Lifetime Value: Empirical Generalizations and Some Conceptual Questions Robert C. Blattberg Edward C. Malthouse Scott A. Neslin Robert C. Blattberg1 Edward C. Malthouse2 Scott Neslin3 August 2007 1 Polk Bros. Professor of Retailing; Professor of Marketing; Director of the Center for Retail Management Center, Kellogg School of Management, rblattberg@northwestern.edu 2 Theordore and Annie Sills Associate Professor of Integrated Marketing Communications, Medill School of Journalism, Northwestern University, ecm@northwestern.edu 3 Albert Wesley Frey Professor of Marketing, Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth, scott.a.neslin@tuck.dartmouth.edu Lifetime Value: Empirical Generalizations and Some Conceptual Questions Abstract: From the extant literature on LTV we identify four empirical generalizations (well-defined, consistent effects found by at least three different authors): (1) customer satisfaction increases LTV; (2) marketing efforts are associated with higher LTV; (3) cross-buying is associated with higher LTV; and (4) multichannel purchasing is associated with higher LTV. The frequency and monetary value of previous purchases generally have a positive effect on LTV, although there are contradictory findings. We identify additional issues that have received limited attention in the literature, but require further empirical study: the effects of pricing and promotions on LTV, managing a sequence of contacts to maximize response rates and LTV, and whether LTV can be forecasted sufficiently accurately. Eight conceptual or strategic issues are identified and discussed. Many firms are now focusing on identifying their most profitable customers and nurturing long-term relations, which represents a different way of making and evaluating marketing decisions and the product-centric approach. At the center of the approach is Lifetime Value of a customer (LTV). It is a pivotal concept in the customer-centric approach to marketing that pervades the many customer relationship management approaches that are frequently discussed and practiced by firms such as one-to-one, loyalty, and database marketing. Lifetime value (LTV) is the present value of all the future cash flows attributed to a customer relationship (Pfeifer et al. 2005, p 17). Due to uncertainty in future customer, firm, and competitor behavior, LTV is in reality a random variable and most applications calculate expected LTV, which can be written as: ~ E Vt LTV t 1 t 1 (1 d ) (1) ~ where Vt is the customer’s net contribution in period t, and d is the discount rate. Net contribution is driven by: (1) customer duration; that is, whether the customer is still active in period t; (2) revenues generated by the customer in period t, given he or she survives to that period; and (3) costs of serving the customer in period t. There are thus four components of LTV: (1) duration, (2) revenues, (3) costs, and (4) discount rate. LTV can be used to guide the firm’s acquisition and retention activities, and is sometimes aggregated over customers as a measure of firm or segment value. Research on LTV and its components is an active area and there are many research articles that propose methods of estimating LTV or its components under various conditions, study their antecedents, attempt to maximize LTV over some space of marketing actions, or discuss its applications. Given this widespread interest in customer-centric marketing and LTV, it is important to take stock of what is known and needs to be known about LTV. There are excellent surveys of this subject (e.g., see Jain and Singh 2002 or Blattberg, Kim and Neslin, 2008). As an indication of breadth and interest on this subject, the survey in the latter reference spans multiple chapters. We shall not attempt to duplicate this effort at summarizing the field here. In particular, space will not permit us to review the models used to estimate LTV. The purpose of this article is to (1) discuss empirical generalizations that can be drawn from extant academic research literature, (2) discuss empirical findings that do not yet reach the threshold for generalization but are suggestive and interesting, and (3) discuss conceptual and strategic issues relating to LTV. This is a subjective list of generalizations and conceptual issues based on our review of the literature and what we think is most important. Blattberg, Briesch and Fox (1995, p G123) defined empirical generalizations as “(1) the topic being analyzed is well defined; (2) there are at least three articles by at least three different authors in which empirical research has been conducted in the specific area; and (3) the empirical evidence is consistent, i.e., the sign of the effect is the same in each of the articles.” It is important to study empirical generalizations for several reasons. From a research viewpoint, multiple studies reporting a similar empirical conclusion can verify theory or identify areas where theoretical work is needed. From a practical viewpoint, empirical generalizations can provide managers with guidance in making marketing decisions. In the following section, we present issues that satisfy the above definition of an empirical generalization. Next, we discuss issues for which there is some research evidence, but not enough (in our judgment) to reach the status of an empirical generalization. We then discuss conceptual issues that are not empirical per se but influence our understanding of how to apply LTV. We close with a brief summary. Empirical Generalizations We have identified four findings that we believe qualify as empirical generalizations regarding LTV: customer satisfaction, marketing, cross-buying, and multichannel purchasing all have positive relationships with LTV.1 Table 1 summarizes research addressing each generalization. Much of the evidence is based on using one of the earlier described components of LTV as the dependent variable. Because of equation (1), if there is a relationship with a component, there will be a relationship with LTV.2 1. Customer satisfaction has a positive effect on LTV. There is a large literature relating customer satisfaction with loyalty and measures of firm performance. The consensus is that satisfaction has a positive relationship with loyalty, retention and profitability,3 although Yeung et al. (2001) find that the strength of the relationship and the magnitude of the impact appear to vary with the choice of performance measures and industry sector. For example, the relationship is strong in the financial sector, but much weaker in the technology and communications sectors. This suggests that there are sector characteristics that moderate the relationship between satisfaction and profitability and points out the need for a richer theory. Yeung’s articles also find that the amount of variation in performance measures explained by satisfaction is generally small, 1 We omit demographics from this discussion because their effects are likely to be product-specific. For example, age might be associated positively with LTV for financial services, but negatively for music downloads. 2 Note however that ideally, the empirical work would use LTV as the dependent variable. We acknowledge the caveat that it is possible some factor, for example cross-buying, might relate positively to customer duration, but also increase costs, so that LTV might indeed relate negatively to cross-buying. 3 Some authors, e.g., Heskett et al. (1994), theorize that loyalty is a consequence of satisfaction and an antecedent of profitability, i.e., satisfaction → loyalty → profitability suggesting other causal factors should be included. Most of the empirical work has used measures of firm profitability as dependent variables and more work is needed to investigate this relationship at the customer level. 2. Marketing efforts are associated with higher LTV: The evidence summarized in Table 1 suggests a strong association between marketing efforts and customer duration. One study looked at customer “profitability” (Reinartz, Thomas, and Kumar 2005) and found a positive relationship. That marketing influence LTV is a requirement for LTV to be a useful marketing metric. However, the finding of a positive association is nontrivial. Firms might spend more money trying to rescue customers who have shorter duration; they might spend too much on marketing to customers who would have purchased anyway, reducing the profitability of these efforts. The ramifications of this generalization are crucial because they suggest firms can formulate marketing activities to manage LTV over time. Note however that most of the evidence is based on associations. The problem is that firms might choose to expend higher marketing efforts on more valuable customers, and thus LTV caused increased marketing rather than the reverse. A formal selectivity model (Woodridge 2002) would be needed to sort out the causality issue, where there would be two equations: one for customer profitability and the second for firm marketing efforts. 3. Cross-buying is associated with higher LTV. Reinartz and Kumar (2003, pp. 81- 82) give a literature review and develop a theoretical rational for cross-buying having a positive effect on duration. Table 1 shows that there is generally a positive effect, although some authors do not find a significant effect. There is some question as to whether the relationship between cross-buying and LTV is spurious. It could be that customers who highly prefer a company buy often from it and also buy from several departments. For example, if customers are loyal to a given electronics retailer because of its service, they are likely to make multiple purchases from that retailer such as TV’s, DVD’s, and computer equipment. Reinartz, Thomas, and Bascoul (2006) used Granger causality tests to assess the direction of causality, and found that profitability caused cross-buying rather than the reverse. So while we clearly have a positive association between cross-buying and LTV, we still need to determine causality. 4. Multichannel purchasing is associated with higher LTV: This is a significant finding in the multichannel literature (see Neslin and Shankar (2008) in this issue of Journal of Interactive Marketing, as well as Neslin et al. (2006)). Multichannel purchasing could increase LTV because it creates switching costs or increases customer satisfaction. For example, customers who use a bank’s ATM, branch office, and online service, must extricate themselves from several contact points in order to switch to another bank. Hence switching costs are high. In a more positive vein, customers may be more satisfied because dealing with the bank is convenient and they therefore give it more business. The evidence in favor of positive association is fairly strong, especially, although not exclusively, in the retail industry. One interesting exception can be found in Campbell and Frei (2006), who find that while adopters of online banking increase usage frequency, total revenue goes down, possibly due to customers managing their assets more effectively. The question of causality rears its head again in the case of multichannel usage, similarly to the case of cross-buying. Conceptually, the phenomena are very similar – multichannel purchasing is “cross-buying” across the firm’s channels rather than the firm’s departments. Again, the multichannel shopper may become more satisfied with the company, and hence becomes more loyal and more valuable. The shopper may also receive more marketing simply by visiting various channels. On the other hand, highvalue customers may self-select into using all the firm’s channels. This explanation is refuted by Ansari et al. (2007), but that is only one study. Further work is needed in this area. If indeed the relationship is multichannel increases LTV, the implication is clear – firms should encourage multichannel usage. An Issue with Conflicting Empirical Evaluations 5. How does RFM affect LTV? Previous purchase behavior is often summarized by the time since the most recent purchase (R=recency), the number of previous purchases (F=frequency), and the total amount spent (M=monetary value) – RFM. Since these variables are widely known for existing customers, they are often included in LTV models and used to make customer-level estimates. Frequency and monetary are often highly correlated and it could be argued that, at least in some situations, they are different measures of the same underlying construct, previous buying intensity. In our discussions with practitioners, most believe that recency has a negative relationship with LTV, and frequency and monetary to have a positive relationship with customer value,4 but this has not been found consistently in the academic literature. Nagar and Rajan (2005) find a positive relationship loan volume and firm profitability. Reinartz and Kumar (2003) find positive relationships between previous spending levels and lifetime duration. The models in Malthouse and Blattberg (2005) were optimized for predictive accuracy and 4 Because of the correlation between monetary and frequency, one must be careful about sign-flips in models involving both variables. some had substantial multicollinearity, inhibiting the interpretation of effect signs, but across over 100 catalog companies, a software company, a nonprofit organization, and an educational service provider they consistently found frequency and monetary variables had positive relationships with individual-level long-term value and recency had a negative effect (the longer a customer has been inactive the lower LTV is). Li (1995), however, finds a negative effect on duration at the customer level and Niraj et al. (2001) find a negative relationship with customer profit, but it is unclear how Li defines his “Usage” variable and Niraj et al. define their “Number of Orders” variable. Clearly this area needs more research, but our view is that frequency and monetary are likely to have a positive effect and recency a negative effect on LTV. Issues with Few Empirical Evaluations 6. How does pricing affect LTV? There has been very little research on this question. Thomas et al. (2004) study the effects of reacquisition pricing strategies for newspaper subscriptions on the likelihood of reacquiring a customer and on the duration after reacquisition. In a longitudinal study, they examine the price offered at the time of reacquisition as well as prices charged after reacquisition. They conclude that an optimal pricing strategy would be to offer a low reacquisition price and higher prices after a customer has been reacquired. Reinartz and Kumar (2000) study the converse question of how a customer’s length of tenure with a firm affects LTV. They find that the shortest-life segment of customers have a significantly higher average price paid for a single product item for a catalog company but warn that this finding could be confounded with other variables. Further empirical work is necessary to understanding pricing effects. The direction of causality is also not clear. 7. How do promotions affect LTV? Anderson and Simester (2004) studied the long- term impact of promotion depth for a catalog company using three randomized controlled experiments. All customers in the study received a catalog including merchandise indicated as being “on sale,” but the prices for the sale items were lower for the “promotion” group. In all tests promotions increased short-term sales, but those in the promotion group purchased less in the 12 months after the promotion than during the subsequent year, suggesting acceleration. They also found that deeper price discounts increased future purchases by first-time customers, but reduced future purchases by established customers. This conclusion should be tested for other firms and in other industries. Li (1995) also finds that the hazard of cancelling long-distance telephone service decreases when a discount plan is offered. Overall, there is some evidence, mostly through Anderson and Simester’s study, that database marketing communications can act like promotions and induce the same long-term effects observed in the promotions literature (e.g., see Neslin 2002 or Blattberg et al. 1995), but more empirical work is needed to measure these effects in other settings. Optimal contact models should consider these issues. For example, a communication may accelerate a purchase, so it would not make sense to communicate again until sufficient time has elapsed for the customer to become ready to buy again. 8. What is the relationship between the number of contacts and response rates? Can too many contacts actually decrease response rates? These questions are important because they provide a non-cost reason to limit the number of contacts – fewer contacts could potentially produce more sales. The answer to the second question seems to be yes, but further work is necessary on the first to know the points at which customers “wear out” and understand the theoretical reasons they do so. Ansari et al. (2007) find a negative interaction between purchase frequency and like communications as well as different communications. For example, they find that two catalogs delivered at nearly the same time have a smaller impact on purchase frequency than if the catalogs are delivered at more highly separated times. They find the same negative interactions between successive emails and between successive emails and catalogs. In evaluating a new way of deciding which customer should receive a catalog, Gönül, Kim and Shi (2000) conclude that “it is better to send (not too many) a few catalogs with (not too long but) a moderate amount of time between them to encourage purchase (pp. 2-3),” also supporting wear out. Using self-reported data, Eastlick, Feinberg and Trappey (1993) conclude that the relationship between the number of catalogs and purchase history (e.g., frequency and monetary) is fit better by a quadratic inverted-U function than a linear one. Ganzach and Ben-Or (1996) critique their conclusions and rationale, and Feinberg, Eastlick, and Trappey (1996) defend them. Campbell et al. (2001) suggest the relationship is concave with diminishing returns, but do not report that the returns become negative at some point. In summary, it seems clear that wear-out is a real phenomenon, in that there are decreasing returns to marketing within a given time period, and that the spacing between contacts can counteract wear-out. While this makes it plausible that a company could produce higher LTV with fewer communications, even if the communications are costless, this specific finding needs to be demonstrated. Further if the shape of the curve is an inverted-U, it is critical to determine the wear-out point. Also, theories need to be developed which explain why the shape is an inverted-U. 9. Do optimal contact models, which select a combination of contacts to maximize LTV, work? The positive associations between marketing and LTV, and between multichannel usage and LTV, suggest that firms may be able to actively manage each customer’s LTV over time, through an “optimal contact model.” For example, Sun and Li (2005) present a dynamic programming model where customers are “right-channeled” to the specific calling center that optimally trades off their costs of using that channel versus their satisfaction. The first issue of the Journal of Interactive Marketing published an article highlighting longitudinal contact strategies as an important research topic (Kestnbaum et al. 1998). Many models have been proposed for this task (Bitran and Mondschein 1996, Gönül and Shi 1998, Gönül et al. 2000, Campbell et al. 2001, Elsner et al. 2003, Ching et al. 2004, Rust and Verhoef 2005, Simester et al. 2006, Neslin et al. 2007). Blattberg et al. (2008, Chapter 28) summarize and contrast the different approaches. They note that while some of these methods have been field tested with positive results, more work is needed, especially to compare dynamically optimized contact models and simpler myopic approaches. 10. Can LTV be predicted with sufficient accuracy at the individual level to allocate resources? If firms allocate marketing resources on the basis of LTV, and LTV is estimated without certainty, then it follows that there will be a chance the resources will be misallocated because customers are misclassified. For example, a LTV estimate could indicate that a customer should not receive some contact, when, in fact, the customer deserves it. Malthouse and Blattberg (2005) propose the 80-15 and 20-55 rules – of the actual top 20% of customers, approximately 55% will be misclassified and of the actual bottom 80%, approximately 15% will be misclassified. They conclude that the probabilities and costs of misclassification should be considered when deciding whether to allocate resources based on LTV. An alternative, which is widely used in many industries, is to allocate perks on the basis of actual future behavior through earned rewards (see issue 16 below). Conceptual and Strategic Issues Concerning LTV 11. Absolute or incremental LTV? Should firms allocate marketing resources based on how much a customer is worth (absolute LTV), or the potential change in LTV (incremental) that could result from the investment? For example, many loyalty programs assign customers to tiers based on absolute LTV; e.g, airlines offer frequent flyers with the most miles top-tier status and thus more marketing resources. (The appropriate objective could be that if an airline did not give perks to those with many miles the frequent fliers would switch to another carrier, thus also affecting incremental LTV, but tier assignments are made based on absolute LTV.) Kumar, et al. (2004) recommend as a best practice “prioritizing and selecting customers [to target with appropriate marketing actions] on the basis of [absolute] LTV (p 65).” Rust and Verhoef (2005), on the other hand, use one-year incremental profit as the dependent variable and determine how much marketing to allocate to each customer to maximize incremental profit. Gönül, Kim, and Shi (2000) suggest using the incremental profit derived from a contact when deciding which customers to mail. This is a complex issue because firms are fearful of not offering high absolute LTV customers the best services and benefits. Economic theory would imply using incremental LTV. 12. Best customers or brand concept? These are different philosophies of marketing. The best-customer approach recommends identifying historically profitable customers (or estimates of future LTV, which are usually highly correlated with historical profitability) and making marketing decisions based on the needs of this customer group. It also suggests segmenting customers by value and developing marketing programs for different value-based segments (e.g., Zeithaml, Rust, and Lemon 2001). In brandfocused marketing the business unit (or brand manager) articulates a brand concept in a positioning statement that guides marketing decisions. Firms that sell consumer package goods such as Kraft and P&G tend to be very good at this kind of marketing. The two approaches could lead to different decisions. Should firms modify their marketing activities to cater to their best customers? Can brand-focused and best-customer marketing be integrated? If so, how? Under what circumstances is one approach preferred over the other? Malthouse and Calder (2005) attempt to reconcile the two approaches. This issue is related to the customer-centric versus product-centric debate (Peppers and Rogers 1993). Note both of these approaches are marketing strategies; the question is whether one should start with the customer and personalize marketing accordingly, or start with a product line developed based on the needs of a definable target group? This issue therefore relates to targeting and segmentation, which are central concepts in modern marketing. Under the best-customer approach, segments are defined based on historical profitability and all segments could potentially receive marketing, albeit at different levels. In brand-centric marketing segments are defined based on other criteria such as attitudes, beliefs, needs, psychographics, or demographics, and a single segment is targeted. This creates confusion with the term segment, e.g., business units that have well-articulated brand concepts such as Eddie Bauer or Courtyard by Marriott have targeted some market segment, which is further partitioned into value-based segments. It also creates the possibility that the marketing efforts designed to communicate the brand concept are inconsistent with those offered to the value-based segments, especially when these marketing activities are managed in different departments within an organization. To what extent should the marketing programs developed for the value-based segments be consistent with the branding efforts? Are there adverse effects when the two are uncoordinated? Of course, not all businesses have well-articulated brand concepts, and in such cases should firms focus on identifying, satisfying and retaining their best customers, or on identifying a brand concept and making marketing decisions to develop the brand (the two may not be incompatible)? 13. Do customers “die,” or just become dormant with some reactivating later? Many LTV models assume that customers die at some point, but there is little evidence whether this is a reasonable assumption. This assumption seems to have been made out of convenience rather than it being reasonable for a wide range of business situations. An alternative is that at least some customers who appear to be dead have entered a temporary dormant state and will return to an active state at a later time. This is the migration or Markov chain model of LTV (e.g., see Pfeifer and Carraway 2000) Gopinath et al. (2007) find that catalog customers and nonprofit donors who are statistically “dead” do reactivate. For example, a customer could discontinue a relationship with a telecom provider and switch to a competitor, but then return to the first provider at a later time. If the segment of temporarily dormant customers is sufficiently large and pervasive across industries, then more complicated models should be developed to accommodate the possibility that customers migrate between states. It is conceivable that there is also an intermediate “switcher” state. 14. Lifetime value or long-term value? Many models for LTV attempt to estimate cash flows in perpetuity, but is a finite horizon more managerially actionable? On a practical level, managers in many industries change jobs frequently and may want to show a more rapid return for their actions. Also, many firms can change the level of investment in a particular customer over time taking into consideration future customer actions. For examples, airlines and hotels adjust loyalty club tier assignments periodically (e.g., annually). Catalog companies and nonprofit organizations make decisions over time concerning which former customers/donors should receive another mailing. If firms can adjust marketing investment levels over time, then over what time period should projections be made? A related question is whether marketing decisions would change if shorter horizons were used (how sensitive is the decision to the time horizon?). Nagar and Rajan (2005) and Rust and Verhoef (2005) both use one-year future windows. Malthouse and Blattberg (2005) vary the length of the future period and find that predictive accuracy remains consistent. 15. Does RFM accurately represent behavior? Is RFM an artifact due to heterogeneity in preference or is there recidivism in buying behavior? What this means is that those customers who prefer a given set of products or services offered by a manufacturer, retailer or cataloguer will purchase more frequently. In a traditional RFM matrix, it would appear that more frequent and more recent customers have a higher probability of purchasing. While this is true, the issue is causation. Should a firm invest in trying to increase a customer’s recency because that increases his or her probability of buying in the future? If it is heterogeneity in preference and the preferences are stationary, then the customer will not increase his or her probability of buying if the customer purchased more recently. This issue is a critical issue to database marketers because it has significant implications for targeting strategies. 16. What is the role of LTV for firms that allocate marketing resources through earned rewards? Many firms allocate a substantial fraction of their perks based on actual future behavior. For example, airlines typically give free flights based on miles or the frequency of flights. Hotels give free nights based on the frequency of stays. Tesco, a British supermarket chain, returns a percentage of the amount spent during the previous quarter to its loyalty club members. Credit cards give rewards (cash-back bonuses, miles, etc.) proportional to the amount charged during a recent period. In each instance the perk is earned through recent behavior. Those who do more of what the firm wants receive greater rewards. How should LTV be used by such firms? How is incremental LTV affected by this marketing allocation strategy? 17. Marginal or full costing? Much of the research on LTV focuses on its revenue and duration components. However, how one computes the costs that enter the LTV calculation can have a dramatic impact. Perhaps the most important conceptual issue in determining the appropriate costs is whether the calculation should only include the direct variable costs of serving the customer (marginal costing) or also include an allocation of overhead that does not change depending on whether the customer is served or not (full costing). The argument for marginal costing (summarized by Blattberg, Kim, and Neslin 2008, Chapter 6), is that full costing can lead to the rejection of customers (either by not acquiring them or by “firing” them) who would clearly increase profits if they were served. Consider the following situation: a company has two customers, one of whom generates net revenues (net of variable costs) of $500; the other generates $150. The company has a fixed cost (e.g., the salary of the CEO, the cost of the marketing analytics group, the cost of a call center) that will not change if either or both of the customers are served. Assume this fixed cost is $400, or $200 per customer. Under these assumptions, we have the following LTV calculations: Customer 1 Customer 2 Marginal Costing LTV = $500 LTV = $150 Full Costing LTV = $500-$200=$300 LTV = $150-$200=$-$50 The full costing calculation says that the LTV of Customer 2 is negative. One might interpret this to mean that the customer has a negative long-term contribution and should be terminated. In practice, this would mean that the customer would be allowed to churn or would receive no efforts to have their subscription or contract renewed. However, the company would then be left with the following profits: Net Revenues Fixed Costs Total Profits With Customer 1 $500 $400 $100 With Customers 1 and 2 $650 $400 $250 Clearly the firm is better off with keeping Customer 2, but Customer 2 has a negative LTV under full costing! The above example makes a compelling case that marginal costing is preferred to full costing. However, life is not always so simple. One complication is that some costs are “semi-variable,” i.e., they are constant within a given range of customers, but then jump according to a step function once a threshold is surpassed. For example, at some point the next customer necessitates the institution of a second call center, and that cost then becomes fixed for successive customers. It seems incorrect to allocate all the costs of the second call center to the marginal customer who necessitates increasing the call center. Also, it may be better to drop Customer 2 and instead acquire Customer 3, thus avoiding having to add a new call center. These are difficult issues. Blattberg, Kim, and Neslin (2008) emphasize that the calculation of LTV needs to be linked to the decision at hand. For example, the firm may be deciding between serving Customer 2, Customer 3, and Customers 2 and 3. Variable costs may differ between the third and the first two options, due to the required addition of the call center. But there is no need to allocate fixed costs – in fact it could lead to the wrong decision, as in the example above – if these costs will not change within the range of options being considered by the firm. In summary, the argument for marginal costing requires that the firm consider the full range of decisions it faces. This may require a longer-term orientation, e.g., thinking about Customer 3 as well as Customer 2. Our point is to note the conceptual challenge of this issue, and that one can find full costing (Searcy 2004) as well as marginal costing (Mulhern 1999) applied in the literature. The field would be well-served to have this issue resolved. 18. What is the appropriate discount rate?5 Capital budgeting theory (e.g., see Brealey, Myers, and Marcus 2004) would view customers as financial assets. Accordingly, the appropriate discount rate is the opportunity cost of capital for the firm’s investors, i.e., the rate of return the firm’s investors could achieve for an investment of 5 Note this issue is related to the lifetime versus long-term value issue raised previously, where the solution to the discount rate problem essentially is to use a short time window where the level of discount, assuming one is even used, will not make much of a difference. similar risk. If the firm uses this discount rate, the financiers of the company will prefer alternative investments to customers who have negative LTV’s. Blattberg, Kim and Neslin (2008, Chapter 6) discuss how to calculate the opportunity cost of capital following capital budgeting theory. This may seem straightforward because this theory is so well-formulated. However, there are complexities that emerge when we are talking about customer management. For example, the key part of the formula is what “investors could achieve for an investment of similar risk.” In practice, customers have different risks. Customer A may be a sure bet to contribute $1000 per year ad infinitum, whereas Customer B may be contribute anywhere between $500 and $3000; it is too early to tell. In capital budgeting applications, companies handle this by introducing “project-specific” discount rates. Does this mean that each customer should have a different discount rate according to his or her risk? How would one handle this in practical terms? Concluding Comments In summary, we have endeavored to identify empirical generalizations regarding LTV as well as suggestive findings that have not yet achieved the threshold for generalizability. In addition, we have discussed conceptual/strategic issues involving LTV that need better theory or practical solutions. We found four findings that reached the requirements to be called empirical generalizations: (1) Customer satisfaction increases LTV; (2) Marketing efforts are associated with higher LTV; (3) Cross-buying is associated with higher LTV, and (4) Multichannel purchasing is associated with higher LTV. While we cannot claim these generalizations exhaust all the possibilities, they share a common theme in that they suggest that LTV can be profitably managed. The one major caveat is that three of these findings are associations; not enough evidence has been found to say for example that cross-buying causes higher LTV rather than a third factor causing cross-buying to be correlated with LTV. Future research needs to focus on distilling causality in these relationships. Much of the extant research studies components of LTV rather than LTV itself, and further research is needed with LTV as the outcome. The suggestive findings are more aptly stated as questions, and include: (1) Does previous purchasing increases LTV? (2) What is the impact of pricing on LTV? (3) What is the impact of promotions on LTV? (4) Does “wear-out” imply that customers can be over-contacted, even when the cost per contact is costless? (5) Do optimal contact models work better than simpler alternatives? and (6) Can LTV be adequately predicted? These are all empirical questions. They all have received some attention in the literature, but more studies are needed. Again, the common theme is that once these issues are generalized, companies will be better able to proactively managed customer lifetime value. We identified eight conceptual/strategic issues and we will not repeat all of them here. These issues eventually could be researched empirically but most of them require conceptual as well as strategic questions to be settled first. For example, the question of full versus marginal costing is clearly a conceptual issue. The issue of whether customers “die” gets at the core of whether the standard “simple retention model” is appropriate, and under what conditions. The issue of best customer versus brand marketing borders on the strategic question of whether firms should be customer-centric or product-centric. We started with a simple definition – LTV is the net present value of the future cash flows generated by a customer relationship – and have pointed out the complexities as well as the progress that has been made in understanding this concept. While we were able to identify four generalizations and other issues that have received substantial empirical investigation, we believe it would be accurate to say the glass is half-empty rather than half-full at the moment. This is meant optimistically, that the most exciting findings and breakthroughs await us in the field of LTV. We hope that this paper contributes to this ultimate outcome. References Database Marketing – Blattberg, Kim, and Neslin 1. Anderson, Eric T., and Duncan I. Simester (2004) “Long-Run Effects of Promotion Depth on New Versus Established Customers: Three Field Studies,” Marketing Science, 23 (1), 4-20. 2. Anderson, Eugene W., Claes Fornell, and Donald R. Lehmann (1994), “Customer Satisfaction, Market Share, and Profitability: Findings from Sweden,” Journal of Marketing, 58 (July), 53-56. 3. Anderson, Eugene W., Claes Fornell, and Roland T. Rust (1997), “Customer Satisfaction, Productivity, and Profitability: Differences Between Goods and Services,” Marketing Science, 16 (2), 129-145. 4. Ansari, Asim, Carl F. Mela, and Scott A. Neslin (2007), “Customer Channel Migration,” Journal of Marketing Research, (Forthcoming). 5. Bernhardt, Kenneth L., Naveen Donthu, and Pamela A. Kennett (2000), “A Longitudinal Analysis of Satisfaction and Profitability,” Journal of Business Research, 47, 161-171. 6. Bitran, Gabriel R., and Susana V. Mondschein (1996) “Mailing Decisions in the Catalog Industry,” Management Science, 42 (9), 1364-1381. 7. Blattberg, Robert C., Richard Breisch, and Edward J. Fox (1995), “How Promotions Work,” Marketing Science, 14(3), G122-G132. 8. Blattberg, Robert C., Byung-Do Kim, and Scott A. Neslin (2008), Database Marketing: Analyzing and Managing Customers (forthcoming): New York: Springer. 9. Bolton, Ruth N. (1998), “A Dynamic Model of the Duration of the Customer’s Relationship with a Continuous Service Provider: The Role of Satisfaction,” Marketing Science, 17 (1), 45-65. 10. Brealey, Richard A., S.C. Myers and A.J. Marcus (2004), Fundamentals of Corporate Finance, New York, N.Y.: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. 11. Brusco, Michael J., J. Dennis Cradit, and Armen Tashcian (2003), “Multicriterion Clusterwise Regression for Joint Segmentation Settings: An Application to Customer Value,” Journal of Marketing Research, 40 (2), 225-234. 12. Campbell, Deb, Randy Erdahl, Dough Johnson, Eric Bibelnieks, Michael Haydock, Mark Bullock, and Harlan Crowder (2001) “Optimizing Customer Mail Streams at Fingerhut,” Interfaces, 31 (1), 77-90. 13. Campbell, Dennis, and Frances X. Frei (2006), “The Cost Structure, Customer Profitability, and Retention Implications of Self-Service Distribution Channels: Evidence from Customer Behavior in an Online Banking Channel,” Working Paper, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School. 14. Ching, Wai-Ki, M. Ng, K. Wong, and E Altman (2004), “Customer Lifetime Value: Stochastic Optimization Approach,” Journal of the Operational Research Society, 55 (8), 860-868. 15. Doubleclick (2004), "Retail Details: Best Practices in Multichannel Integration" (March), New York: DoubleClick, Inc.. 16. Eastlick, Mary Ann, Richard Feinberg, and Charles Trappey (1993) “Information Overload in Mail Catalog Shopping,” Journal of Direct Marketing, 7 (4), 14-19. 17. Elsner, Ralf, Manfred Krafft, and Arnd Huchzermeier (2004) “Optimizing Rhenania’s Direct Marketing Business Through Dynamic Multilevel Modeling (DMLM) in a Multicatalog-Brand Environment,” Marketing Science, 23 (2), 192-206. 18. Feinberg, Richard A., Mary Ann Eastlick, and Charles V. Trappey (1996) “Using Information Overload or Decreasing Marginal Responsiveness to Determine ‘How Many Catalogs Are Too Many?’: It Really Makes a Difference – Reply to Ganzach and Or,” Journal of Direct Marketing, 10 (2), 10-12. 19. Ching, Wai-Ki, M. Ng, K. Wong, and E Altman (2004), “Customer Lifetime Value: Stochastic Optimization Approach,” Journal of the Operational Research Society, 55 (8), 860-868. 20. Ganzach, Yoav, and Pinchas Ben-Or (1996) “Information Overload, Decreasing Marginal Responsiveness, and the Estimation of Nonmonotonic Relationships in Direct Marketing,” Direct of Direct Marketing, 10 (2), 7-9. 21. Garland, Ron (2004), “Share of Wallet’s Role in Customer Profitability,” Journal of Financial Services Marketing, 8 (3), 259-268. 22. Gönül, Füsun F., Byung-Do Kim, and Mengze Shi (2000) “Mailing Smarter to Catalog Customers,” Journal of Interactive Marketing, 14 (2), 2-16. 23. Gönül, Füsun, and Meng Ze Shi (1998) “Optimal Mailing of Catalogs: A New Methodology Using Estimable Structural Dynamic Programming Models,” Management Science, 44 (9), 1249-1262. 24. Gopinath, Shyam, Robert C. Blattberg, and Edward C. Malthouse (2007), “Are Revived Customers as Good as News?” working paper, Kellogg Department of Marketing, Northwestern University. 25. Guo, Chiquan, Anand Kumar, and Pornsit Jiraporn (2004), “Customer Satisfaction and Profitability: Is There a Lagged Effect?” Journal of Strategic Marketing, 12 (3), 129-144. 26. Hallowell, Roger (1996), “The Relationships of Customer Satisfaction, Customer Loyalty, and Profitability: An Empirical Study,” International Journal of Service Industry Management, 7 (4), 27-42. 27. Heskett, J.L., T.O. Jones, G.W. Loveman, W.E. Sasser Jr and L.A. Schlesinger (1994), “Putting the Service Profit Chain To Work,” Harvard Business Review, March-April, pp. 105-111. 28. Jain, Dipak and Siddhartha Singh (2002), “Customer Lifetime Value Research in Marketing: A review and Future Directions,” Journal of Interactive Marketing, 16(2), 34-46. 29. Kestnbaum, Robert D., Kate T. Kestnbaum, and Pamela W. Ames, (1998), “Building a Longitudinal Contact Strategy,” Journal of Interactive Marketing, 12(1), 56-62. 30. Kumar, V., Girish Ramani, and Timothy Bohling (2004), “Customer Lifetime Value Approaches and Best Practice Applications,” Journal of Interactive Marketing, 18 (3), 60-72. 31. Kumar V. and Rajkumar Venkatesan (2005), “Who Are Multichannel Shoppers and How Do they Perform?: Correlates of Multichannel Shopping Behavior,” Journal of Interactive Marketing, 19(Spring), 44-61. 32. Kushwaha, Tarun L. and Venkatesh Shankar (2007a), “Single Channel vs. Multichannel Customers: Determinants and Value to Retailers,” Working Paper, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX 77845. 33. Li, Shaomin (1995), “Survival Analysis,” Marketing Research, 7 (4), 16-23. 34. Malthouse, Edward C. and Robert C. Blattberg (2005), “Can We Predict Customer Lifetime Value?” Journal of Interactive Marketing, 19(1), 2-16. 35. Malthouse, Edward C. and Bobby J. Calder (2005), “CRM and Relationship Branding,” In Kellogg on Branding, edited by Tybout and Calkins, Wiley, 150-168. 36. Mulhern, Francis J. (1999), “Customer Profitability Analysis: Measurement, Concentration, and Research Directions,” Journal of Interactive Marketing, 13 (1), 25-40. 37. Najar, Venky, and Madhav V. Rajan (2005), “Measuring Customer Relationships: The Case of the Retail Banking Industry,” Management Science, 51 (6), 904-919. 38. Neslin, Scott A. (2002) Sales Promotion, Relevant Marketing Series, Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute. 39. Neslin, Scott A., and Venkatesh Shankar (2008), “Key Issues in Multichannel Customer Management: Current Knowledge and Future Directions,” Journal of Interactive Marketing (submitted to special issue). 40. Neslin, Scott A., Dhruv Grewal, Robert Leghorn, Venkatesh Shankar, Marije L. Teerling, Jacquelyn S. Thomas, and Peter C. Verhoef (2006), “Challenges and Opportunities in Multichannel Customer Management,” Journal of Service Research, 9 (November), 95-112. 41. Neslin, Scott A., Thomas P. Novak, Kenneth R. Baker, and Donna L. Hoffman (2007) “An Optimal Contact Model for Maximizing Online Panel Response Rates,” Working Paper, Tuck School of Business, Dartmouth College, Hanover, NH. 42. Niraj, Rakesh, Mahendra Gupta, and Chakravarthi Narasimhan (2001), “Customer Profitability in a Supply Chain,” Journal of Marketing, 65 (July), 1-16. 43. Peppers, Don, and Martha Rogers (1993), The One to One Future: Building Relationships One Customer at a Time, New York: Doubleday. 44. Pfiefer, Philip E., and Robert L. Carraway (2000), “Modeling Customer Relationships as Markov Chains,” Journal of Interactive Marketing, 14 (2), 43-55. 45. Pfiefer, Phillip E., Mark E. Haskins, and Robert M. Conroy (2005), “Customer Lifetime Value, Customer Profitability, and the Treatment of Acquisition Spending,” Journal of Managerial Issues, XVII(1), 11-25. 46. Reinartz, Werner J., and V. Kumar (2000), “On the Profitability of Long-Life Customers in a Noncontractural Setting: An Empirical Investigation and Implications for Marketing,” Journal of Marketing, 64 (October), 17-35. 47. Reinartz, Werner J., and V. Kumar (2003), “The Impact of Customer Relationship Characteristics on Profitable Lifetime Duration,” Journal of Marketing, 67 (January), 77-79. 48. Reinartz, Werner, Jacquelyn S. Thomas, and V. Kumar (2005), “Balancing Acquisition and Retention Resources to Maximize Customer Profitability,” Journal of Marketing, 69 (January), 63-79. 49. Reinartz, Werner, Jacquelyn S. Thomas, and Ganaël Bascoul (2006), “Investigating Cross-Buying and Customer Loyalty,” Working Paper, Fontainebleau, France: INSEAD. 50. Rust, Roland T., and Peter C. Verhoef (2005), “Optimizing the Marketing Interventions Mix in Intermediate-Term CRM,” Marketing Science, 24 (3), 477-489. 51. Searcy, DeWayne L. (2004), “Using Activity-Based Costing to Access Channel/Customer Profitability,” Management Accounting Quarterly, 5 (2), 51-60. 52. Simester, Duncan I., Peng Sun, and John N. Tsitsiklis (2006) “Dynamic Catalog Mailing Policies,” Management Science, 52 (5), 683-696. 53. Sun, Baohong, and Shibo Li (2005), “Adaptively Learning about Customers and Dynamic Service Matching – An Empirical Investigation of Service Allocation with Off-Shore Centers,” Working Paper, Pittsburgh, PA: Tepper School of Business, Carnegie Mellon University. 54. Thomas, Jacquelyn S., Robert C. Blattberg, and Edward J. Fox (2004), “Recapturing Lost Customers,” Journal of Marketing Research, 41 (1), 31-45. 55. Thomas, Jaccquelyn S. and Ursula Y. Sullivan (2005a), “Managing Marketing Communications with Multichannel Customers,” Journal of Marketing, 69 (4), 239 - 251. 56. Woodridge, Jeffrey M. (2002), Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. 57. Yeung, Matthew C. H., and Christine T. Ennew (2000), “From Customer Satisfaction to Profitability,” Journal of Strategic Marketing, 8 (4), 313-326. 58. Yeung, Matthew C. H., and Christine T. Ennew (2001), “Measuring the Impact of Customer Satisfaction of Profitability,” Journal of Targeting, Measurement and Analysis for Marketing, 10 (2), 106-116. 59. Yeung, Matthew C. H., Lee Chew Ging, and Christine T. Ennew (2002), “Customer Satisfaction and Profitability: A Reappraisal of the Nature of the Relationship,” Journal of Targeting, Measurement and Analysis for Marketing, 11 (1), 24-33. 60. Zeithaml, Valarie A., Roland T. Rust, and Katherine N. Lemon (2001), “The Customer Pyramid: Creating and Serving Profitable Customers,” California Management Review, 43 (4), 118-142. TABLE 1 Summary of empirical generalization articles Authors Anderson et al. 94 Hallowell 96 Anderson et al. 97 Bolton 98 Bernhardt et al. 00 Yeung et al. 00 Yeung and Ennew 01 Yeung et al. 02 Guo et al. 04 Reinartz and Kumar ‘03 Reinartz and Kumar Brusco et al ‘03 Brusco et al ‘03 Li ‘95 Reinartz, Thomas, and Kumar ‘05 Li 95 Hallowell 96 Niraj et al. 01 Reinartz and Kumar 03 Garland 04 Nagar and Rajan 05 Reinartz, Thomas, and Bascoul ‘06 Direction of Effect Dependent Variable(s) Customer Satisfaction + Firm profitability + Individual Duration + Firm profitability + Individual Duration + in time series, NS Store profit for cross-sectional +, but R-squared low Firm profitability Mostly +, but varies Firm and market generated across industries measures of firm performance + in 5/6 years Net and Operating firm income + lagged effect Firm profitability Marketing + (expenditure level) Individual duration + (loyalty program) + (service) + (product quality) + (discount programs) + (retention dollars, marketing contacts) + + NS + + NS + Thomas and Sullivan ’05 DoubleClick ’04 Kumar and Venkatesan ‘05 Kushwaha and Shankar ‘07 Campbell and Frei ‘06 + Nagar and Rajan ‘05 Reinartz and Kumar 03 Malthouse and Blattberg 05 + + + + + - + Industry Multiple industries Retail banking Multiple industries Cell phones Restaurant chain Multiple industries Multiple industries Multiple industries Multiple industries Retail catalog Individual duration Individual duration Individual duration Individual duration Retail catalog Telecom Telecom Telecom Individual profitability B2B Hi Tech Cross-Buying Individual duration Division profitability Customer profitability Individual duration Customer profitability Firm performance measures Individual revenues and purchase frequency Multichannel Purchasing Individual revenues and purchase frequency Individual revenues Individual revenues and duration Individual purchase frequency and volume/purchase occasion Revenues Past Purchase Behavior Firm performance Individual duration Individual-level profit Telecommunications Retail banking Grocery distributor Retail catalog Retail banking Retail banking Direct mail book seller; Catalog retailer Retail Retail B2B Hardware and Software Retail Retail banking Retail banking Retail catalog Retail catalog, non profit, education, Li 95 Niraj et al. 01 - Individual duration Customer profitiabilty software Telecommunications Grocery distributor