ENHANCING COMPLIANCE WITH ENVIRONMENTAL LAWS IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: CAN BETTER ENFORCEMENT STRATEGIES HELP? OSTROVSKAYA, ELENA1 LEENTVAAR, JAN2 1 Lecturer, UNESCO-IHE Institute for Water Education PO Box 3015, 2601 DA Delft, the Netherlands, eostrovskaya@yahoo.com 2 Professor, UNESCO-IHE Institute for Water Education PO Box 3015, 2601 DA Delft, the Netherlands, j.leentvaar@unesco-ihe.org SUMMARY Implementation of environmental policies proves to be challenging worldwide, especially in developing countries. The competition between individual and social interests produces confrontation. Thus it is important to analyze the motivations to comply and the behavior of regulated communities in differing developing countries. This paper discusses a novel approach to this analysis in relation to environmental data management, “Table of 11”, which is a tool developed for the Netherlands’ Ministry of Justice. This paper also summarizes findings of studies of the main reasons behind noncompliance of environmental regulations in developing countries. The studies show that monitoring and enforcement significantly impact environmental behavior and environmental quality in developing countries, as well as indicate that there is more than one pathway to high compliance. The paper highlights important considerations for mastering enforcement strategies in developing countries while taking into account differing countries’ contexts. This paper did not address official corruption, which requires deeper analysis and rectification before developing countries can achieve the most possible environmental compliance. 1 INTRODUCTION Though the deterioration of environmental quality is a major worldwide concern, full compliance with environmental regulations is rarely observed. As Kremlis and Dusik (2005) note, environmental protection is traditionally fighting “for the place in the sun” with the economic policies (“growth and competitiveness versus environmental conservation”). Evidence from developed countries indicates that compliance rates rarely reach 100%. For example, Russel (1990) reported the following rates of compliance with air pollution limits by industrial sources in USA: percentage of sources in violation – 65%; percentage of time the sources were in violation – 11%; excess emissions as a percentage of standards – 10%. According to Heyes (2000), the United Kingdom published compliance rates with many key water quality standards that were significantly below 100%, sometimes as low as 50%. The true compliance rates were likely to be even lower. The Netherlands government initiated a special study initiated that revealed that only 67% of industries complied with Surface Water Pollution Act (Eindrapport, 2002). As summarised in Mitchell (1996), Sparrow (2000), and INECE (2009) the main factors affecting compliance include economic, political, technological, personal, and 1 social ones. However, the most common explanation for non-compliance is insufficient monitoring and enforcement of law. A large and growing theoretical literature indicates that functional enforcement is necessary to ensure compliance (e.g., Ehrlich, 1972; Stigler, 1970; Heyes, 2000; Sparrow, 2000; Zaelke et al, 2005). This is because functional enforcement methods serve as a “deterrence”, which is defined as the act or means of changing people’s behaviour to avoid a sanction (Silberman, 2000). Enforcement deters detected violators from breaking rules again, and it deters other potential violators by sending a message that they may experience the same adverse consequences for non-compliance. Some theorists assume that effective enforcement may not require frequent or strict regulatory action. For example, Harrington’s game theoretic analysis (1988) demonstrated that compliance may be high even when the frequency and severity of enforcement actions are quite low. The empirical evidence for this inference, however, is mixed. Livernois and McKenna (1999) support this hypothesis, while Nyborg and Telle (2006) do not. Huang (1996), Rousseau and Proost (2005), and Shimchack and Ward (2005) find that inspections and sanctions are associated with improved future compliance and environmental performance. Recent empirical evidence also indicates that credible enforcement may increase beyond-compliance behaviour. Shimshack and Ward (2008) show that many plants with discharges typically below legally permitted levels reduce discharges further when regulators issue fines, even when issued on other plants. Also, non-compliant plants often respond to sanctions by reducing discharges beyond reductions required by law. Thus, increased enforcement protects the environment beyond deterring violations. Because perception is so important in creating deterrence, how a government implements enforcement actions is just as important as their existence alone. They can have significant effects far beyond bringing a single violator into compliance if they are well placed and well publicized (Heyes, 2000; Cohen, 2005; Malloy, 2003). 2 CONTRIBUTION AND RESEARCH QUESTION Although studies show that effective compliance monitoring produces desired results, the behavioral motivations and pathways underlying effective monitoring and enforcement are not well understood. Also, there is not enough empirical evidence on the impacts of monitoring and enforcement in developing countries. This paper reports the study that attempts to contribute to these two understudied areas. This paper also discusses a novel approach to environmental data management and its applicability to studies in developing countries. This framework, “Table of 11”, is approved by the Netherlands’ Ministry of Justice and used in the practice of the country’s environmental agencies, compiles a comprehensive set of environmental indicators from detailed interviews and field observations. This paper is based on application of the framework from “Table of 11” to review environmental compliance behavior and regulated entities’ attitudes towards environmental performance, monitoring, and enforcement five studied countries: Kenya, Rwanda, Nigeria, Tanzania, and China. The study’s investigation provides early evidence on environmental performance in developing countries. Further, the methodology permits an understanding of not just environmental outcomes, but the underlying motivations for those outcomes as well. 2 3 METHOD To analyze regulatory compliance with environmental laws this study uses five case studies carried out in 2007-2009 in selected developing countries. The study programmes were designed and guided by a rational choice framework, based on the Becker study (1968), and recent achievements in exploring regulatory compliance motivations discussed above in the introduction section. Therefore, the range of variables from traditional deterrence measures: risk of detection and sanction, expected benefits from violation, etc., to social and moral measures: perceiving the regulation and the enforcers’ authority as legitimate, following the regulation due to peer pressure from the fellow users and from the community, etc., was covered in the studies. The respondents were chosen randomly and included both enforcers and representatives of regulated communities in order to obtain a realistic picture of the current situation and to avoid one-sided judgment. The study used questionnaires based on “Table of 11” tests (2006), and was guided by the Table’s selection of explanatory variables. The questionnaires included close- and open-ended questions. The checklist of the “Table of 11” is composed of 11 dimensions containing variables that relate to spontaneous compliance and to enforcement (Table 1). Table 1: “Table of 11” dimensions and underlying assumptions “Table of 11” dimensions Assumptions 1) Spontaneous compliance dimension group Spontaneous compliance dimensions - factors that affect the incidence of voluntary compliance that is, compliance that would occur in the absence of enforcement T1. Knowledge and quality If legislation is written in clear and understandable language, a of rules regulated entity will likely comply with a regulation. T2. Cost-benefit If material and non-material advantages of compliance are considerations (including perceived by a regulated entity being higher than those of violation, implications for image) and material and non-material disadvantages of compliance are perceived being less, then a regulated entity will likely comply with a regulation T3. Level of acceptance If a regulated entity (generally) accepts policy, laws, and regulations, to which it should comply, it will likely be in compliance T4. Respect for official If a regulated entity respects official authority to setup and enforce and informal authorities regulation, it will likely be in compliance. But if innate willingness, habit or values of a regulated entity competes with official authority and regulation, it will likely violate the regulation T5. Informal control (peer If there is a possibility that non-compliant behaviour of a regulated pressure) entity will be detected and disapproved by third parties (i.e. nongovernment authorities), and the possibility and severity of sanctions that might be imposed by third parties (e.g. loss of customers/contractors, loss of reputation) are high, a regulated entity will likely be in compliance. 2) Enforcement dimension group Control dimensions - the influence of enforcement on compliance T6. Informal report risk If there is a possibility that an offence may come to light other than 3 during an official investigation and may be officially reported, a regulated entity will likely be in compliance. T7. Risk of inspection If there is a high likelihood of being subject to an administrative (paper) or substantive (physical) audit/inspection by official authorities, a regulated entity will likely be in compliance T8. Risk of detection If there is a high probability of an official detecting an offence during an administrative audit or substantive investigation, a regulated entity will likely be incompliance. T9. Selectivity If there is an increased chance of control and detection as a result of risk analysis and targeting of firms, persons or areas, a regulated entity will likely be in compliance. Sanctions dimensions - the influence of sanctions on compliance T10. Risk of sanction T11. Sanction severity If there is a high likelihood of a sanction being imposed if an offence has been detected through inspections and criminal investigation, a regulated entity will likely be in compliance If a sanction and adverse effects associated with imposing sanctions (including loss of respect and reputation) are adequate to cause damage and timely imposed, a regulated entity will likely be in compliance. For understanding compliance and compliance motivations, the application of “Table of 11” variables resulted in five sub-groupings of regulated entities (according to the English version of 2006): Unconscious compliers: do not know the rules very well but unknowingly comply with them; usually copy the behaviour of others. Unconscious non-compliers: break the rules because they do not know the rules well. Spontaneous compliers: know the rules and would comply with them even if theoretically the government lacked enforcement measures. Conscious violators: know they are breaking the rules and consciously accept the risk of being caught and sanctioned; and Compliers deterred by enforcement: know the rules and would break them, but choose to comply because they disfavor undergoing enforcement activities. The questionnaires included a special set of questions enabling a researcher to make the estimation (can be found at www.iT11.nl). However, this compliance estimate does not provide accurate numbers because the calculations are based on interviewees’ perceptions about portions of those sub-groups. The estimate provides a general picture of the compliance rate in a regulated community. The critical review of the instrument can be found in Elffers et al (2003), and in a number of Dutch sources (Koenders & Ruimschotel, 2002; Ruimschotel et al, 1996; Van Reenen, et al, 1996; Wietzema Menkhorst et al, 2002). Elffers et al (2003) pointed out that the “Table of 11” is a conceptual scheme that can be used for surveys, expert interviews (as it was done in our case studies), round tables, and ex ante evaluation of laws. The studies involved face-to-face interviews and direct field observations. Usually, self-reporting from the target group is used as a method for data collection in this kind of 4 research (Elffers et al, 2003; Eggert and Lokina, 2010), however this study was mainly aimed at gathering the opinions of enforcers about the regulatees’ behavior. The interviews with regulatees were used for crosscheck analysis, especially to get a more realistic picture of enforcement practices. The study relied more on expert opinion than on survey self-reporting. This research design tried to avoid bias and errors common when people were asked to assess their own violating behavior (Elffers et al, 2003). The study chose randomly regulated entities, while enforcers were selected among notable enforcing authority figures. This approach has limitations; one of the most important is the limited number of respondents. Another limitation is that the issue of corruption was mainly left out of the scope of the study, though we received some complaints about it from the interviewed regulatees. However, the study is advantageously framed to demonstrate the non-compliance from an enforcers’ perspective and to gather opinions on improving enforcement. 4 COMPLIANCE WITH ENVIRONMENTAL LAWS IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: CASE STUDIES This section describes the five case studies that used the “Table of 11”, which were conducted within the MSc programs in Environmental science at UNESCO-IHE Institute for Water Education, Delft, the Netherlands, in 2007-2009 (Table 2). Table 2: Summary of the case studies Country, area The law in question Kenya, Lake Victoria Kenya Fisheries Act (1991) prohibits the use of certain fishing gears and methods and fishing in certain areas of Lake Victoria Rwanda, Kigali region Nigeria, Ogun State Tanzania, Arusha region China, Inner Mongolia The Rwanda Environmental Organic Law (2005) in the part of wetland use regulation and control The Law for Preservation and Control of Forest, cap 39 (1992) Plant Protection Act (1997) in the part of regulation of pesticides retailing Water and Soil Conservation Law (1991) Number of respondents - 24 fishers - 15 enforcers from the central government enforcing body - 21 enforcers from Beach Management Units - 13 wetland users - 13 enforcers (regional) - 10 managers of logging industries - 10 enforcers (national and regional) - 16 managers of retailing companies - 15 enforcers (regional) - 8 managers of mining companies - 8 enforcers Specialists conducted case studies for developing countries, justifying the use of “Table of 11” this context because it provides a general picture of compliance. “Table of 11” also assesses the effectiveness of the enforcement strategies with respect to a country’s environmental legislation. Analysis software is user-friendly and manages large amounts of quantitative and qualitative data. Further, the software presents results in a more understandable and visible way that is especially important to communicate the 5 results to stakeholders and the public. “Table of 11” is proven help enforcing bodies improve their reporting and accountability if used on a regular basis. There are limitations of using “Table of 11”: its rankings were found to be quite subjective and sometimes ambiguous. As a result, an analyst handling the data needs to be well trained to interpret the data properly; otherwise one may draw incorrect inferences. Interpreting the controversial rankings also requires a sophisticated understanding of enforcement program operations and a skill for diagnosing problems. In addition, the Table’s eleven dimensions all have the same weight, while it is clear that some of them can dominate others. For instance, this study mirrored Eggert and Lokina (2010) to indicate that economic reasons often prevail over moral or normative ones. “Table of 11” application enables an analysis of the major compliance and enforcement characteristics in various countries and comparison for experiential learning. Understanding of underlying motivations of regulated entities helps environmental agencies evaluate the effectiveness of their tools and strategies to achieve compliance. Performance analysis enables agencies to better employ and allocate their resources, invest in activities that achieve results, and modify or disinvest from those areas that are not producing results. Overall, “Table of 11” can help environmental agencies increase their efficiency, effectiveness by using their limited resources in a more productive way. Table 3 illustrates the motivations to comply in the countries under study. Table 3: Motivations for compliance “Table of 11” Kenya dimensions Knowledge of law + Clarity of law + Cost/benefit of 0 compliance Cost/benefit of violation Implications for image 0 Policy acceptance + Respect for official + authority Social control Risk of reporting 0 Risk of physical 0 inspection Risk of detection 0 Selectivity of inspection Risk of sanction + Severity of sanction - Rwanda Nigeria Tanzania China + 0 0 0 0 + + - + - - - 0 0 0 0 + - + 0 0 0 + 0 + + 0 - 0 + - + 0 0 0 0 0 - + - + 0 - “- ” – a dimension has score showing that it has negative effect on compliance “0” – no influence or dimension slightly encourages compliance “+” – a dimension has score showing that it encourages compliance Although data is based on a limited number of interviewees, the study still offers valuable information. For example, in spite of differences between the countries, they 6 experience similar problems in implementation of environmental laws: the level of compliance is rather low (Figure 1), and the governmental agencies are facing serious enforcement problems. China Tanzania unconsciously compliant consciously compliant Nigeria deterred by enforcement consciously violating unconsciously violating Rwanda Kenya 0% 50% 100% Figure 1: The level of compliance with the environmental laws in countries under study Compliance levels can vary dramatically from case to case, whether it is a countryto-country comparison or an internal comparison. In all five countries studied, environmental legislation is relatively new and changing, which makes it difficult to enforce. The emphasis on economic improvement or expansion often causes environmental protection to fall to the bottom of the governmental priority list (OECD, 2000). Economic reasons often prevail over moral or normative reasons when the regulatees decide whether to comply or violate a rule. Eggert and Lokina (2010) pointed out that in Tanzanian Lake Victoria fisheries, Tanzanian fishers were poor and could not afford moral and legitimacy concerns to the same extent as the fishers in industrialized countries. Poverty’s influence yielded higher non-compliance rates compared to those of fisheries in industrialized countries. Compliance depends mostly on the governmental willingness to enforce a specific law. Enforcing agencies in developing countries are not mature enough and lack the ability and capacity to perform their activities properly. There is a lack of formalized procedures to plan and set priorities that can help enforcers to use their limited resources more productively. Some countries, like Rwanda, are just beginning to develop data systems. However, in the absence of organized efforts to collect and report data, even basic analysis of the situation is difficult to accomplish. Another important lesson is that enforcers should design their strategies to reflect that different groups of regulatees have different motivations to comply (see Table 3). Resource users consist of 1) big business, and 2) small businesses, individuals, and each group can demonstrate a variety of behavior and attitudes toward compliance with 7 environmental regulations. Our country case studies can also be divided into two groups according to major characteristics and behavior of regulatees: 1) countries with many large businesses (China, and Tanzania) and 2) countries with many individuals and smallscale businesses (Kenya, Nigeria, and Rwanda). In general, authorities’ decisions have more influence on big business, which is more sensitive to the public opinion. Big business is willing to adopt environmental management systems (e.g., ISO 14000) and to comply with international standards in order to compete on foreign markets (OECD, 2000; Yasamis, 2007; Ostrovskaya et al, 2009).). However, a majority of natural resource users in the developing countries, like Rwanda, Nigeria, Kenya, are small businesses and therefore, enforcement strategies should address the limitations of the small-scale sector while highlighting the importance of reducing environmental degradation that result from their activities. Dasgupta (2000), for instance, also indicates the limited coping abilities and lower environmental awareness of small industries in India, and demonstrates that small business is more reluctant to change, as compared to big industries. Dasgupta highlights sanction-based strategy employed in order to force small industries to change technology and/or install pollution abatement equipment and evaluated it as counterproductive and anti-poor. Civil society can play an important role in creating effective social control over industries and resource users. Experience of developed countries (Sparrow, 2000; Heyes, 2000; INECE, 2009) shows that nongovernmental groups (NGOs, neighbouring businesses, individuals, professional associations etc.) can undertake a range of various actions against violators and contribute to bringing them into compliance. They can detect and report offences, negotiate with violators, comment on government enforcement actions, and where the law allows, can take legal action against a violator for non-compliance or against the government for not enforcing the requirements. However, our case studies show that in the developing countries social control is weak due to the current low level of public awareness and concern for the damage to human health and local communities’ well-being caused by environmental noncompliance (e.g. in China, Kenya and Tanzania). Institutions of civil society may be weak in general (e.g. in Rwanda and Nigeria). Where social control and institutions are weak, the only kind of their contribution to ensuring compliance, which was identified in the cases, is reporting violations to government authorities when the latter provide necessary facilities for that (e.g., hot-lines etc.). Finally, authorities of the developing countries often encounter difficulties in the practical application of legislation. Obligations imposed on regulatees are often unrealistic or overambitious (e.g., in cases of China, Rwanda). Greenspan-Bell (2003) also pointed out, that industrialized countries prescribed overambitious policies to developing countries, however, the success of those policies were determined by local traditions, culture, institutions, and infrastructure. Therefore, local context should be taken into account when the good practices are transferred to developing countries. Greenspan-Bell offered a sound suggestion that developing countries could consider a tiered or timelined approach, that accounts for their capabilities and institutions by selecting compliance-assisting tools after first asking what is achievable and easy to monitor. 8 5 CONCLUSION This paper has outlined a number of issues that affect regulatory compliance with environmental laws in developing countries. The case studies were designed within the ‘‘rational choice’’ model and guided by the ‘‘Table of 11’’, which is an inventory of relevant variables. We are not pioneers in using this framework in the context of a developing country [see, for example, Eggert and Lokina (2010)], but believe our research can contribute to the empirical evidence on its applicability to studying regulatory compliance in developing countries. Our experience also indicates that the ‘‘Table of 11’’ scheme (for sorting out different influences within a rational choice framework) turns out to be useful both for future research and for use by enforcing bodies. For enforcers, better understanding of underlying motivations that shape behavior of a regulated community enables them to master their strategies, to more efficiently allocate their resources, to invest in activities that achieve results, and to modify or disinvest from areas that are not producing results. This better understanding consequently helps authorities to productively use their limited resources. The findings obtained from this analysis clearly show the need for deeper analysis or further investigation to understand the drivers and constraints that shape the behavior of regulated entities in developing countries. This study did not address the issue of official corruption. We are convinced that in many countries corruption compromises the position of the enforcers and severely affects the credibility of enforcement. Corruption requires deeper analysis and rectification before developing countries can achieve the most possible environmental compliance. 6 ACKNOWLEDGEMENT We appreciate the support by the Netherlands’ Inspectie Verkeer en Waterstaat and UNESCO-IHE Institute for Water Education for conducting the research. All students of UNESCO-IHE MSc programs who participated in case studies are gratefully acknowledged. 7 REFERENCES Becker, G, Crime and Punishment: an economic approach. J. of Political Economy, 1968, 76(2), pp. 169-217. Cohen, M. In: Zaelke D, Kaniaru D, Kruzhikova E (Eds.), Making Law Work: Environmental Compliance and Sustainable Development, Vol. 2, 2005, pp. 403414 Dasgupta, N., J.World Development, 2000, 28(5), pp. 945-967 Eggert, H., and Lokina, R.B., J.Environmental Development Economics, 2010, 15, pp. 197-217 Ehlich, I., J. of Legal Studies, 1972, 1, pp. 259-276 Eindrapport, Naleving en handhaving van de Wet Verontreiniging Oppervlaktewateren in 2000-2001. Ministerie van Justitie Expertisecentrum Rechtshandhaving, Den Haag, Nederlanden (in Dutch), 2000 9 Elffers, H., and Heijden van der, P., and Hezemans, M., J. of Quantitative Criminology, 2003, 19(4), pp. 409-439 Greenspan-Bell, R. In: Zaelke D, Kaniuri D, Kruzhikova E (eds), (Eds.), Making Law Work: Environmental Compliance and Sustainable Development, Vol. 2, 2005, pp 317-330 Harrington, W., J. of Public Economics, 1988, 37, pp. 29-53 Heyes, A., J. of Regulatory Economics, 2000, 17(2), pp. 107-129 Huang, C.-H., J. Environmental and Resource Economics, 1996, 8, pp. 183-204 INECE Expert Working Group on Enforcement and Compliance Indicators, Performance measurement guidance for compliance and enforcement practitioners, 2005, available at www.inece.org INECE Secretariat, Principles of Environmental Compliance and Enforcement. Handbook. INECE, 2009 Koenders, A., and Ruimschotel, D., Het gebruik van een integrale handhavingsbenadering en de T11®-methodiek in de Veiligheidsketen, Jaarboek Veiligheid 2003, augustus 2002 (in Dutch) [T11 methodology used as an integrating perspective in the safety and security chain. Yearbook Safety and Security, 2002] Kremlis, G., and Dusik, J., In: Zaelke D, Kaniauri D, Kruzhikova E (Eds.), Making Law Work: Environmental Compliance and Sustainable Development, Vol. 2, 2005, pp. 155-164 Livernois, J., and McKenna, C.J., J. of Public Economics, 1999, 71, pp. 415-440 Malloy, T.F., J.Temple Law Review, 2003, 76, pp. 451-467 Mitchell, R.B. In: Cameron, J., and Werksman, J., and Roderick, P. (Eds.), Improving Compliance with International Environmental Law, 1996 pp. 3-28 Nyborg, K., and Telle, K. J., Environmental and Resource Economics, 2006, 35, pp. 1-18 OECD report, Environmental compliance and enforcement in NIS: a survey of current practices of environmental inspectorates and options for improvements, 2000 available at www.oecd.org/dataoecd/32/51/19044683.pdf OECD Reviews of Regulatory Reform: Regulatory Policies in OECD Countries. From Interventionalism to Regulatory Governance, Chapter 5, 2002 available at 10 http://rru.worldbank.org/Documents/PapersLinks/Regulatory_Policies_in_OECD _Countries_ch5.pdf Ostrovskaya, E., and Leentvaar, J., and Makarova, E. In: Ozhan, E. (Ed.), Proceedings of the Eighth International Conference on the Mediterranean Coastal Environment, MEDCOAST-07, November 2007, Alexandria, Vol. 1, pp. 329-338 Reenen van, P., and Klaasen, B., and Ruimschotel, D., Nieuwe instrumenten voor de rationalisering en optimalisering van beleid en wetgeving: vergelijking van Ketenbenadering en Tafel van Elf. Beleidsanalyse, 1996, 4. (in Dutch) [New instruments to rationalize and optimize policy making and regulation, Policy Analysis, 1996, 4] Rousseau, S., and Proost, S., J. Environmental and Resource Economics, 2005, 32, pp. 337-365 Ruimschotel, D., and Reenen van, P., and Klaasen, B., De Tafel van Elf: een conceptueel kader en een instrument bij rechtshandhavingsvraagstukken. Beleidsanalyse, 1996, 3 (in Dutch) [the Table of Eleven: a conceptual work model and an instrument for analysing law enforcement issues, Policy Analysis, 1996] Russel, C.S. In: Portney P (Ed.) Public Policies for Environmental Protection, 1990 Shimshack, J.P., and Ward, M.B. In: Zaelke D, Kaniauri D, Kruzhikova E (Eds.), Making Law Work: Environmental Compliance and Sustainable Development, Vol. 1, pp. 429-442 Shimshack, J.P., and Ward, M.B. J. of Environmental Economics and Management, 2008, 55(1), pp. 90-105 Silberman, J.D. In: Zaelke D, Kaniuri D, Kruzhikova E (Eds.), Making Law Work: Environmental Compliance and Sustainable Development, Vol. 2, pp. 379402 Sparrow, M.K., The Regulatory Craft: Controlling Risks, Solving Problems, and Managing Compliance, 2000, 346 p. Stigler, G.J., J. of Political Economy, 1970, 70, pp. 526–536 Table of Eleven. A versatile tool, Ministry of Justice, 2006, available at www.iT11.nl Wietzema Menkhorst, H., and Ruimschotel, D. De T11®-methodiek in de financiële sector, Jaarboek Fraudebestrijding, Kluwer, maart 2002 (in Dutch) [T11®-methodology in the financial business sector, Yearbook Fraud Prevention, 11 2002] Yasamis, F.D., J. Environmental management, 2007, 39(4), pp. 575-586 Zaelke, D., and Stitwell, M., and Young, O. In: Zaelke D, Kaniaru D, Kruzhikova E (Eds.), Making Law Work: Environmental Compliance and Sustainable Development, Vol. 1, pp. 29-52 12