apply tariffs on in the rare instances where first best strategies to eliminate the distortion (domestic or international are not available), or there are sound welfare-theoretic reasons for doing so – infant industries, monopoly power in trade etc. The “self-willed” government corresponds to the policy-driven objective function from the politics literature, in which the government has its own objective function – not driven by welfare or pluralist politics, or concerns about reelection or survival in office. The third type, more resembling observed government behavior, is what Jagdish calls the “Clearinghouse” government – where the government attempts to manage the competing claims of often opposed interests, and, usually driven by concerns about survival in office, and must make policy in the face of pluralist politics. In the language of the political science, policymakers are both office (or political support) and policy-motivated. Early approaches adopting the clearinghouse model include Findlay and Wellisz (1982), Mayer (1984), Magee Brock and Young (1989) but government in these is barely more than a black box, producing trade policy from a tariff production function. Grossman and Helpman (1994, 1995) adopt an objective function that is the weighted sum of social welfare and campaign contributions, money presumably important to finance election campaigns. Here, given that some sectors are organized and others are not, the level of lobbying activity (in this context, the level of campaign contributions) is determined endogenously, as is the level of protection. Organized sectors are protected (or subsidized) when neither all nor none of the sectors are organized, and the level that an organized sector receives depends on the level of output relative to imports and the import demand Page 3 of 8 Ideas, Interests, Institutions, Information: Rosendorff elasticity. Mitra (1999) using this model as a baseline endogenizes the decision to “organize” providing a crucial answer to the “who gets protected question”. Nevertheless, government here too is largely a reduced form. Institutional features of the polity are missing, and certainly cross-country variations in these institutions have not been adequately considered. Rodrik (1995) observes the paucity of work on the cross-country variation in the levels of protection, and identifies that institutions matter in this context (p. 1484). Scholars in international relations and comparative politics have, on the other hand, focused intently on “institutions”, both domestic and international, and this has recently been picked up by the economists. The international institutions of interest include, of course, the GATT/WTO and recent work by Bagwell and Staiger (1999, 2002) explores the architectural elements of the agreement – nondiscrimination and reciprocity, and show how these lead to more efficient tariff setting rules. Others will talk about the contributions to the regionalism debate, but this includes Bagwell and Staiger (1997), Krishna (1998) and Levy (1997). But most significantly, economists have largely ignored the importance of domestic political institutions and their importance for trade. On the domestic side, while Jagdish has always stressed the need for domestic policy makers to be insulated from political pressure to assure freer trade policies, variations across domestic political institutions has been shown to matter for the level of trade barriers and the willingness of countries to cooperate on tariff reduction. In particular, the regime types with separation of powers and electoral accountability behave differently to systems absent those features when it comes to trade policy. Democracies are, in general, characterized by these features, which turn out to be influential in the trade-liberalizing tendencies of these regimes. Some results in this vein: 1. Pairs of democracies are more likely to negotiate to lower tariff bindings than mixed dyads. (Mansfield et al. 2000) 2. Democracies are more cooperative with respect to their willingness to join tariff-reducing PTAs (Mansfield et al. 2002) 3. Democracies have a greater tendency to unilateral liberalization; (Rosendorff 2005b) 4. Democracies are better able to extract concessions (in the form of reduced tariffs) from their trading partners than are non-democracies. (Rosendorff 2005b). Page 4 of 8 Ideas, Interests, Institutions, Information: Rosendorff This is consistent in some sense with the broader facts from international relations that democracies to cooperate along a variety of dimensions: they fight fewer wars with each other, or with autocracies than do autocracies with each other (Morrow et al 1998), or to recognize and enforce one another’s laws. More recent work examines the variations in the type of democracies for trade policy outcomes. Grossman and Helpman (2004) establish that majoritarian democracies have a protectionist bias, while with a student of mine, we have established that presidential systems are more protectionist on average than are parliamentary systems (Doces and Rosendorff 2005). Rogowski (1987) argues that PR systems with large electoral districts is a system more conducive to lower trade barriers than majoritarian systems with small districts; McGillivray (1997) argues that as to which districts/sectors get protection depends on the degree of party discipline operative within the political system – high party discipline democracies lead more easily towards protection for widely dispersed industries in safe districts; low party discipline leads concentrated industries in marginal districts to have more lobbying power for protection, and this explains differences in US-Canada patterns of protection rather well. Within the US variation across time in the degree of divided government leads to variations in the degree to which congress is willing to delegate trade policy making to the executive branch (Lohmann and O’Halloran 1994), While Bueno de Mesquita et al. argue that democratic policymakers by virtue of having large “selectorates” and large winning coalitions, find survival in office enhanced by the provision of public goods, free trade being one of them. In summary, what we have in the field, is the emergence of what we might call the “comparative political economy of trade” – where variations in domestic institutional form are shown to be systematically related to trade policy outcomes. III. Information and Institutions A new generation of models of the political economy of trade policy recognize that tariffpolicy is made in an environment of incomplete information. Asymmetries of information occur at both international and domestic level; and within the domestic level, various types of uncertainty are present: Page 5 of 8 Ideas, Interests, Institutions, Information: Rosendorff International organizations play crucial information providing roles – 1. when states aren’t sure of the behavior of their trading partners, or perhaps they see the behavior but can’t determine if it is consistent with their obligations – Keohane (1984), Rosendorff (2005a). 2. voters can’t see the behavior of their policymakers, but can rely on the signals provided by the international institutions to better monitor the behavior of policymakers that might otherwise be extractive (Mansfield et al. 2002). 3. Uncertainties about the political pressures governments may experience in the future lead governments to design flexibility and opportunities for renegotiation (Rosendorff and Milner 2001, Bagwell and Staiger 2005). Domestic political uncertainty 1. about identity off gainers and losers leads to a status quo bias (Fernandez and Rodrik 1991). 2. say about the preferences of the median of the voter over trade policy lead government to be “conservative” in its willingness to liberalize (Milner and Rosendorff 1997). 3. uncertainty about one’s trading partners’ domestic politics can lead that state to extract more – the Schelling conjecture (Milner and Rosendorff 1996, Schelling 1960). 4. uncertainty, about the effect of policy choices under most circumstances makes international trade agreements more difficult to strike (Milner and Rosendorff 1996). 5. and lobbying generates information that can be used by the government and the special interests to alter outcomes (Milner and Rosendorff 1996, Grossman and Helpman 2001). Conclusion Jagdish concludes his marvelous, little book, by reasserting his “guarded optimism in regard to the long-run prospects for keeping protectionism at bay”. Let me express my enthusiastic optimism for the prospects for the field of the political economy of international trade, and let me congratulate Jagdish for his long and productive career as producer of ideas, and may there be many more I’s to come. Page 6 of 8 Ideas, Interests, Institutions, Information: Rosendorff References Bagwell, Kyle and Robert W. Staiger (1997), “Multilateral Tariff Cooperation During the Formation of Customs Unions” Journal of International Economics, 42:91-123. Bagwell, Kyle and Robert W. Staiger (1999), “An Economic Theory of GATT,” American Economic Review 89(1):215248. Bagwell, Kyle and Robert Staiger (2002) The Economics of the World Trading Systerm, Cambridge: MIT Press. Bagwell, Kyle and Robert W. Staiger (2005), “Enforcement, Private Political Pressure and the GATT/WTO Escape Clause” forthcoming, Journal of Legal Studies. Bhagwati, Jagdish (1982) Directly Unproductive Profit-Seeking (DUP) Activities, Journal of Political Economy 90:9881002. Bhagwati, Jagdish (1988) Protectionism Cambridge: MIT Press. Bhagwati, Jagdish (1991) The World Trading System at Risk, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Bhagwati, Jagdish (1993) “Regionalism and Multilateralism: An Overview,” in Jaime de Melo and Arvind Panagariya, eds. New Dimensions in Regional Integration Cambridge: Cambridge University Press Bhagwati, Jagdish and Robert C. Feenstra (1982) “Tariff Seeking and the Efficient Tariff” in J. N. Bhagwati, ed. Import Competition and Response, Chicago: Chicago University Press. Bhagwati, Jagdish and Hugh T. Patrick, eds. (1990) Aggressive Unilateralism: America’s 301 Trade Policy and the Word Trading System, Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press. Bhagwati, Jagdish and T. N. Srinivasan (1980) “Revenue Seeking: A Generalization of the Theory of Tariffs”, Journal of Political Economy 88(6):1069-1087. Bueno de Mesquita, B., A. Smith, R.M. Siverson and J.D. Morrow (2003), The Logic of Political Survival, MIT Press. Destler, I.M. (1992) American Trade Politics, Washington: Institute for International Economics. Doces, John and B. Peter Rosendorff (2005) “Intra-Democratic Variations and Trade Policy: Why Presidential Systems Have Less Open Trade”, unpublished. Feenstra, Robert. and Tracy Lewis (1991), “Distributing the gains from trade with incomplete information,”, Economics and Politics 3(1):21–39. Fernandez, Raquel and Dani Rodrik (1991), “Resistance to Reform: Status-Quo Bias in the presence of IndividualSpecific Uncertainty,” American Economic Review 81(5):1146-1154. Findlay, Ronald and Stanislaw Wellisz (1982) “Endogenous Tariffs, the Poltical Economy of Trade Restrictions, and Welfare, in in J. N. Bhagwati, ed. Import Competition and Response, Chicago: Chicago University Press Garrett, Geoffrey and Barry R. Weingast (1993) “Ideas, Interests, and Institutions: Constructing the European Community’s Internal Market”, Ideas and Foreign Policy, Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman (1994), “Protection for Sale,” American Economic Review 84, 833-850. Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman (1995), “Trade Wars and Trade Talks,” Journal of Political Economy 103, 675-708. Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman (2001) Special Interest Politics Cambridge: MIT Press Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman (2004) “A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics”, unpublished Irwin, Douglas A, and Randall S. Kroszner (1999) “Interests, Institutions, and Ideology in Securing Policy Change: The Republican Conversion to Trade after Smoot-Hawley”, Journal of Law and Economics Keohane, Robert. (1984), After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy Lohmann, Susanne and Sharyn O’Halloran (1994), “Divided Government and US Trade Policy: Theory and Evidence”, International Organization, 48(4): 595-632. Mansfield, E., H. Milner and B.P. Rosendorff (2000), “Free to Trade: Democracies, Autocracies and International Trade Negotiations,” American Political Science Review, 94(2):305-321. Mansfield, E., H. Milner and B.P. Rosendorff (2002), “Why Democracies Cooperate More: Electoral Control and International Trade Agreements,” International Organization 56(3):477-514. McGillivray, Fiona. (1997), “Party Discipline as a Determinant of the Endogenous Formation of Tariffs”, American Journal of Political Science, 41(2):584-607. Milner, Helen and B. Peter Rosendorff (1996) “Trade Negotiations, Information and Domestic Politics: The Role of Domestic Groups,” Economics and Politics, 1996, 8(2): 145-189. Milner, Helen and B. Peter Rosendorff (1997) “Democratic Politics and International trade Negotiations: Elections and Divided Government as Constraints on Trade Liberalization,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 1997, 41(1): 117147. Mitra, Devashish (1999), “Endogenous Lobby Formation and Endogenous Protection: A Long Run Model of Trade Policy Determination”, American Economic Review 89,:1116-1134. Page 7 of 8 Ideas, Interests, Institutions, Information: Rosendorff Morrow, J.D., R.M. Siverson and T.E. Tabares (1998), “The Political Determinants of International Trade: The Major Powers, 1907-90”, American Political Science Review, 92:649-61 Rodrik, Dani (1995). “Political Economy of Trade Policy” in: Grossman, G., Rogoff, K. (Eds.). Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3. North-Holland, Amsterdam. Rogowski, Ronald (1987), “Trade and the Variety of Democratic Institutions”, International Organization, 41(2):203223. Rosendorff, B. Peter (2005a), “Stability and Rigidity: Politics and the Design of the WTO's Dispute Resolution Procedure,” American Political Science Review, August 2005, 99(3):389-400. Rosendorff, B. Peter. (2005b) “Do Democracies Trade More Freely?”, forthcoming in Robert Pahre ed. Divided Government and International Trade, London: Palgrave. Rosendorff, B. Peter and Helen. Milner (2001), “The Optimal Design of International Institutions: Uncertainty and Escape,” International Organization, 55(4):829-858. Samuelson, Paul (1996) “The Age of Bhagwati et al.”, in Robert C. Feenstra, Gene M. Grossman and Doug Irwin, eds., The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Essays in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996. Schelling, Thomas. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Varshney, Ashotosh (1988) Ideas, interests and institutions in policy change: transformation of India's agricultural strategy” Cambridge, Mass.: Center for International Studies. Page 8 of 8