Single-payer Health Care Reform in South Korea: Major actors behind the reforms Chang-Bae Chun, Ph. D Health Insurance Research Centre National Health Insurance Corporation, South Korea 1. INTRODUCTION During the 1990s many countries experienced rapid changes in health care. Particularly following the economic crisis of the 1970s, most developed European countries attempted to reduce health care expenditure by introducing competition mechanisms into health systems and putting private market elements into their public health sectors. However, the Republic of Korea (hereafter Korea) pursued a uniquely different path. The restructuring of health care in the 1990s followed an altogether opposite trend compared to other countries’ paths. Korea integrated multi-insurers into a single-insurer in July 2000 and thus reinforced income redistribution by enlarging risk pooling. This paper begins with the question of why Korea proceeded along this unique path. To answer the question, it will first explore current fundamental reforms of health care that have taken place since the late 1990s. Then it will analyze the background to these reforms: that is, why these were possible in Korea at that time? In order to answer the question, this paper will focus on two-key questions: firstly, what happened and secondly why this was. The methodology of this paper is based on a case study, because this method can be convenient and relevant to analyze complex cases in greater depth than other research methods. A case study makes it possible to study all variables with relation to studying the content, and makes it possible to look at the internal relationships holistically. Besides, in order to analyze the equity in financing and redistribution after the reform in 2000, statistical approaches were adopted. For this, several data sets were used, and sample data was extracted from the total population data stored in the National Health Insurance Corporation (NHIC) database. This paper consists of six chapters. Chapter II will briefly mention the theoretical background and analysis framework, covering hypothesis, and framework of this paper. Chapter III will describe the key features of the health care reforms achieved since the late 1990s to the present. This chapter will intensively discuss the major outcomes of reforms such as integration and income redistribution. Chapter IV will identify the underlying forces behind health care reform in Korea and thus this part will be a main discussion section of this case study. Chapter V will find policy implications from the outcomes of health care reform and analyze the main actors in the transformation of the health care system in Korea since the 1990s. The final chapter summarizes the outcomes associated with a single insurer and mentions the roles of major players in achieving this health care reform. 2. HYPOTHESIS AND ANALYSIS FRAMEWORK To grasp the causes of the transformation from multi to single-payer, and from regressive to progressive in terms of income redistribution, this paper needs to set a hypothesis that can elucidate the causes of changes to the health care system which have occurred since the late 1990s. Especially in the midst of globalization and economic recession, all reforms represent a significant and meaningful development. As mentioned before, it was a very uncommon phenomenon, considering most countries experienced reductions in spending on health care and more dependence on private resources (Mishra 1999). Despite the difficult situation, the Korean health care system achieved a single payer model after almost 20 years of ‘big debate’. To explore the cause of these changes more thoroughly, it is meaningful to suggest an independent variable to explain the cause of the changes in the late 1990s and early 2000s. For this, this paper set hypothesis: the development of health care systems with a single insurer and the reinforced income redistribution scheme became possible with the emergence of power elites and the advent of civic groups. Based on the above hypothesis the paper briefly features a framework of analysis to find the causal actors behind the health care reforms. So the framework of analysis in this paper starts with suggesting two independent variables: the emergence of new power elites and the activities of civic groups. Figure 2-1 shows the analysis framework for the causes of the Korean health care reform. [Figure 2-1] Analysis framework Emergence of Civic Group Multi-payers Single-payer Regressive income redistribution Inefficiency Residual Model Transformations Progressive income redistribution Efficiency Social-democratic Model Emergence of SocialDemocratically minded power elite Pressure/Input Support/ Alliance 3. FROM MULTI-PAYERS TO AN SNGLE-PAYER This chapter in general belongs to ‘what happened?’ It thus naturally relates to the discussion of integration of health care in 2000. Integration itself can be seen as beyond just achieving a single-payer insurance system. Perhaps to many Koreans, the integration of health care itself has great significance, both from political and social perspectives. 3. 1. Risk pooling Since the introduction of compulsory health insurance for corporate employees and public servant/private school employees in 1977, many problems have been exposed. One of them was the problem of a weak risk pooling mechanism. This drawback had been derived from the structural weakness of the multi-fund systems, which resulted from the existence of many small societies. The following data shows that in 1980, when only 20 per cent of corporate employees were covered, the number of societies amounted to 602. Worse, among these corporate societies, 229 funds (38%) of total funds in 1980 would have less than 1000 people insured. Moreover, more than 75 % of societies insured less than 3000. In these circumstances, income redistribution under weak risk pooling structures was not possible. [Table 3-1] The number of societies by size of the insured (1980, persons) Less than Less than Less than Less than More than 1000 3000 5000 10000 10000 602 229 221 65 52 35 100 38 37 11 9 5 - 38 75 86 95 100 Total No.of Societies % Accumulated % Source: MOHW(1980) “Internal report by the insurer integration and dismantling committee” The problem derived from the weak risk-pooling structure, due to significant differences in membership didn’t disappear but rather worsened with the coverage expansions for the self-employed in 1988 and in 1989 for rural and for urban residents respectively. Because insurers for the self-employed were founded solely on basic local administrative units such as Gun and Gu, the gap in members, as table 3-2 shows, between the largest and smallest societies was significant. While the smallest societies are mostly located in rural areas and cover at best 3,912 households, the largest insurers in the large city number more than 121,975 households – i.e. a 3,118 times difference between the two insurers. Under these significance gaps between societies, risk pooling in health insurance was intrinsically impossible. In addition, considering the social demographic traits that two-thirds of the elderly live in the rural area (Anderson 1989), risk pooling through health insurance seemed rather contradictory. [Table 3-2] Comparison of societies’ size for self-employed (Jun. 2000) The smallest (Yang-Gu) No. of household 3,912 No. of the insured 11,699 The largest (Goyang city) Difference of No. of No. of the No. of household insured households 121,975 348,057 3,118 times Source: Internal report from NHIC (2001). However, with the reform of 2000, the problems of narrow and weak risk pooling disappeared. This single payer system made the risk pool nationwide by integrating all insurers into a single pool and by spreading individual risks across a pool of the entire population. As a result, the establishment of the single insurer was a way of combining risk pooling into one insurer and thus overcoming the previous weak risk pooling mechanism under the multi-payer schemes. 3. 2. Equity As mentioned before, multi-payer schemes brought about financial imbalances between insurers. The fundamental gap in financing was caused by the deterioration of equity in financing, such as unfair contribution systems and different social demographic backgrounds. For example, small insurers located in rural areas consisting mainly of elderly members would likely fall under the structures of fundamental financing instability, partly because the old experience increased illness and are thus likely to require more medical services. Moreover, since the elderly do not have regular incomes, it was common for monthly contributions to be late. Consequently, the small insurers in rural areas suffered chronic financial instability. However, so-called ‘rich insurers’, which are mainly located in urban areas and largely consisted of the younger generations, had better positions demographically and financially and therefore were financially stable. Contrary to the smaller ‘poor societies’, the insured of the rich societies were less likely to get treatment, because they were relatively young compared to those of the poor societies. More than that, they were working and earned regular incomes, so they could pay their monthly contributions on time. As the table 3-3 shows, financial disparity between rich and poor payers inevitably incurred. [Table 3-3] Number of deficit societies by years (1990-1997) Years 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 No. of societies 254 266 266 266 266 227 227 227 No. of deficit 194 1 0 18 28 26 147 59 Percent (%) 76.4 0.4 0 6.8 10.5 11.5 64.8 30.0 Source: National Federation of Medical Insurance, “Balance Accounts Report by years” Similarly, the financial status of corporate societies was also capricious. Although the finances of corporate societies were not so serious as for the self-employed, there were also significant disparities between rich and poor societies. In general, the societies who largely consisted of young employees in smaller work-sites kept sound finances, while societies with relatively older employees with more dependents in larger companies tended to suffer financial deficits. As the table 3-4 shows, the degree of financial disparity between insurers deteriorated to an easily distinguishable situation. That is, while some insurers were in danger of insolvency, others accumulated huge reserves. [Table 3-4] No. of societies 145 Numbers of deficit societies: corporate insurers (1995) Size of the surplus Less than 70 % 1 71-79% 80-89% 26 67 Size of the deficit More than More than More than 90% 100% 110% 41 8 2 Source: NHIC (2001), Health Insurance White Paper, p 69. Meanwhile, financial gaps between the self-employed and corporate society rapidly increased as well. While most of corporate society had sound financial status, most selfemployed societies were in the crisis of insolvency during the 1980s - 1990s. Given this significant disparity, the government was able to do almost nothing, but depend on increase of contribution rate. As table 3-5 illustrates, the disparity between the two occupation-based societies was distinct in 1996. The percent of accumulated reserves was calculated by dividing the claimed amount for the current year against the total accumulated reserve. [Table 3-5] The disparity of reserve between the corporate and self-employed societies (1996) The corporate societies Hwasung Seoul 26 Unit 701 % 586% The self-employed societies Hanil Synthetic 536% Jung-up City Young-Dong Gun 0% 0% Source: HIAIBE (2001), ibid., p. 217. * Note: Per cent of the reserve = accumulated reserve/current year’ medical costs The ultimate and best way to solve this fundamental problem is finding a way towards a single-payer scheme and a fair contribution method under which “contribution ability to payment” and, as a result, “better-off pays more and worse-off pays less” was established. In the end, the new contribution methods were introduced in 1998 and 2000, for self-employed and corporate insured respectively. This section looks at the result of the reforms from various equity viewpoints. Benefit Ratios The Benefit Ratio is calculated from total amounts of payment to total benefit amounts in order to see the extent or degree of benefit compared to payment of contribution. The formula is as follows: - Benefit Ratio = Benefit amounts/Contribution amounts If the benefit ratio is more than 1, according to the above calculation, it means that the amounts of benefit are larger than the amounts of contribution. By contrary, if less than 1, it means the insured pays more contribution than the eventual benefit. Thus, if the benefit ratio of low-income classes is higher than that of higher income classes, or the amount of benefit is more than those of the contributions, it suggests that income redistribution effects exist from the rich insured to the poor insured. As table 3-6 show, the benefit ratio for the self-employed shows that there was a lot of income redistribution between low and high-income groups. While the benefit ratio of the insured that pay a contribution of more than 2 million Won a year was 0.59, that of the insured who pay a contribution of less than 100,000 Won a year was 5.89. Consequently, these figures support the fact that there was a significant income transfer from higher payers of contributions to lower payers. Meanwhile, in terms of the use of medical treatment, low-income groups visit medical institutions more often than highincome classes; the former group’s average frequency of medical treatments a year per capita was 17.52 and the latter was 14.48. [Table 3-6] Benefit ratio by income brackets: Self-employed (2001) Frequency Medical Bene Cont (in Cont.* Cont.* Benefit Benefit use (yearly) (capita) (yearly) (Capita) (Capita) Ages 1000Won) M F Total fit Ratio ** <10 52 110 162 60.90 82822 71101 488193 406374 17.52 5.89 10-20 403 392 795 44.59 148353 116367 452717 276449 10.17 3.05 20-30 499 236 735 44.60 248501 135887 571708 242861 10.87 2.30 30-40 594 173 767 44.86 347435 145940 728301 246504 11.70 2.10 40-50 520 90 610 46.63 448953 165467 820316 271127 12.05 1.83 50-60 433 73 506 47.24 548187 187898 866599 258819 12.62 1.58 60-70 354 41 395 46.75 647158 205635 907365 267088 12.13 1.40 70-80 249 34 283 47.70 746816 238816 946814 258203 11.74 1.27 80-90 174 29 203 49.42 847732 284147 885801 243491 11.15 1.04 90-100 129 17 146 47.45 947992 301918 1188627 306007 11.45 1.25 100-150 262 32 294 49.82 1182229 378158 1119437 305589 12.87 0.95 150-200 67 4 71 51.27 1701431 507220 1428199 375172 14.05 0.84 >200 31 2 33 50.48 2371818 816991 1405764 409342 14.48 0.59 3767 1233 5000 46.75 491170 187316 762655 270439 11.79 1.55 Total * Excluding government subsidy per household. ** Cases of treatment times a year per Capita. Table 3-7 below shows the analysis results of 2002 for the self-employed. There are almost identical trends and results both in medical use and benefit ratios; the lowest bracket visited 17.02 a year per capita, while the highest income group used 15.25. Undoubtedly, this result means income transference effects exist between high and low income groups. The benefit ratio also shows almost the same results as that of the previous year 2001, showing 7.69 of benefit ratio in the lowest earners and 0.37 in the highest earners. [Table 3-7] Benefit ratio by income brackets: Self-employed (2002) Frequency Medica Cont’(in Cont’ Cont’ Benefit Benefit Ages 1000Won) M F (yearly) Total Benefi l use (capita) (yearly) (capita) t Ratio (capita) <10 163 179 342 54.0 70,054 54,998 538,741 394,847 17.02 7.69 10-20 419 293 712 44.6 149,842 116,270 379,399 232,897 10.23 2.53 20-30 372 199 571 45.8 254,314 143,060 598,466 270,633 11.54 2.35 30-40 480 155 635 45.3 355,248 180,748 684,766 264,558 12.01 1.93 40-50 445 107 552 45.9 458,952 193,766 736,724 262,563 12.19 1.61 50-60 318 62 380 46.9 550,453 202,479 793,247 242,790 12.46 1.44 60-70 444 75 519 46.5 648,165 231,043 835,355 250,801 12.09 1.29 70-80 268 50 318 47.5 757,124 269,219 959,689 286,533 12.14 1.27 80-90 212 20 232 48.2 853,583 263,197 1000472 280,850 12.94 1.17 90-100 175 19 194 50.0 954,751 318,015 883,711 265,373 13.26 0.93 100-150 355 44 399 51.1 1,204,938 384,588 1231303 361,005 13.64 1.02 150-200 87 8 95 50.2 1,728,351 669,281 897,886 283,622 14.60 0.52 >200 48 3 51 54.3 2,451,798 928,975 910,808 311,158 15.25 0.37 Total 3786 1214 5000 47.3 538,875 214,929 740,872 277,072 12.42 1.37 Looking at the benefit ratio for the corporate insured, similarly to the self-employed’s benefit ratio, there was a high level of income redistribution between high-income and low-income groups. That is, the benefit ratio of low income groups who pay less than 100,000 Won a year was 5.96, while the benefit ratio of high income groups who pay more than 2 million Won a year was at best 0.31 (Table 3-8). In terms of frequency of medical use, however, low-earners use was less frequent compared to high earners (9.89 vs. 12.79 times). The result seemed to relate to the ages of employees and the size of enterprises. These figures might result from a general hypothesis that the relatively young and low earners enjoy better health and small-sized work sites mainly consist of blue-collar workers, for whom frequent medical treatment for their employees can be discouraged compared to larger companies with comparatively older white-collar workers. Like 2001, the result from 2002 shows similar trend (Table 3-9). [Table 3-8] Benefit ratio by income level: Corporate insured (2001) Frequency Cont(1000 Cont Cont Benefit Benefit Medical Benefit (yearly) (capita) (yearly) (capita) Use(capita) Ratio Ages Won) M F Total <10 76 70 146 39.31 89,103 52,549 531,129 196,408 9.89 5.96 10-20 537 557 1,094 36.76 158,341 102,351 550,132 229,883 10.84 3.47 20-30 866 355 1,221 34.32 257,531 143,396 691,304 229,250 11.27 2.68 30-40 659 120 779 36.15 358,215 162,046 975,914 299,238 12.43 2.72 40-50 529 76 605 37.51 453,693 168,747 1,113,440 285,098 13.05 2.45 50-60 397 46 443 38.53 560,558 189,301 1,319,048 314,098 14.52 2.35 60-70 213 9 222 39.87 657,817 180,524 1,253,605 280,518 15.16 1.91 70-80 155 7 162 41.25 738,896 210,770 1,296,792 298,109 14.10 1.76 80-90 137 6 143 44.50 845,502 228,304 1,364,159 284,701 13.90 1.61 90-100 55 3 58 44.55 970,301 287,668 1,134,799 263,647 13.66 1.17 100-150 89 1 90 47.43 1,191,496 350,014 1,294,581 315,156 13.29 1.09 150-200 21 0 21 47.90 1,696,697 607,922 1,060,293 297,823 11.50 0.62 >200 15 1 16 46.88 2,760,630 830,266 865,033 235,843 12.79 0.31 Total 3,749 1,251 5,000 37.26 386,499 157,604 888,714 261,957 12.23 2.30 [Table 3-9] Benefit ratio by income level: Corporate insured (2002) Frequency Cont(1000 Cont Cont Benefit Benefit Medical Benefit (yearly) (capita) (yearly) (capita) use(capita) Ratio Ages Won) M F Total 1 23 13 36 42.92 85,420 54,158 550,938 221,140 12.21 6.45 2 383 409 792 40.31 161,399 100,752 589,290 224,186 11.53 3.65 3 433 330 763 34.67 249,542 154,536 615,872 238,119 12.06 2.47 4 677 251 928 35.27 353,564 188,105 817,397 261,395 12.13 2.31 5 513 146 659 36.79 460,913 196,954 1,121,259 296,057 14.21 2.43 6 421 88 509 38.00 560,686 207,879 1,096,253 282,459 14.21 1.96 7 355 54 409 40.14 657,965 214,382 1,311,452 316,913 15.02 1.99 8 250 34 284 42.65 750,153 234,909 1,128,136 262,853 13.99 1.50 9 185 20 205 44.10 836,694 250,454 1,157,741 277,962 14.02 1.38 10 169 17 186 46.78 940,140 287,643 1,261,108 294,282 14.29 1.34 11 162 12 174 47.44 1,181,179 409,294 1,196,302 301,989 13.76 1.01 12 27 4 31 47.84 1,719,155 509,040 1,133,175 324,446 14.97 0.66 13 22 2 24 46.88 3,002,250 1,148,007 798,274 215,792 10.23 0.27 Total 3,620 1,380 5,000 38.68 479,591 196,722 920,606 266,484 13.07 1.92 Income transfer ratio (ITR) This section tries to establish the income transfer ratio, using contribution and benefit occupancy ratios. Occupancy ratio is the ratio of each group’s contribution and benefit ratio to total amount of contributions and benefits. This indicator easily shows contribution and benefit levels of each class to the total amount of contribution and benefits. Thus, the formula for ITR is as follows: - Contribution occupancy ratio (COR) = Sum of contribution amount of each - group/total contribution amount × 100 Benefit occupancy ratio (BOR) = Sum of benefit amount of each group/ total - benefit amount × 100 Income transfer ratio (ITR) = Each class’s benefit occupancy ratio/each class’s contribution occupancy ratio Based on the above calculations, if the figure of the income transfer ratio is larger than 1, it means positive income redistribution. Therefore, if the income transfer ratio of low income classes is larger than 1, and if that of high-income class is less than 1, it shows that there is income transfer between high and low income classes. The figures of Table 3-10 were calculated from the above tables and show the income transfer ratios. As the following table shows, the figures were similar between the two compared years. That is, the figures of income transference ratios of low-income classes, both in self-employed and corporate insured, were less than 1, while those of benefit occupancy ratios of lowincome groups were more than 1. All the mentioned figures, therefore, suggest that income redistribution effects were reinforced by the reforms of NHI integration. [Table 3-10] Income transfer ratios COR BOR ITR Classifications Selfemployed Corporate 2001 2002 2001 2002 2001 2002 Lowest-income group 0.81 0.67 4.13 5.15 5.10 7.69 Highest-income group 23.10 23.49 11.90 8.72 0.52 0.37 Lowest-income group 0.82 0.78 3.95 4.31 4.82 5.53 Highest-income group 25.71 27.40 6.43 6.25 0.25 0.23 3. 3. Efficiency Inefficiency issues didn’t abate at all before the integration due to the multi-fund systems. Indeed inefficiency problems were so prevalent that almost all criticisms of health insurance tended to relate to inefficiency: from inefficiency in management due to the multi-payer structure to inefficiency in cost containment. The integration of NHI promoted efficiency of organizational management by establishing economies of scale. The introduction of standardization and unification in various work-fields supported by the computerized information network will accelerate the reduction of administrative costs. Table 3-11 shows the statistical data on reduction of administrative costs over several years. Of total health expenditure, the administrative costs were significantly reduced from 7.3% in 2000 to 4.5% in 2003 with the emergence of the positive effects of health care reforms. Moreover, integration into a single-insurer was accompanied by monopsonic power. This power can be attributed to improved purchasing power and giving insurers suitable levers to control costs efficiently (Carr-Hill 1994). [Table 3-11] Comparisons of annual administrative costs (Unit: million Korean Won) Before integration After integration Classification 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Total Expen.(A) 76,787 87,157 95,614 Admi. Costs(B) 6,719 7,020 6,814 7,799 7,109 6,771 7,404 B/A 8.8% 8.1% 7.1% 7.3% 5.0% 4.6% 4.5% 106,736 141,075 147,984 2003 165,317 Source: NHIC (2002), Internal Report. 4. MAJOR ACTORS OF HEALTH CARE REFORMS This chapter is a case analysis to understand independent variables that can explain why and how the health reforms took place at that time. Simply put, this section is to find the causes and key actors of the reforms and verify them through the case analysis. For this, this chapter will presuppose two independent variables first, and then look at how these independent variables can play a role in bringing about health care. 4. 1. Civic groups 4. 1. 1. The situational background of the emergence of civic groups in the 1990s It is true that today’s health care achievement, especially considering globalization and the economic crisis, was unthinkable without the emergence and role of civic groups, most of them founded in the 1990s. It was a time that civil society emerged, taking up the so-called social citizenship, a concept developed by T.H Marshall in 1939 just before the Second World War. Like in Europe before and after World War II, Korean people were beginning to understand the influence of the social rights movement in the 1980s, when the democracy movement erupted up against the tyrannical Chun Do-whan regime. Once democratic governments were elected in the early 1990s, with a civilian president-elect Kim Young-sam, the democratic movement rapidly shifted to a social rights movement. So it was in auspicious circumstances in the 1990s that a few nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) were established in Korea. Coincidently, citizens began to recognize that social rights were not spontaneously given by government, but rather rights which were won by asking government to provide social protection. As Table 4-1 shows, this thought was developed into a more fundamental thought on the principle of social policy that the welfare provision by government was not a grace from a King or an overwhelming authority, but the right things they should be naturally entitled to posses. Interestingly, this people’s attitude toward the role of the government was rooted in their consciousness on health (Table 42) [Table 4-1] Korean attitudes to the State’s responsibility for individual welfare May 1997 October 1998 Individual responsible 51% 17% State responsible 49% 83% Source: Shin and Rose, 1997, 1998 [Table 4-2] Korean’ consciousness on health and other social affairs Health 44.9% Wealth 24.5% Education Job Child Edu.. Marriage Others 7.4% 6.5% 4.6% 2.5% 9.6% Source: Korea National Statistical Office (2004), “2003 Korean Social Indicators” 4.1. 2. Policy network between government and NGOs in health insurance Before the achievement of the single insurer system and emergence of powerful NGOs in Korea, most important decision making in health policy was decided by the so-called symbiotic relationships between the Ministry of Health and Welfare and large industry groups (Bidet 2004:Shin D.2000). Indeed the hegemony that large corporate business groups played dated back to the first stage of Korean health insurance implementation in 1977. In the early stage of health insurance programmes, when Park Jung-hee government had to urgently expand coverage of health insurance without spending government subsidies, the government had to rely on large business, because the latter paid half of their employees’ contributions. In the circumstances, it seemed not unnatural that the close relationship between the two key players was developed to become policy-partners in the health policymaking process. However, the symbiotic relationships had to face a new situation and were challenged with the advent of the single payer system in 2000. This time, doubtless, civic groups occupied the vacancy the big corporate business had left, as large portions of their roles had to be passed to new upcoming occupants, NGOs. NGO played an important role influencing health care polices in a variety of ways. In general, there were several ways that civic groups utilized for the reform of health insurance. Firstly, civic groups themselves first incorporated all pro-integration civil societies into the ‘Health Care Alliance for Integration and Benefits Expansion’ (HCAIBE), founded in April 1994, which consisted of 77 civic groups and labour unions, etc., in order to focus their ability to achieve their ultimate goal of health care reform. The first stage of their main strategy set out integration agenda. In order to spread the importance of health care reform to the public, the next thing the HCAIBE had to do was to organize street demonstrations. Secondly, both individual civic groups and the HCAIBE invited a group of progressive academics to develop more articulated theories and philosophies. Most of the scholars who had actively participated in civic groups were rather young and had studied social welfare and public health. The progressively minded academics actively spread their ideas and played important roles in expediting integration by participating in many important television debates, seminars, and contributing to newspapers. Thirdly, the representatives of NGOs officially participated in major policy-making bodies. As a result of their broad participation at various levels, NGOs consistently proposed that increased revenues from increased contribution rates should be spent on expanding benefit coverage. This principle was successfully championed and so changes to contribution rates became very difficult, unless government or provider associations could provide sufficient evidence for the need for adjustment of contribution rates to catch up with the increase of fee schedule (Table 4-3). [Table 4-3] Changes of contribution and fee schedule rates Increase of Increase of fee contribution rates* schedule rates Average (1990-2000) - ** 8.87% Increased revenue 2001 4.6% 7.08% from contribution 2002 6.7% -2.90% should be use to the 2003 8.5% 2.79% expansion of benefit 2004 6.75% 2.65% coverage Years Source: NHIC (2004), Internal Report. * For the corporate insured ** Not available due to different contribution rate under the multi-funds systems. 4. 1. 3. Case studies on activities of civic groups In the previous section, we saw the ways NGOs were involved in the policy-making process and how civic groups strengthened their influence in the process of health insurance reform. This section will focus on several cases that show how NGOs really affected on health insurance policies. The Case of Medical Savings Account (MSA) In January 2001, Choi Sun-Jung, Minister of Health and Welfare, reported to the President that it was time to introduce the Medical Savings Account to reduce public medical expenditure by curtailing frivolous treatment and to increase cost consciousness at the point of treatment. After this announcement, however, the Peoples’ Solidarity for Participatory Democracy (PSPD) issued a statement regarding MSA. Needless to say, it strongly denounced not only the lack of discussion, but also argued the MSA was not appropriate to the reality in which coverage of public health insurance was insufficient. The following is part of the statement on MSA: “ … The announced MSA, however, is a system that introduces personal charges for medical treatment based on income and ability to pay and it will restrict medical access of the elderly and the poor…” (www.peoplepower21.org/setion, consulted on 10th June 2005). Although it was not clear how much the role of the PSPD can be attributed to blocking the policy implementation at that time, and whether the opposition of the PSPD stopped the policy directly or indirectly, it is not difficult to guess that the role of the PSPD had a significant impact on the withdrawal of the new policy. Coincidence or not, the PSPD’s statement was reported by many newspapers over the following couple of days after new policy initiative was launched by MOHW. For example, Munhwa-ilbo, one of the broadsheets in Korea, criticized the MSA as the following: “ …. However, the problem is that the MSA will likely bring about other problems of inequity between the rich and the poor. Thus the new policy can’t avoid criticism that government has put financial burdens on weaker social groups …” (Munwhailbo, 31st Jan. 2001). Two days later, after the announcement of the new policy by the MOHW, on 2nd February 2001, the ruling party officially announced that the introduction of MSA would be postponed for a certain period. Also, it added that it was time to reassess how current public health insurance could be improved. The chairman of the social policy committee in the ruling party confirmed that the MSA system could be an option in the long run and it thus couldn’t be considered an option at that time (ibid, 2nd February 2001). Consequently, with the widespread unpopularity of MSA, MOHW officially withdrew from its first position and added that the final decision on implementation of this policy should depend on national consensus (ibid, 7 February 2001). The above pattern and process was repeated over several major policy initiatives during the 1990s after many civic groups had been established in Korea. Any policy that was likely to threaten equity in financing and access to medical care faced strong protests from civic groups. Many influential newspapers then criticized the problematic policies, quoting opinions of experts who were usually related to the activities of civic groups. The Glivek case The following is a vivid example of the Health Right Network’s (HRN) activity to influence health care policy in Korea. Recently, a new innovative drug called ‘Glivek’ for the treatment of leukemia was added to coverage lists, but the price of the drug was too expensive to be prescribed for the poor, even though the price of the drug was determined on the basis of the Swiss estimated price to relieve the burden on patients. So the price was determined at 17,862 Won per capsule, rather than 23,045 Won, which is based on the price across of A7 countries. Faced with low prices, providers threatened to stop providing the drug and this situation pushed the government to seek solutions. Nevertheless HRN still raised questions about the irrationality of the drug pricing decision method, which was entirely determined by the average price of A7 countries. The NGO recognized that the price determined by the current method was inevitably higher and HRN therefore argued that the government should also consider other elements, such as different economic situations and consider different health care system, such as low benefit and high user charges. (www.healthright.org. consulted on 10th June 2005). As mentioned earlier, NGOs usually adopted a range of methods in order to achieve their goals. For example, raising and diffusing social rights to citizens, checking government policies, and organizing demonstrations. More than the others, the last method demonstrating is interesting and unique in achieving their aims for the health of ordinary people. In this case, the HRN planned a one person demonstration, chain strikes, at several locations, asking the government to withdraw and reduce the price that had been already determined. As a result, NGOs and patients made the government listen. Indeed, the government reviewed the price of the drug and tried to find reasonable ways to resolve the complaints from patients. In the end, an agreement between government and the pharmaceutical company was reached that guaranteed 10 % free provision of the total purchase for patients and that, on the other hand, increase drug price based on A7 countries (MOHW Notification, 25 Jan. 2003) To sum up, two cases are enough to understand how civic groups influenced the health policy area. In many ways it is not exaggerating to say that the roles of NGOs in health care reforms since the late 1990s were a decisive force toward more redistribution and greater equity. Briefly, there are several policy implications with regard to the role of NGOs based on the above two cases. First, the major civic groups occupied new positions in policy-making and decision processes as a key policy-partner. Second, their energies come from ordinary people, not from NGOs themselves. All NGOs operate with membership fees that are voluntarily paid by members themselves. It was natural that under these structure leaders of NGOs should follow the intentions of their members. Third, the involvement of NGOs in the policy process makes government policy transparent as well as more beneficiary-oriented. Last but not least, center-left minded NGOs represent supportive forces in reinforcing health care reform, a path toward a social-democratic model. Therefore, all the above implications support the hypothesis that civic groups armed with a social-democratic orientation will be an independent variable in developing health insurance to redistribute income and provoke an equitable system. 4. 2. Emergence of new center-left power elite The influence of the new power elite should not be underestimated in the change of policy in the health care reforms. Most of the new political elite, who occupied many major posts in the Presidential Office and ruling party just after power shifted to the opposition party after 50 years, were armed with a social-democratic philosophy, emphasizing more state involvement and responsibility for health policy. Especially, the president-elect’s view on health care reform critically contributed to reshaping it in an equity orientation. Moreover, in consideration of power structures, it was expected that the political philosophy and will of the President would play a critical role in policymaking in Korea (Kwon, S. 2003). This section deals with three cases that provide evidence to support the fact that presidential power played a great role in changing policies and integrating health insurance societies. Of the three cases, two are related to roles of the power elite in deterring policy changes and the remaining one is in a supporting role. As mentioned before, reforming the single-payer system from multi-insurers took almost twenty years and the final result was achieved after numerous conflictions. As the following cases will show, the Korean health care would not have accomplished the single-payer system, had the power elites not emerged. First case: presidential power against integration (October 1980) Soon after the introduction of social health insurance in 1977, a clear voice against the multi-insurer system was first born, mainly within the MOHW, partly because most people didn’t recognized the problems due to the small number of beneficiaries under the initial system where only corporate employees working in firms with more than 300 workers could be insured. However, there were two opposing voices: one for integration and one against integration. The beginning of the debate surrounding health policy started in the early1980’s and continued for the last 20 years. At first, in May 1980, integration of health societies began with the inauguration of new minister Chen Myong-ki who then recognized the problem aroused due to small-size insurers in the early stages of multi-fund systems and so he ordered a special committee to review health insurance problems with the multi-payer scheme. Integrationists within MOHW then mainly consisted of officials who had studied social welfare and sociology, and they actively led discussion about integration, because most officials in MOHW already knew and had experienced the fact that multiple, small societies unavoidably lead to serious financial imbalances depending on the characteristics of their employees and the size of the insured. So they might think that they should establish the singlepayer plan before implementation of the pilot programme for the coverage extension to the self-employed, which was started in July 1981 at several regions. On the other hand, some officers in MOHW clearly opposed integration. In the meantime, after six months, members of the advisory organization under the MOHW submitted the final paper, called “The Plan for Integration of Health Insurance”, under which the so-called ‘Health Insurance Management Corporation’ was to be established as a single-insurer, to Minister Chen in October 1980. In October 1980, the plan was finally reported to President Chun Do-Hwan, a former military man. In November 1980, however, the President killed the integration plan by adding the so-called ‘study review’ instead. The authoritarian President Chun then accepted his staffs’ opinion that a unified health care system inevitably incurs serious financial instability and this would contribute to the burden on central government (HCAIBE 2001). Thus, the first chance at integration was blocked even though both ruling and opposition parties in parliament agreed to support the single payer scheme and a special committee suggested unified health insurance system was a more appropriate system than the multi-fund system. Second case: Presidential Veto to integration law (March 1989) With coverage expansion to rural residents in 1988, the issue of integration faced different stages. The pro-integration movement exploded almost spontaneously and voluntarily nationwide. This stage was quite different, compared to the first case, from various viewpoints. This time, the first huge opposition to the multi insurers system came from farmers across all regions and this protest developed further into a systematic social movement, organizing branches and demanding more government subsidies for rural residents (NHIC 2001). This movement from rural residents was an uncommon case in Korean tradition because rural people were accustomed to accepting government policy. There is no doubt that the farmer-led request for a single insurer was ignited based on their experiences: high contributions and low benefits compared to their expected high benefit coverage and low contributions. They clearly understood that the problems they faced were due to the structural problems of the multi-insurer system and therefore they believed that there was no alternative but a single-payer scheme As a result of an integrationist’s great efforts, in March 1989 the Parliament unanimously passed a law commanding a single-payer scheme. This time destiny was not on the integrationist’s side either. President Roh Tae-Woo vetoed the law after accepting the opinion from the Minister of Health and Welfare and therefore the law was returned to Parliament. According to the constitution, any law vetoed by the President should be aborted unless it gains votes from three quarters of the parliament members within the same assembly period. Otherwise the law will be automatically abrogated. Thus, once more integration failed to transform social insurance into a single payer system. However, the reasons of the veto were not acceptable to many prointegrationists. As a result, just after the Presidential veto, many civic groups, farmer’s organizations and labour unions were critical and reorganized to mobilize their power in achieving their unified goal of integration. Paradoxically, the veto by the President reinforced the movement towards integration and more civic groups and organizations got opportunities to raise their voices for the integration of health insurance. The Third Case (July 2000) After two critical chances at integration had been aborted, another opportunity was given for the integrationists after almost exactly 20 years since they first proposed integration in 1980. This time was quite different and there was great potential for integration after the peaceful power transition from the ruling to opposition party after almost 50 years of Korean democracy. Before the Presidential election was scheduled in December 1997, the three major parties, the ruling and the two in opposition, put forward integrationist proposals. First of all, the conservative ruling New Korean Party didn’t oppose integration of health insurance and another conservative Free Democratic Coalition was also ready to accept integration. The causation of change, of course, was largely due to the activities of HCAIBE and civic groups. And relatively closer to those groups was the progressive party of New Politics and People’s Coalition (NPPC) which had been actively supporting integration for a long time. In the meantime, the presidential candidate of the opposition party was elected in December 1997. President-elect Kim Dae-Jung has a belief in social solidarity and emphasized several times before the election that he would integrate health insurance if his party won power in the presidential election. Soon after the election and before the inauguration of his Presidency, the ‘committee for government transference’ selected the integration of health insurance as one of one hundred reform agendas. Also the Tripartite Committee, a newly established body, established soon after President Election in order to get social consensus in economic and social sectors with representatives of labour, employers and government, and confirmed that health care integration should go ahead with the single-payer system. With the emergence of social democratically minded power-elites in both the Presidential Office and Parliament, the process of integration progressed rapidly. Of course, there was anti-integration activity. Like in the previous two cases, strong opposition and rallies against integration erupted before and after the passage of the law in Parliament. Among pro-multi-insurers, the union workers of the corporate societies strongly opposed integration and they, as a result, led the opposition groups. However, unlike the previous two cases, the likelihood of success in aborting integration by supporters of multi-funds was thinner in the new environment. In the end, with the establishment of the single-payer scheme in July 2000, the long way to achieving health integration ended and faced a new stage. 5. PLOICY IMPLICATIONS Through the three cases in the previous chapter with regard to presidential power, we can find important policy implications. Among the three cases, two cases failed to achieve their goals since the highest power holders refused integration. But the third case showed the other way, accepting it and to a certain degree accelerating it. Thus, the result was ultimately different, although pre-existing conditions and parallel opinions over the pros-and-cons of integration had not changed. Then a question is raised here: why a different result was possible in third case. The answer can be attributed to the influence of presidential power and, on a broader level, power elites who were executing their powers by putting their ideas to the President. Importantly, the philosophy of the leader is an important element and thus can be an independent variable. That is, the influence of power elites comes from their ideas and philosophy. Indeed, of the three cases regarding health insurance integration in Korea over the last twenty years, the assumption that the philosophy of the President can play a critical role in health care reform is a persuasive variable with strong evidence. Conservative-minded Presidents refused integration two times because they weren’t armed with a social democratic philosophy but were pro business. However, President Kim meanwhile supported it, because he was filled with strong will and philosophy toward integration. As Kwon, S. (2003: 86) said, without the strong will of the President, the political resources to implement the structural reform in health care integration would not have been mobilized. Despite both the World Bank’s demand for Medical Savings Account (Kim C.Y et al.1998; World Bank 1998), and political pressures from supporters of the market-friendly social welfare schemes –such as big business and a segment of the labour unions – the Kim government took the opposite path with the help of his will and political ideology (Moon, et al. 2003). Needless to say, it was the social democratic mind that a new power group can refuse to accept MSA scheme forcedly suggested by World Bank, a powerful international creditor, under the economic crisis in the late 1990s. So the third case supported the second hypothesis that socially democratic minded power elites can influence the direction of policy to a more equitable and redistribution-reinforcing orientation. 6. CONCLUSIONS. As the first step to the further development towards a sustainable Korean model in health care was implemented in 2000, social health insurance of Korea faced a new situation. As a result of integration, first of all, significant outcomes in terms of efficiency and equity took place. Due to the single-payer system, as we’ve seen in previous chapters, administrative costs reduced gradually after the first year after integration. This was achieved with efficient management under the single insurer system in various fields, such as collection of contribution and reduction of underwriting affairs, etc. In addition, monopsony power of the single insurer after integration can help in increasing macro-efficiency, because the insurer can take efficient and flexible cost-containment measures. Second, in terms of equity in financing, there were significant changes. Achievements in this are undoubtedly due to reform to the single-payer system. Under the single-payer scheme, with implementation of a new, fair contribution method based on ability to pay with real income, income redistribution effects have been reinforced since 1998. As a result of integration, the pattern and level of income redistribution has been transformed from regressive to progressive under the single insurer. This paper has discussed what the underlying causal forces behind health care integration were. At first it presupposed two actors as independent variables and next, in order to support this hypothesis, this paper adopted a case study approach. The emergence of civic groups and new power elites with social democratic-mind sets were introduced as major actors in achieving their goal which had been aborted for the twenty years. As the civic groups increased their influence through their transparent and fresh policy approaches, they can occupy the position previously held by big business and enlarged their policy influence. The area of health policy was no exception in the late 1990s. The emergence of civil societies played a critical role in cracking the long held balance between proponents and opponents and thus finally giving more weight to the pro-integration side. Meanwhile, the advent of new power elites armed with social democratic ideas also played an important role in unblocking almost twenty years’ deadlock. As pointed out in previous case studies, two cases failed to achieve the singlepayer system mainly because two presidents did not have social democratic ideas and so they depended on their staff in making the decision. On the other hand, president Kim, in the third case, played a critical role in fulfilling integration, mainly because he is a committed social democrat especially in the area of health policy especially. In the end, as Kuhnle (2002) mentioned, the Korean health care system will ultimately move closer to those of the Scandinavian countries – the social democratic model described by Esping-Anderson (1990). Reference Anderson, G. (1989) “Universal health care coverage in Korea”, Health Affairs, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp 24-34. Carr-Hill, R (1994) “Efficiency and equity implications of the health care reforms”, Social Science Medicine, Vol. 39, No. 9, pp. 1189-1201. Cha, H.B (1998) The unified contribution system for the self-employed insured, Seoul: National Health Insurance Corporation Chun, H.Y and O.R Moon (1981) “The study on frequency of medical use and transfer degree of contribution”, Health care review, Vol. 32. [in Korean] Esping-Andersen, G. (1990) The three worlds of welfare capitalism, Cambridge, Polity Press. Health Care Alliance for Integration and Benefits Expansion (2001) Activity Report: 10 years’ struggle chronicle for health insurance integration, Seoul. [in Korean] Hussey, P. and G. F. Anderson (2003) “A comparison of single-and multi-payer health insurance systems and options for reform”, Health policy, Vol. 66, pp. 215-228. Kim, C. Y, T. S Lee, and Y. M Kim (1988) ”What does IBRD demand from us?” Monthly Welfare Trend, November, pp 33-41 [in Korean] Kim, Y. M. (2000) “The performance, Issues, and the future of the National Health Insurance”, The Trend of Health Insurance, Vol. 17. [in Korean] Korea National Statistical Office, (2004) “2003 Korean Social Indicators” [in Korean] Kuhnle, S.(2002). ‘Productive welfare in Korea: Moving towards a European welfare state type?’ (ECPR Joint Session of Workshops, 22-27 March) Kwon, S. (2003) “Healthcare financing reform and the new single payer system in the Republic of Korea: Social solidarity or efficiency?”, International Social Security Review, Vol . 56, pp 75-94. Ministry of Health and Welfare, (2003) Viability of health care integration. Mishra, R. (1999) Globalisation and the Welfare State, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Moon, C.I and J.I Yang (2002) “Globalization, Social inequality, and democratic governance in South Korea”, in J. S. Tulchin and A. Brown, eds. Democratic Governance and Social Inequality, Rienner Press National Federation of Medical Insurance (1997) Balance Accounts Report by years, Seoul National Health Insurance Corporation (2001), Health Insurance White Paper, Seoul.[in Korean] National Health Insurance Corporation (2002), National Health Insurance Statistical Yearbook, Seoul. [in Korean] Park, J.Y and J. W Park (2001) “The comparison of income redistribution effect of selfemployed after the health care integration”, Health Administration Review, Vol. 11, No. 2. [in Korean] Shin, D. C and Rose. R. (1997) Koreans evaluate democracy: A new Korea barometer survey, University of Strathclyde, Centre for the Study of Public Policy. Shin, D. C and Rose, R. (1998) Responding to economic crisis: the 1998 new Korean barometer survey, University of Strathclyde, Centre for the Study of Public Policy. Shin, D. M (2000) "Financial crisis and Social security: The paradox of the Republic of Korea", International Social Security Review, Vol. 53, No. 3, pp 83-107 World Bank (1998) “Korea Structural Adjustment Loan II Approved by the World Bank Board on Thursday, October 22”. http//www.healthright.org http//www. munwha.co.kr http//www. Peoplepower21.org/section