Session 7D: ERel-Ed: Teaching Students the Economics of Religion [ASREC] Meetings of the Association for the Study of Religion, Economics, and Culture, 2009 Enhancing Traditional Courses: Integrating Topics in the Economics of Religion Robert J. Stonebraker Winthrop University stonebrakerr@winthrop.edu Abstract: Integrating topics from the economics of religion can enrich a wide variety of undergraduate courses that use microeconomics. Students typically respond favorably and gain an enhanced appreciation of the power of economic concepts. Although most of my experimentation has been with an introductory economics course for non-majors, I have used them successfully in teaching Principles of Microeconomics, Intermediate Microeconomics, Public Finance, Game Theory and Managerial Economics as well. As my fellow panelists have so ably demonstrated, it is possible to teach entire courses on the economics of religion at different levels of sophistication for different audiences. I've considered trying to present a similar course, but faculty shortages and conflicting curricular demands have not allowed me to do so thus far. For those who might be interested, I've appended a sample syllabus for the course I envision. However, being unable to offer a full-fledged three-credit course does not mean I cannot teach many of the same concepts. Concepts from the economics of religion can easily be incorporated into many traditional economics courses. Why does it matter? Why should we care about such things? Why worry about integrating the economics of religion into an undergraduate curriculum? First, most of us obviously find the subject to be exciting, to be interesting, and to be important. We think it matters, and we want others to think the same. But not everything that matters can or should find its way into undergraduate classes. Some are too complex; others are too specialized. As economists we certainly appreciate the reality of scarce resources, opportunity costs, and trade-offs. Is the economics of religion a more valuable topic than its alternatives? I believe it is. My mantra is that economics is a social science that studies and predicts behavior in all areas of life. I push the notion that if behavior differs across people or across time, it is because the perceived costs and benefits of that behavior differ. Few of us awaken at 3:00 a.m. and, with no cause, spontaneously proclaim ourselves reborn. We change when we perceive it to be in our best interest to change. Not any sooner. Not any later. Students expect costs and benefits to drive corporate behavior. They expect Microsoft to weigh costs and benefits before setting software prices; they expect Disney to weigh costs and benefits before launching a new theme park. However, if economic models can illuminate corporate price and product decisions, why not other decisions as well? If expected costs and benefits drive every choice, then economic models and analytical tools should yield insights into every choice. I am an enthusiastic advocate of the economic way of thinking. I applaud what some have termed economic imperialism. I have spent much of my professional life trying to apply economics and economic thinking in a variety of non-traditional areas and making that analysis accessible to a wider audience.1 If we believe that economics is a way of thinking, we must teach accordingly. And the most effective way to do this is to show that basic economic principles can be applied in a wide variety of areas, not just "business" or "consumer" areas. That means we must use examples and illustrations from unconventional areas; areas like religion. Liberal arts students often bring unwelcome baggage into our economics classes. They walk in with disinterest, even latent hostility. If we are to reach them, to turn them on to the beauty and joy of economics, we must convince them that our field transcends blind profitmaximization. We need unconventional applications to show them how economics intersects with all areas of life, not just business. Lectures to such students about the economic choices of GM or Microsoft will elicit little more than sideways looks at nearest clock. But discussions about how economics can explain the relative success of different religious traditions will pique their curiosity and open up a new way of viewing the world around them. Business majors also can benefit from such an approach. They need to have their horizons expanded. Many of the employment/career opportunities will be in the non-profit world; yet few economics or business classes address this increasingly large segment of the economy. And religion certainly constitutes a major part of that sector. More importantly, in our more honest moments, we know that a year after they leave our classes few of our students will be able to accurately reproduce a graph showing a monopoly’s profit-maximizing price and output or even calculate an arc price elasticity of demand. Indeed, many cannot even remember them for the final exam. We think the intricacies of our graphs are exquisite, but most of our students do not. We might be better served by spending our time showing how economics relates to parts of their life that they do see as important, faith for example. Not only might such ideas prove to be more memorable, they might also be enough to tempt our students into wanting to pursue this thing called economics more seriously. How can we do it? I have used several different approaches to this. The easiest is to throw a few supplementary readings into a course syllabus at the appropriate places. Many excellent articles have appeared in multidisciplinary journals and are accessible to undergraduates with little or no background in economics. The readings need not be discussed in class; they can be used as independent learning opportunities for students outside of class. On occasion I have offered students a choice of several articles and then asked them to write a short two-page review of the article. In courses requiring longer research papers, issues in the economics of religion easily could be included in a list of suggested topics for students to pursue. Such assignments involve minimal class time, yet still give students insights into the field. However, many of you will want to devote in-class lectures and/or discussions to showing how economics theory can generate insights into religious behavior. Where can we teach it? Concepts from the economics of religion easily fit into a wide variety of courses. I personally have used them in teaching Introduction to Economics (for non-majors), Principles of Microeconomics, Intermediate Microeconomics, Public Finance, Managerial Economics, and Game Theory. [We teach a wide variety of courses in small departments.] Economics for non-majors Most of my experimentation has been with an introductory economics course for nonmajors. Teaching a general education course for non-majors can be challenging. Sociology majors and art majors and biology majors and even business management majors often show far less enthusiasm for price elasticity formulas than we might like. But there are advantages as well. Because these students will not be pursuing economics, I feel less need to present a specific set of traditional material to them. I appreciate the insights one can gain from production isoquants, but if I ignore them my students will not be disadvantaged in subsequent courses. They typically will not be taking other courses that use them. No harm will be done. It is liberating. It has allowed me more freedom in developing courses and to experiment with unconventional material; especially the economics of religion. I currently assign and discuss readings on three different topics. Area #1: Externalities/public good issues When teaching externalities I typically used pledge drives on public television to illustrate free-riding and discuss the problems in producing efficient amounts of non-excludable and non-rivalrous goods. The example works but, in recent years, I have thrown religious congregations into the discussion as well. I describe the congregations as providing a type of public good. We discuss how congregations theoretically could exclude non-buyers from products such as attendance at worship, but choose not to do so. Students understand that a relatively small number of members often contributes most of the needed financial resources while others free ride, and readily discuss how that might impact the ability of the congregation to produce desired ministry programs. They also like discussing the relationships between freeriding and congregational size and see that if people opt to free-ride in a religious context, they certainly will opt to free-ride elsewhere when the opportunity occurs. When I first used such concepts, I was pleasantly surprised to find students jumping into the discussion with similar examples drawn from their student organizations. They complained that such groups, like congregations, were carried by a small number of participants while many free-riding students happily claimed membership on their resumes, but faded into the shadows when work needed to be done. This allowed me to discuss differences between club goods and public goods, a distinction I typically would gloss over in such classes, and was a perfect lead-in to Larry Iannaccone's work on sacrifice and stigma.2 Every year at least one bright student then makes a link to fraternity hazing and sets off a spirited debate on the impact of such practices on the campus community. Area #2: Competitive vs. monopolistic behavior In this introductory class I skip the traditional graph-laden market theory found in textbooks, but want students to think clearly about how competition impacts market efficiency. After discussing externalities, students understand that market failures occur and want to know if there are other circumstances in which competitive markets can lead to inefficient outcomes. It's a perfect place to discuss "sacred canopy" issues. Does pluralism and competition in religious markets destroy the "sacred canopy" of a monolithic faith and lead to secularism, or does it invigorate religious resources and create increased religiosity? The notion that Episcopalians and Baptists might compete in ways very similar to that of Domino's and Papa John's captures the interest of many students. They often have interesting personal observations on the ways in which competition plays out in the real world. Area #3: Market strategies Traditional courses often discuss ways in which firms might increase customer demand for their products and keep customers from straying to other firms. As Iannaccone has pointed out, religious organizations have been unusually successful in demanding consumer exclusivity.3 How do they do it? How do the Baptists keep their members from dabbling in Catholicism and Buddhism? Could secular firms employ similar strategies with as much success? Students enjoy trying to unravel such puzzles and discussing how churches offer full-lines of cradle-to-grave services, how they develop belief systems (technologies) that are incompatible with other competitive systems, and how they develop strategies that reward allegiance and/or penalize defection to rivals. It works. It captures their attention and interest. I require students to write short papers in which they must apply concepts from the course to events and issues in their personal lives. A surprising number choose to discuss the economics of religion. Many students relate stories about free rider problems in their own congregation. One even wrote about how her mother quit her job as a lay assistant at a large congregation because of her frustration with free-riding members. Another wrote about how the construction of a new congregation across the street from his started a competitive battle between the two and another wrote of how her family had been pushed out of a strict, fundamentalist congregation because they insisted on worshipping at mainline churches on a semi-regular basis. At least in South Carolina, topics in the economics of religion hit home. Additional course applications These same concepts and examples that I use with non-majors easily can be incorporated into both principles of microeconomics and intermediate microeconomics courses. In fact, more advanced courses allow more complex discussions. The last time I taught intermediate micro I raised some eyebrows by asking whether or not terrorist acts by religious extremists could be considered rational economic behavior. And, when I had students read textbook material that used Hotelling models to describe how firms locate in product space, I shifted to an application of the economics of religion in class. It was an easy jump to use religion as example of a market with differentiated products and to discuss how denominations might jockey for optimal locations in a theological product space. We know that if cereal firms leave a product niche empty, new competitors are apt to invade at precisely that point. Can we observe the same phenomena in religious competition? Will new religious entrants look for empty or under-served market niches? And how might firms react to threats of entry? Secular firms crowded by entrants on one side of their product spaces might shift their product mix away from the competition toward the less crowded side of the space. Presidential candidates crowded from the right side of the political spectrum, might shift their stance to the left. Do religious firms react in similar ways? 4 Discussions of monopoly theory offer another tie-in. Here we can dip into the extensive literature on religious pluralism and the debates on monopoly vs. competitive religious markets and take off in almost any direction. Government entry barriers can create secular monopolies; can they create religious monopolies as well? Why might governments create such entry barriers? We know that secular monopolies raise price and restrict output. Would a religious monopoly have a similar impact? What "price" does a religious organization charge? Field courses offer still more opportunities. Religious examples of free-riding and club goods fit nicely into Public Finance courses, as do discussions of the interactions between public and private giving. When governments fund charitable activities, how are private, religious gifts affected? Do government dollars crowd out private dollars? Or, do government funds bestow a stamp of approval and crowd-in additional religious contributions? 5 Game theory courses might discuss how religion and religious communities can impact trust and reputation and how that might impact the outcomes of prisoners' dilemma and related types of games. Here in South Carolina many small business claim to provide "Christian" service. The local yellow pages advertise Christian plumbers, Christian roofers, Christian landscapers, and many others. Are these signals credible? How might a service provider make them credible? Finally, at least one text in the field now includes a discussion of Pascal’s Wager in what is called the Existence-ofGod-game. 6 My latest experiments have been in a Managerial Economics course I teach for Executive MBA students. I started by using some of my own research in the section on regression analysis and showed how publicly available data could be used to estimate cost and revenue equations for church congregations. Perhaps because a significant minority of my students work in nonprofits, and because nearly all are actively involved in their churches (remember, I’m in South Carolina), they seemed more interested in these statistical applications than in more traditional ones discussed in textbooks. When I then assigned them a short regression project, one student decided to check to see if there were statistical differences in the giving patterns of Presbyterian churches of two different regions, one that included wealthier communities than the other. Given the success of my first experiment, I next incorporated religious examples in the forecasting section of the course. Instead of discussing how public utilities might forecast kilowatt demand or how an auto dealership might forecast its inventory needs, I asked the class how a congregation might forecast contributions for an upcoming budget year. It set off the best discussion I ever had gotten of the subject. They immediately started to speculate on issues such as what factors drive rates of giving and will economic downturns cause people to cut back on giving as a result of lower disposable incomes, or will it cause them to give more to satisfy increased perceived charitable needs. Conclusions Concepts from the economics of religion literature complement the material in a variety of courses. When I first began using them I feared that they might be an unwelcome intrusion that would offend my students’ religious sensibilities. I was wrong. Students enjoy these nontraditional applications. They enjoy seeing how economic principles can be just as effective in shedding light on behavior in the sacred world as in the secular world. It grabs their attention and encourages them to think of new things in new ways. It’s fun to see. I encourage you to try it; you’ll like it. Endnotes: 1. My web-text, The Joy of Economics: Making Sense out of Life, can be accessed at http://faculty.winthrop.edu/stonebrakerr/book.htm. 2. Laurence R. Iannaccone, "Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-riding in Cults, Communes, and Other Collectives," Journal of Political Economy, volume 100, number 2 (April 1992), pp. 271-291. 3. Laurence R. Iannaccone, "Risk, Rationality, and Religious Portfolios," Economic Inquiry, April 1995, volume 33, number 2, p. 285(11). 4. For an interesting discussion of such applications, see Pedro Pita Barros, and Nuno Garoupa, “An Economic Theory of Church Strictness,” The Economic Journal, vol. 112, no. 3, July 2002, pp. 559-76. 5. Several of Dan Hungerman’s papers address this issue. See, for example, “Are Church and State Substitutes: Evidence from the 1996 Welfare Reform,” Journal of Public Economics, October 2004. 6. Harrington, Jr., Joseph E., Games, Strategies, and Decision Making, Worth Publishers, New York, 2009, p. 70. Note: This paper builds upon an earlier paper presented at the ASREC Meetings in October 2007. Appendix: Suggested Course Outline: Economics of Religion I. Introduction: Definitions and Rationale Descriptive data on religion and trends in religiosity II. Consumer Theory and Demand for Religion A. Religion and rational choice B. Factors affecting demand 1. Theoretical models 2. Empirical evidence C. Religious capital and choices through time III. Supply A. Theory of non-profit enterprises B. Churches as firms 1. Revenues a. Descriptive data b. Club theory, externalities and free riding c. Theories of religious giving 2. Costs a. Input choices and production technologies (1) Volunteerism: trends and issues (2) Professional labor markets: trends and issues b. Economies of scale and scope/optimal firm size IV. Religious Markets A. Equilibrium quantities of religion 1. Current data 2. Competition between sacred and secular institutions 3. Historical trends a. Demand-side explanations b. Supply-side explanations: competition and regulation B. Competitive market structures within religion 1. Descriptive data 2. Spatial models of competition and structure C. Choices across religious traditions 1. Risk and diversification 2. Denominational switching theory 3. Changes in denominational market shares a. Historical trends b. Models of denominational growth c. Church vs. sect 4. Competition and religious doctrine D. Choices within religious traditions 1. Congregational growth theory and data 2. Mega-churches: past, present, and future [My personal bias is to emphasize the role of economics in explaining religious choices and markets. However, it would be easy to include material on the impact of religion on economic choices and markets as well. The topics below could be covered and expanded.] V. Economic Impact of Religion A. Religion and economic development 1. Christianity and western economic development 2. Islam and economic development in the Middle East B. Religion and public choice 1. Models of religion and political preference 2. Public and religious charities: crowding out and crowding in 3. Markets for education C. Religion and family economics 1. Religion and family structures 2. Religion and labor force participation decisions