ABI Commission to Study the Reform of Chapter 11 June 7, 2013 Field Hearing Association of Insolvency & Restructuring Advisors Chicago, IL Robert Keach: Al and I have a rather lengthy prepared statement that we'll dispense with. It will be posted as part of the record of this meeting, and if anybody would like a copy of it, I'm happy to send it to them. Let me give the very abbreviated version. [*] We are going to hear from witnesses today on a number of topics. First, members of the leadership of the AIRA will address issues of concern to the organization, and report on a survey of their membership on things they like about chapter 11 and areas that are ripe for reform as far as their membership is concerned. Second, we will take testimony regarding the control and governance of chapter 11 cases, in particular the problem of identifying who is in control of, or attempting to control, the case in light of lack of transparency and regulation of the claims trading markets. That same witness will also address the issue of mandatory examiners in chapter 11 cases of a certain size and the possible need for reform of those provisions. Then we will hear from a witness with respect to the continuing problem of addressing retiree benefits issues in Chapter 11, including whether or not section 1114 or like solutions are effective, or even appropriate remedies, and what the alternatives might be, as well as the consequences of such alternatives. To put those topics in a bit of context let me frame today's hearing. As we have said in other venues and in other articles, trading and claims and distressed debt has changed the landscape within which chapter 11 functions. The acquisition of claims can be purely financial, or arbitrage play; the claim's purchaser simply wants to make money on the spread between the purchase price of the claim and the value of the distribution made on the claim under a plan or otherwise. Claims acquisition can also be a takeover mechanism, with the acquirer seeking to acquire control of the process and, eventually, the reorganized debtor or its assets. However, determining what entities are seeking to acquire such control, or have already acquired the means to do so, can be difficult. Knowledge of these entities and these factors may be critical to the fair and efficient administration of the chapter 11 process in a way that protects the interests of all stakeholders. While changes to Rule 2019, that we all know about, increased transparency relating to ad hoc groups, the improved rule does not completely address these concerns. * Language clarified in transcription process. 1 Section 1104(c)(2), the so-called mandatory provision for the appointment of an examiner in cases of a particular size has become controversial. Likely the product of a political compromise at the time of the Code’s passage, given the diminished role of the SEC under the new chapter 11, the provision is seldom utilized. Moreover, despite its apparent plain meaning, some courts have found the appointment of an examiner under that section not to be mandatory upon request, even when the dollar threshold is met. Still others have acquiesced in appointing the mandatory examiner only to handcuff the newly-appointed examiner with a small budget, a lack of professionals, or unrealistic time limits. The continuing efficacy, not to mention necessity, of the provision is questioned by many, while others decry the fact that courts seem to be ignoring or endrunning the statute and failing to utilize a valuable tool for necessary fact-finding in chapter 11 cases. Finally, section 1114, introduced to provide the same protection to retiree health benefits that section 1113 was intended to provide to rights under collective bargaining agreements, may or may not have accomplished that limited goal, depending on one’s view as to what protection was appropriate. Critics, particularly those on the labor side, often contend that neither provision succeeds in providing sufficient protection, and that even the intended protection, whatever that was, is too easily avoided by resort to all asset sales under section 363. The original dilemma may remain: how to reasonably protect retiree medical benefits whenever possible for a particularly vulnerable population without dooming restructuring by imposing the sometimes massive cost of doing so. The corollary question of “who pays such costs” follows inexorably, leading to questions of competing priorities, both in the technical bankruptcy sense and otherwise. With that, by way of introduction, we turn to our first panel, and we welcome the leadership of the AIRA and, gentlemen, we'll turn it over to you. Our general approach is to let you do your prepared remarks, and we have had the benefit of having your paper last night, and then we'll open it up for questions by the Commissioners. With that, Grant, take it away. Grant Newton: Thank you very much. First of all, on behalf of the AIRA we want to thank ABI for giving us the opportunity to make this presentation, we are delighted that you joined us here as a part of our Annual Conference. The process that we are going to go through is, we did a survey among the Board Members asking them to fill out a survey [on] the good and the bad aspects of chapter 11 and the areas where they recommended change. We summarized the results and then we, at a Board Meeting this week reviewed these again, and made some changes to them, and we circulated of a draft of the document. * Language clarified in transcription process. 2 I think there are several issues that are good; there are some that are bad. Obviously we believe in chapter 11. My first question is how much time do we have? I noticed you have quite a busy agenda there, so home much time do we have? Keach: We do. We are going to go until five o'clock, so I would suggest that if, between the two of you, you can 10 or 15 minutes and then we'll have some questions, and then we'll move on. Does that work? Newton: That will work, yeah. We are going to skip the issues related to the good aspects and the bad aspects then, and move down to some recommendations. Okay? Keach: Thank you. I will add, just so you know, the paper will become part of the record as we'll be posted. [*] Grant Stein: I'm Grant Stein, with Alston & Bird in Atlanta. I wear two hats in the AIRA. I'm a Former President and Chair, and I'm also licensed practicing attorney at Alston & Bird, but my area of interest for years and years has been the financial area and my comments are made less with a lawyer hat and more with an AIRA hat on. The first change that the AIRA wanted to focus on was the change relating to the lease assumption periods and giving the court more time in appropriate circumstances, not on an automatic basis, to modify that [period] to make real estate cases run more smoothly, particularly in the area of retailers. I'm sure you’ve heard of that before, but that’s an area that the folks that we work with sees creating problems. The second area that we wanted to focus on and it's not necessarily a legal provision, but it's the way time is recorded and the way professionals, particularly in the financial area, other than investment bankers, have to record their time, instead of doing it in tenths, to get that modified to be in 15 or 30-minute increments, which is more in keeping with what, usually the financial professional does in the way they keep up with their time. Newton: I'll make one comment, that we realize that’s not a provision that’s currently in the Bankruptcy Code, but it's a practice that’s used by the U.S. Trustee's office, and we are not sure whether that’s an issue that you would want to address or something that should be take up with the Trustee, but it is a observation that we made and a recommendation that we would make. Stein: The third area that we focused on, [*] is that the detailed, overly detailed and very un-useful for that reason, nature of disclosure statements in large cases that don’t cut to the chase, [They] don’t explain economically what's happening in a way that is less technical and more common sense, [they are] more focused than our prospectus in SEC requirements and less on what do you need to know if you're going to be voting as a holder of a claim in a given class. Less is better, more is * Language clarified in transcription process. 3 not better, and that the excruciating detail that goes into these is not productive, it's not helpful to those that read in many instances, and those that are more sophisticated don’t need all that information in disclosure statement anyway, and that’s an area that the folks that the AIRA wanted us to focus on. Newton: I think one of the examples that was shared with us, dealing with this issue, and I actually had an opportunity to see this plan as well was where the draft of the plan is clearly laid in a term sheet showing exactly what each of the constituents was going to get, it showed the percent of the value they would be receiving of the reorganized entity. When the document came out they was sent with the plan for the voting, that schedule was not there and everything was expressed in terms of $1,000 of claim and no values were given. In order to get to the essence of what you really were going to get, you had to through and figure out what they thought the value was and then back into it and determine what dollar amount they were going to get. [*] We've seen several of these. I'm not sure if it was written to make it as confusing as you could to figure out what it was.[*] It felt like that was needed from a legal perspective was to get to the point as to what the consideration would be. I think, as Grant mentioned, simple language would have served the readers of the disclosure statement much better in that case. Stein: The next area that we focused on was the provision in section 1111, that basically says: if your schedule is undisputed, non-contention and liquidated, then you don’t have to file a proof of claim, that provision doesn’t apply in Chapter 7.The thought was that that provision should be modified to apply to Chapter 7, that will make those types of cases and liquidations easier to deal with and administer. The next area that we focused on was the section 503(b)(9) administrative expense claim for goods delivered in the 20 days preceding the bankruptcy filing and the view there was that the allowance of that claim, the funding of that the claim, [and] the question of when that claim has to be paid. The whole concept has created a situation in chapter 11 that makes dealing with those folks and dealing with that funding obligation in changing the relative amounts necessary to be able to exit bankruptcy, such that it's reflective of the efforts of a particular interest group to try and codify or modify the statute and it takes away from what was the original structure which was a more balanced statute. It's not to say that the law shouldn’t involve it, but that at least our constituency looks at that particular provision in the law as an evolution in the law that was not constructive [*]. You all may have questions I know some of you have lived through the disparate treatment among circuits of critical vendor payments, but we don’t see that as a substitute for judicial determination and the judgment of the debtor in an appropriate case where it's necessary to benefit the debtor if allowed in that circuit. * Language clarified in transcription process. 4 The last area that we wanted to focus on is KERPs. We know the statute was changed to get rid of KERPs and we know that folks have tried to figure out ways to deal with that under various incentive plans, but [it’s important] at the end of the day being able to keep appropriately qualified management in place, motivated to carry through in the rigors of what happens in a chapter 11 case, be it one that reorganizes or one that sells where there's a sale as a going concern. However it is, the statute should get scaled back to again, give the bankruptcy judge more authority, more leeway to, in an appropriate case, to recognize the benefit of and allow, KERPs. That’s something that our Board, based on what they heard from our constituency, thinks is something that should get scaled back from the amendments that have occurred in the last few years. Newton: I think that some of the comments came from our members related to the fact that while we spent considerable amount of effort in terms of top management, [*] of being sure that we have independent management, when you apply that rule to lower-level employees you have to develop an incentive plan to retain some of those individuals, [and] it becomes very difficult and a process that takes considerable time. Probably it would be much better if the lower level managers and executives at certain divisions of the company, were not required to go through this process of developing some form of incentive method to retaining those executives once they're in chapter 11. This was a concept that at least a half-a-dozen of our members made comments about, and issues that they felt had made it more difficult for them to go in and take over and run a company in chapter 11 and [*] the need to retain a lot of the middle management type people that were necessary for operations yet, there were some restrictions placed on them in terms of their ability to continue. Stein: My final comment, with respect to the materials that we submitted, [and] if you go through the written materials, there's so much good about chapter 11 and the rehabilitative nature of what you do. You all see it in your practice or in your courts, as the case may be, the cases and what they accomplish in the environment that we have. We are a model for the rest of the world in that regard, as you know. [*] That’s what the AIRA is, it's primarily on the financial side, it's business folks looking at the business aspects of what we do and what you're trying to accomplish in chapter 11, including from a policy standpoint even though we have absolute priority and other rules that apply that are purely economic focused. Having said that, there's also in the materials comments that were received that are not the official AIRA positions, but that we thought were worth passing along to the group to reflect some concerns of the various members of the organization but that didn’t necessarily carry a consensus behind them. With that, thank you for your time. [*] Newton: I do have one comment I would like to make, that I know we are going through the process of looking at chapter 11, [and] I think this is very important and I * Language clarified in transcription process. 5 think it's important for some changes to be made to the Chapter 11 process, but I think that we need to realize that chapter 11 as it has been developed and it has grown and developed over time has a lot to offer to businesses, and I know there are other aspects of the world that would like to have the opportunity to use something like we have in chapter 11. I recently had an opportunity to address the Insolvency Practitioners Association of Australia, and at the time I was there they were in the process of looking at, attempting to adopt some form of our chapter 11 process. I spent three days there and at the end of the third day I was told that they had decided not to push legislation this year to move toward chapter 11, but that it would be back in a couple of years. Again, trying to get their law changed to be more in line with some of the provisions we had in chapter 11 and I described some of these good and bad aspects of chapter 11 that we've put in this paper with them, and had a opportunity to spend quite a bit of time with him, talking about chapter 11. I learned what a scheme was, okay, so a scheme is nothing more than [*] basically a chapter 11 without calling it a chapter 11, where they put together a plan, ideas, and actually put it in effect, and we had a case study, when they finished it, my comment was, "This looks like a chapter 11 to me." They say, “No, it's a scheme.” I said, “It's a scheme,” so that was the end of that session. Do you have any questions? Keach: I'm sure we do. Thank you for your prepared remarks and for the paper, we appreciate that, and let me just open it up to the Commissioners for questions. Jack, you had a question. John Butler: Thank you very much for your testimony. Much of your recommendations, on the face at least, go to the issue of how much discretion a bankruptcy judge ought to have. I mean, the issues relating to professional compensation, issues relating to the executive non-residential property contracts. Will it go to issue of discretion? The Commission in one of our other field hearings, earlier this week actually in New York, had compelling testimony from landlord representatives who said, "Look, unfettered discretion has led, historically, to results that are just unfair to landlords who are compelled by their nature to be one of the few and voluntary lenders in a post petition environment.” I guess what I'd like to ask you to reflect on for us is the discretionary elements of this, both as it relates to your recommendation on leases, and also to your recommendation [*] on management compensation. We understand that the limitations that you speak are mostly related to insiders but again, I think you're relating to [*] how discretion is exercised on behalf of the judge, or by the judiciary. I think judges would like to have more discretion and believe that they're capable of exercising it appropriately, but I think we all recognize that some of the changes you complain about have occurred over the last number of * Language clarified in transcription process. 6 years have been where stakeholders have been dissatisfied with how that discretion has been exercised. [*] Stein: Three points. Just so that you know, there's only three even though it may sound like more, the first is: landlords as involuntary lenders, landlords under the statute from the time it was enacted get paid for their post-petition occupancy and use of their premises. That’s not an involuntary lender. [An] involuntary lender is someone that is required, for example, to give trade credit to a debtor, that’s an involuntary lender. Or of course a real lender that could be and they're not under the stature required to loan. From the perspective of a landlord, it depends on how you look at it. If you're getting paid for the use of your property, which is what you're entitled to, and that benefits the reorganization process, why do we have the structure and statute that we have of adequate protection? I don’t see that and I don’t think that our group sees that just because that one constituency has the issue they have, if that makes them and involuntary lender, or unfairly treated any different than any secured lender; again, that receives adequate protection and has their property used. That’s been in the statute for a long time. The preferential treatment, if you will, where there's no cram down on a lease, is an extraordinary protection for the lessor if that lease is assumed. The second point, and the third point, which are probably more important, go to the issue of judicial discretion, [*] and I'm not going to tell you that I was practicing back when this happened, but we all are students of how things have developed, my understanding is that back when the 1978 law came together, that there was a major dispute that had to get resolved, were bankruptcy judges going to be administrators, or were bankruptcy judges going to judges? I mean, they became judges by rule in 1973 and so the question was, how was that going to change? Which way was it going to go? There was a strong leaning toward having them be bankruptcy administrators as opposed to judges, and ultimately, through the efforts of the National Conference of Bankruptcy Judges, Judge Joe Lee, Judge Drake, a compromise was reached. As I understand what happened back in the late 1970s leading to the 1978 Reform Act that had the judges designated to be judges, they couldn’t get Article III status, so they got Article I status, but the standard of having a judge that makes decisions, that may not make everybody happy, but that are structured and based and allowed to facilitate the reorganization process to resolve disputes. [*] I don’t mean to sound like I'm on a soap box, Jack, but the idea is that you try to build consensus, there's nobody better at that than you, and with regard to consensus, if you can't get there someone has got to make the decision and having the judge being able to make that decision with the policy issues involved as that judge perceives it, that’s supposed to be statutory that’s supposed to be a judge. If * Language clarified in transcription process. 7 it's going to be a judge let them be a judge, let them make that judgment based on the record and based on the evidence that’s presented to them in individual cases. Is that going to mean you'll have lack of uniformity, it's going to mean that different cases get different results based on different facts? That brings me to the last point with respect to management compensation. That’s what the judge is there for, in our view, and why there should be reasonable amount of power in that judge to make decisions, because they're not bankruptcy administrators, and haven’t been, and that determination was made a long time ago. It doesn’t mean they have to be Article III Judges to be able to make those determinations in the context of their authority as an Article I Judge dealing with bankruptcy. I said I wasn’t going to be a lawyer, sitting here. Keach: Following on that KERP point because I wrote an article a long time ago, called “The Case Against KERPs” which focused on what I call top-heavy KERPs; Senior Executive KERPs. I guess one of the things that I would want to ask you about is, if we were to think about reinstating KERPs in some shape or form, to whom should they apply? Grant, you talked a little bit about [*] upper middle management, and they have to be insiders, so we'd have to be pretty far up in middle management I guess. More importantly, if we are talking about an issue of discretion, what would the standard be? Because as we all know from recent cases from a labor standpoint, and I won't pretend to be a spokesperson for labor, one of the reasons that there is linkage in the current statute between the treatment of employees in general, and whether or not you can have KERPs and whether or not you can have KEIPs, is that from labor's standpoint it's a sensitive issue, obviously, for KERPs to be handed out to senior management at a time when rank and file compensation and benefits are being suspended, frozen, slashed, rejected. William Brandt: Or pension plans being discontinued. Keach: Right. What would the standard be? Could, for example, the judge take into account whether or not the rewarding of KERP would create labor unrest? Could it take into account what set of factors in deciding to exercise that discretion, because if we are going to get back to discretionary KERPs, I doubt judges just want a blank slate, I'm assuming they would want a standard, and what would that standard be if we were to do that? Newton: The first comment I will make is that AIRA has a position on this issue that we drafted sometime ago and submitted to Congress when they debated the issue and [*] I will send you a copy that you can attach to the record. I think that in that statement that we stated that KERPs have been misused, at that point in time there's no question about that, but at the same time we felt like the restrictions that were placed with the proposed legislation, was just basically what became the * Language clarified in transcription process. 8 actual legislation, was too burdensome on companies and was not a good way to go. Keach: In the area of KERPs, [*] it’s virtually impossible to qualify a KERP, right? Newton: That’s right, that’s correct. Therefore, I guess if you’ve got something that you qualify for, should we make changes in it? [*] I'm not saying we should do away with it, that’s not our point at all. I will send you a copy of that, and I think that will be better to explain it. [*] Keach: Well, we would appreciate that and we'll add that to the record. Thank you. Newton: Okay. I think that as Grant pointed out, I think that the entire process involves certain decisions that have to be made, and it's impossible to set guidelines for each of these decisions along the way so the judge can look at a code and say, “hey, this is what you do here, this is what you do there.” Certain items involve judgment. It's a critical issue to decide which do and which do not, and that’s one of the jobs that you'll have in making your recommendation, is which way to go with certain items. On this issue, we felt that moving back to a system that we had previously although there certainly could be some modifications to it that d[o] away [with] the abuses, and establish some type of standards in it, that it might make it helpful to the judges to have some issue to look at to decide which way to go with it based on some principle laid out. Certainly we would need a principle laid out in it, and I have not spent any time trying to identify how that might be worded, but I think that would be one point that you might want to do in this process. Keach: Okay. Thank you. Before I dominate this, let me ask if anybody else had any questions. Bill? Brandt: Professor Newton, following up on that, having worked with, now Senator Warren, to write the KERP language at the last minute in the Senate Judiciary room one night, one of the issues that came [up] when we wrote the language was that in an era when you have, as Judge Carey pointed out at a panel yesterday, primarily 363 sales, the era of two and three-year reorganizations long being over and that might be the norm for the future, is the issue of the basis of the rational of KERPs. Why not let the buyer pay the KERP? I mean, if you were going to do a 363 sale, why make the creditors bear the cost of this, especially when, as I used to tell Professor Warren, I'm old enough to remember when we paid people to go away, rather than to stay. That’s probably dating me back in that Act, but that was the case. Why not allow the purchasers, or the bidders to put those packages together because [*] if they choose to keep the management team together, it is to their benefit rather than the * Language clarified in transcription process. 9 creditors. That’s just, you know, that’s my thought on that, but would that be something that you'd allow to have along with bid protection and the rest of it? Newton: Well, I understand the point you're making and I guess my response to that is two points. Number one is that if this is laid out as a sale of the business then certainly the question is: do you need someone to operate the business while the sale is taking place? If so, do you want that to be put on a potential buyer before the deal has been put together, or do you want to let the business continue to deteriorate while the party’s bid is on process and [the process] takes six days at most to go through it. I think some judgment has to be used to decide, what steps do we need to be taking in the process. The second point I would make is that this is not uncommon in a non-bankruptcy situation, or in any business acquisition for some peoples to be paid a fee to keep this business running until the deal is put together. [*] Brandt: I don’t have a debate with that I guess I'm trying to remember the last time I saw a six to eight-month 363 sale. I get the melting ice-cube line all the time from the lenders, with drop-dead dates in the debt financing and if it's going to be as quickly as it suggested, is it not something that, perhaps if you found the case that was going to last six or eight months, or had some time threshold, and you could revisit KERPs after that, that might be something that I could think about? Would that make some sense to you? Stein: The question, or at least my view on the question is: what is the best way when what's involved is preserving growing concern value. If it's a three-month liquidation, and I've done three-month liquidations and I've had KERPs approved back when they were allowed, if in fact [KERPs are] appropriate to do, to maintain the value that going concern, and enhance the likelihood of its being sold, and enhance the likelihood of it being sold to a buyer that’s going to maximize the number of employees and its viability as a business going forward, which happens. Not all businesses are bad. Sometimes they’ve got to get rid of leases if it's retail. Sometimes they’ve got to shrink a variety of other things, change their balance sheet, [but] the core business may be good. So the ultimate question is, how much lead time is there coming in, is this going help preserve going concerned value and is it consistent with [*] [the unwritten] policy of rehabilitation and revitalization of a business when it comes out of bankruptcy, which can be through a confirmed plan or through a sale? That’s what I come back to, [it] depends what the case is, [it] depends what the facts are, [and] it's not supposed to be a rubber stamp, [*] that’s what the judge is there for, judges don’t rubber stamp, someone has got to make a record to support the determination by that court at that time. [*] * Language clarified in transcription process. 10 Brandt: One last question, which gets Mr. Butler involved. I kind of like the American Airlines problem here. I mean if you're going to do a bonus system, you put it in where the plan is confirmed, so the creditors are essentially voting on this since it's their money. Perhaps maybe that’s the way to approach this, if you have a confirmation process and internal reorganization versus a fast sale. Stein: Well, it's an apple and orange, and again he's done a wonderful job there. What you could do before the statute changed in the way that it has to be done now, we are talking about different things. Keach: Speaking of Mr. Butler, hold your question for a second. Did you have a question, Steve? [*] John Butler: Commissioners aren't supposed to debate yet, but Mr. Brandt did say something, and I'll just point out that some of us believe that if the buyers pay for it, the creditors are still paying for it, because it's a zero-sum gain. Keach: It might be a pricing consideration. Butler: Right, it might be a pricing consideration. Brandt: Plus optics are important. Butler: I'm not talking about the political optics, and I don’t mean to underestimate, those may be critical actually, but it does from a value perspective I think, I'm not sure what the difference is. [*] Again, on this judicial discretion issue, and on management comp, I'm thing to find a solution. Talk about your views if you have any on whether insider definition is too imprecise here. It's been suggested that maybe what we should do is say look, KERPs and KEIPs are ordinary course except they are not ordinary course for anyone in the C-suite: CEO, CFO, COO, CAOs, and anyone who directly reports to them. That group of people ought to get judicial scrutiny, but that otherwise the debtor in possession ought to be able to run its business in the ordinary course subject to Committee review and anyone else's. Keach: Which was actually the point of the paper I wrote years ago. Butler: I asked whether you have a point of view on that because if we segregated out the C-suite and their direct reports and that had some level of judicial and committee other stakeholder scrutiny and everyone else was dealt with in the ordinary of business, do you have a view as to whether that makes sense or doesn’t make sense? Stein: I have a view but it's not an AIRA view because we didn’t focus on that. Butler: Okay, I'd love to hear your view then. * Language clarified in transcription process. 11 Keach: We'll acknowledge the disclaimer. [*] Stein: That makes a lot of logical sense in that it's often the way I've seen it play out, the way you're describing where the structure in the play retention issues are not at the top but it's at the lower levels. So that makes a lot of sense to me. Keach: Steve, you had a question and then … we are about five minutes, and in fairness to the other witnesses move on. Go ahead. Steven Hedberg: I'm just curious, on your [section] 503(b)(9) comments and your paper. We had a chat with the NACM at a hearing a few weeks ago and you probably wouldn’t be surprised to learn that they really, really like [section] 503(b)(9), and in fact that they think it's too narrowly drawn, they should get the drop-ship goods, and all kinds of other things. I'm curious on your thoughts on revising it. [*] Where is the right balance between where their view is, that they continue to extend credit to would-be debtors and companies that are in trouble because they know they can fall back on this provision. They of course like to get paid early on in the case if they can, and as a corollary to the arguments toward a lot of judicial discretion in the other parts of the conversations, it sounds like to me you're proposing to take that away here. So I'm just curious to try to get a clearer sense of what kind of amendments you would propose or changes to the [section] 503(b)(9) process that would reach an appropriate balance of the trade creditors, the DIP lenders, the debtor in reorganization, that entire constituency across the board. Newton: I'll make one little comment then let me turn it over to Grant. My first comment would be that the payment of administrative expenses, related to the [section] 503(b)(9) should be no different than the rules regarding the administrative expenses. We have special rules for those administrative expenses that are different from what other administrative expenses are in the process, so I'm not sure there's justification for that difference. Keach: You mean it would have to be a post-petition event, right? This is the only circumstance in which we've created a pre-petition event to give rise to the administrator? Newton: No, no, no. The issue with the payment is the timing, other administrative expenses that may be classified as administrative expenses do not have to be paid in the short time period you have with the [section] 503(b)(9). Keach: So you're not quibbling with the creation of the expense, but the manner in which it's satisfied? Newton: No. I'm just pointing out the second part of it. [*] I agree with AIRA's position that I think this has been detrimental to some restructurings in some situations, * Language clarified in transcription process. 12 and we have some examples that we've discussed among our members. I do not agree that we should necessarily retain that part of it either. Keach: Okay. Geoffrey Berman: Again, I think the concern in the field hearing that Mr. Hedberg referred to, was a few weeks ago, and that it was the trade's opportunity to tell us how they feel. They are at the backend of this process and they feel that they are the class of creditor that has been taken from the most. If you take away the [section] 503(b)(9) concept, where reclamation doesn’t work, the larger extenders of unsecured credit are going to just stop. They see a company get ready to go into bankruptcy they just won't ship. They rely on the [section] 503(b)(9) claim. Where is the line that says we are not going to keep taking from the unsecured creditors? Newton: First of all, the question is: under what conditions do we need to consider unsecured creditors different than any other creditor in the case? That distinction you're making, is when that change was made in the covenant. That’s one issue that has to be addressed. To the extent that they're entitled to different treatment than an employee is, or others that make a commitment and then they end up filing bankruptcy. This is a special rule designed for suppliers. [*] The second point I make is, in some situations there may have been a chance for this company to have restructured, but for the administrative expenses that had to be paid [and] because [of section] 503(b)(9), they were not able to restructure. In that case, what did the creditors get for that? Obviously they're getting almost nothing. If the company had been able to provide a foundation for restructuring they would have gotten more; so it's not totally one way or the other, I think there's some balance between that in terms of the benefit. Berman: Where is Chapter 11 debtor is going to get the inventory to sell if they can't get it from wholesale credit? This is a tension that I haven’t heard how it gets addressed. Stein: Where did it get it before the law was changed a few years ago? It worked, it happened. Brandt: I think what Geoff is saying is recognizing that the commercial markets have changed since the Code was enacted, and you now see all of these cases or most of these cases winding up, in the bankruptcy court on a highly over-leveraged basis, where there's virtually nothing for most of unsecured creditors in an overwhelming majority of the time. How do you get vendors on the eve of insolvency when the discussion is plain that the company is having problems to continue to ship in, when they think they're just transferring value to the secured lender at that point? That is what some of us saw [section] 503(b)(9) as the counterweight to. * Language clarified in transcription process. 13 It may be slightly excessive, but we are wrestling with the problem. Some of the Commissioners here have talked about a surcharge. If the lenders want to use the bankruptcy court then they have to leave an automatic carve out of a percentage of the value for unsecured. That may be one of the ways to address it. We are struggling with that up here. Keach: Also I mean, just a quick response to: how did it work before and I’ll weave this into the question. Remember [a] reclamation [claim] was at one point in time a meaningful remedy. [A] Reclamation [claim] actually worked as a remedy when there were not second and third liens on the assets. [A] reclamation [claim] doesn’t work as a remedy when the ABL loan fully encompasses all of the inventory and is under water. The reason it used to work was that the basic capital structure of debtors was different. We've talked a lot about that externality driving a lot of what we are trying to investigate now. I mean [section] 503(b)(9) became a surrogate for a meaningful reclamation [claim] process, and I guess that’s where the tension is. Brandt: … and to provide some assurance that there was no wealth transfer in the last month to the secured lender from the unsecured who felt like they'd already given at the office, and didn’t need to give more. Keach: We've only got about a minute at most, and I'll ask you a quick question which maybe has a quick answer. I was fascinated by the recommendation about disclosure statements because the Code currently has a provision that literally allows a different disclosure statement to be drafted and used for each class of claims, and in fact I've used that in cases where there was a heavy consumer constituency to [use a] one-page disclosure statement for that class. That provision of course is not mandatory now, so there's no requirement that the disclosure statement actually be tailored on a per-class basis, so that classes get a more simplified disclosure statement when that would do. I guess my question is, would you be in favor of that kind of a provision, or at a minimum to implement your suggestion of a more detailed requirement, that the kind of summary you’ve talked about be included? I mean, I know I spent a lot of time reading American Airline's disclosure statement and I do know they had such a chart, and it was actually pretty useful and that’s in an all-equity plan, so they were actually translating what the values were going to be under certain scenarios which, I think was very useful to the constituency in that case. Would those kinds of simple fixes address the problem you're talking about? Newton: It would help the process, I believe. I think somehow we need to change the wording that’s used in the disclosure statements to get a lot of the layering out of it, to get more practical information in it, and business information so it can be understood [*]. * Language clarified in transcription process. 14 I think it's unnecessary to put some of the detailed information that’s in it, like the one I just referred to [*]. The meaning of a disclosure statement is to be such that it can be understandable by the creditors, and I don’t think we have accomplished that, and I'm not blaming attorneys [*] obviously other financial advisors have been guilty of this in many cases as well, so I'm not trying to pick on any one part, but just as a general observation. The Code did make it clear that that creditor should be able to understand, that’s part of the wording in the Bankruptcy Code in terms of what the disclosure statement should accomplish. That was our observation about it. [*] [*] Newton: One side, one sheet, I've been suggesting for years in terms [that for] a certain classes of unsecured creditors that might be the best way to go with, they might have a better understanding of what's taking place in the process if we did that. Keach: We thank you. We've got to move on to our other witnesses, but we thank you very much. We would appreciate receiving the language you talked about that the Congressional Submission [on KERPs] and any other written follow up you would like would be fine. Newton: I want to thank you very much for giving us this opportunity and we are delighted you came to be here while we are having our conference. Keach: We appreciate your hosting us. Thank you. Stein: Thank you. Keach: Our next witness is Professor Daniel L. Keating, from the Washington University School of Law in St. Louis. Professor Keating is going to talk to us, among other things, about Section 1114, I should say. [*] Dan Keating: First, I want to thank all of you for inviting me and for spending your time on this project, which I think is a great and worthwhile project. I was unable to attend the labor-specific hearing in D.C., but I did read the transcript from that hearing. The testimony that I'll be giving today is more general than most of what was said in March by those witnesses, many of whom I saw had very direct involvement in specific bankruptcy cases involving labor issues. It's been 25 years since I last practiced bankruptcy law and it was here in Chicago, at the First National Bank of Chicago, so my testimony today is going to be more from the 30,000-foot view of an academic, but I hope that it will add a possibly useful perspective to the overall mix of testimony. * Language clarified in transcription process. 15 I don’t represent anyone or any group today, so these views are strictly my own, but I did want to mention by way of full disclosure, that I grew up in a union household with both of my parents serving as members of the Chicago Teacher’s Union. They are both retired now and in their late 70s, and they are waiting anxiously to see when and how the State of Illinois will reduce their retiree medical benefits; so I certainly have some direct connection with people who are experiencing the kind of emotions that the union worker and retirees experience in chapter 11 bankruptcy cases where they feel like they’ve kept their end of the bargain, and why can't their employer keep their promises as well. With that, sympathy for the injustice that’s occurring does not necessarily then translate into my agreeing with all the solutions that are being proposed by organized labor to try to remedy these injustices. Instead, what I'm going to do is offer five big-picture lessons that I think we've learned since the last round of Congressional action on labor employment retiree issues back in the mid-[19]80s. I'm just going to run these quickly because I know you’ve all read the written testimony, and then I'll try to answer any questions you have. First, you cannot effectively fix a non-bankruptcy problem with a bankruptcy specific solution, and here I would like to compare under-funded defined pension plans with under-funded retiree medical benefits. I think both of these are nonbankruptcy problems that are a form of financial deferred maintenance. One of them got a non-bankruptcy solution, and that was ERISA and the other got Bankruptcy Code section 1114. Now why is that? Why did one get the non-bankruptcy solution and one got the bankruptcy specific solution, because I think the underlying problems are essentially the same. Is it simply the happenstance that the Studebaker Company failed and walked away from its defined benefit pension obligations without even filing for bankruptcy but LTV Corporation filed chapter 11 as their way to avoid the retiree medical benefit obligations? Section 1114, I think, was better than nothing from the perspective of the retirees, but it failed to solve the fundamental problem of the failure to pre-fund these kinds of promises. The second lesson, I think, we've learned in the last 25 or 30 years is that when you create large priorities that apply in a certain type of reorganization process, then employers will simply seek to avoid that process and I think this helps explain at least part of the reason [*] why companies with large retiree medical benefit liabilities will often try to reorganize with the section 363 sale rather than a traditional chapter 11 reorganization plan process. Third, if you make a particular type of employee benefit more expensive for an employer, then fewer employer will give that benefit. [*] I think we see how two of the employee benefits have been subject of so much of the high profile litigation these days. I'm talking here about defined benefit pension plans and * Language clarified in transcription process. 16 what I think of as the open-ended retiree medical benefit plans. Those will soon be a thing of the past and in their place virtually all workers, including even government workers, I think, ultimately, will have some form of 401(k) for pensions and then some sort of retiree medical account rather than an open-ended promise by the employer to pay retiree medical benefits for life. The fourth lesson is that a piecemeal liquidation can destroy even the most powerful priority that Congress might create. Employers can always walk away and do a piecemeal liquidation if they believe that a reorganization that requires having to honor all legacy obligations is simply not financially viable. One recent example that comes to mind is the Hostess Brands Case, where the buyer of the assets and liquidation is now planning to reopen those plants and to hire about 1,500 workers but not at the wage rates of the prior collective bargaining agreement. Then the final lesson we've learned is that a lender's willingness to lend can be affected by the creation of new priorities. Even if we were to create a Fair Labor Standards Act “hot goods” provision to protect labor claims beyond the minimum wage in overtime claims that are not protected by that super-priority, then any company that had a lot of those kinds of claims would have a really difficult time in the credit and capital markets. In conclusion I worry that the creation of more bankruptcy specific priorities for labor claims will end up hindering the overall effectiveness of bankruptcy as a corporate reorganization tool, and at the same time, I don’t believe that approaching these problems through the Bankruptcy Code will cure the true underlying disease which is the ability of employers to make long-term promises to workers and retirees without having to provide adequate pre-funding of such promises. That’s all I have to say with my oral remarks, and I welcome your questions. Keach: [*] Let me just ask a sort of basic point and this goes to something we were talking about before went live, and that is that retirees strikes me as sort of the ultimate involuntary creditor. They are, generally speaking, not at the company when the decisions are made to put the company in the position that it's in where it can't honor its retiree medical benefits. Does that fact alone make a difference, and there are others, obviously, involuntary creditors who have higher and lower social priorities, but does that make a difference in terms of how we should prioritize their claims? How we should secure them? I appreciate your point that this is not a bankruptcy problem, but the non-bankruptcy solution to this problem will probably have to be a different Commission. With respect to what we are doing, does that fact suggest that we should in fact treat retiree medical claims differently, than we treat other claims? * Language clarified in transcription process. 17 In other words, should we take into account those kinds of factors and voluntariness, social priority, et cetera when we are resetting these priorities? Keating: Well, I guess I would say, in a perfect world if we think that they deserve a special priority for that reason and I tend to think that they do, I'd want to give it to them in a way that they had it outside of bankruptcy as well as inside. I guess if all we've got is bankruptcy, that’s the form we are talking about, I would be more inclined to give them a priority. I think, as I said, [that] I concede [section] 1114, was better than nothing, and how much better than nothing is one issue. Another issue is a cross benefit issue, which is from the retiree's perspective it as clearly better than nothing, because [*] I think it put them in a position where they were getting better recoveries than they would have gotten otherwise. I mean, I think LTV is the perfect example [where] without [section] 1114, they're just general unsecured creditors. They are just going to sit back and wait for a case that might take a couple years, they are not in a position like a banker, a trade creditor, they are [not] going to have a diversified portfolio. In a case like that, it got them something. Then you sort of have to ask the question [because] there's a lot of sympathetic groups, retirees are near the top of the list. What about tort creditors, they are involuntary too? The other thing about retiree benefits that makes it difficult in terms of the cost to the process, is that unlike a number of the priorities, even like the basic priorities that you see in section 507(a), these retiree benefits in certain cases, in certain industries, can literally swallow up the company, and in that respect they are different than a lot of the garden variety priorities, even the ones that consumer deposits. Even in the [section] 507(a) priorities, you have a dollar cap, so they are not going to skew a case. But we've certainly seen cases where the retiree benefits, the size of the obligation, is worth more than the assets of the company, [like] in those auto cases. I think what's started to happen, and I don’t think this is a bad result, is sometimes, and I'm thinking the auto cases again, the retirees’ union deals with the employer and says, “all right, we all see that there is no way in the world the company with the current demographic of workers to retirees could every pay what we originally promise, so what can we do?” “We'll give you half the company, or we'll give you a third of the company, and we'll create a VEBA”and then you do the best and then we'll leave that to you and we'll administer and do the best that you can to try to give as much coverage as you can to the folks that got the promise, who are not going to get the full benefit of the promise as originally made.” In a way it does sort of become like the mass tort cases where there is a channeling injunction, but in this case it's a negotiated channeling injunction. I guess, going back to your question, [*] shall we treat them differently because they involuntary they are more sympathetic? I would say yes, versus someone who went into a lending arrangement with their eyes open. I mean, you could say, * Language clarified in transcription process. 18 I mean, if you were just a super-hardcore libertarian conservative type, you could say, “well, you know, back when they were workers and they were made this promise, they could’ve checked to make sure that the company pre-funded, and if the company wasn’t pre-funding they would go and find a job with a company that would give them a separate medical benefit account that they were funding on a cash basis.” You can always walk back and say, well, you know, they really weren't completely involuntary, because at some point they made a choice even if by their passivity. I'm not going to make that argument, but it isn't even when volunteering and involuntary, I think my point is it's not always black and white, even when it seems like it's black and white, it's often shades of gray. Keach: One quick follow-up and then I know Mr. Butler has a question and Mr. Togut does too. This is a structural question and it goes to something you said when you were talking about how the unions deal with this particular issue. [Section] 1114 was set up, essentially, with the presumption that if the retiree medical benefits spring from a collective bargaining arrangement, that the union will be the representatives of the retirees. They are obviously some concerns that have been expressed that there's an inherent conflict there when there isn't enough money to go around which is, of course, in every case. I wondered if you have a view on that, whether or not the presumption should be that the union continues to represent the retirees or should they have separate representation of their interest once a bankruptcy is filed. Keating: Maybe it should be a rebuttable presumption. I do think increasingly we are starting to see conflicts between the active union workers and the interest of the retirees. Maybe historically, if we went back a few decades where union workers almost like something in the family, and so even if you weren't a retiree maybe your dad was a retiree in the union, and so I think it seemed like traditionally, maybe there's been a greater alignment of interest naturally between the retirees in the union and the active workers. Lately there have been cases where retirees feel like they are being sold out by the current union workers, and feel like they're not getting the best representation because of the inherent conflict of interest. Maybe those are still the exception and not the rule, so maybe we are still at a point where we can start with the presumption that the unions will look out for those that worked before them, but that retirees, individual retirees should be able to make a case to the bankruptcy judge that, in fact, the union is not adequately looking out for their interest. Keach: Thank you. Mr. Butler and then Al. Butler: Professor, I wonder if you could reflect on what you understand to be the differences between qualified pension plans and non-qualified retiree benefits. * Language clarified in transcription process. 19 The reason I make the distinction is that one comes with a contract and a promise, the other, many times, comes in its initial form without a promise. Many, many companies maintain retiree benefit programs that on the terms the programs say in plain English in large type, "This program can be discontinued at any time at the discretion of the Company. It can be modified, it can be changed, there are no promises." Yet we, for social reasons, choose to ignore the face of that disclaimer. Do you see a difference between the two? Because one concern I have is your paper pointed out, or testimony points out, is that you're seeing is people because of what's happened in some bankruptcy cases where there has been a conversion of discretionary programs to something else, you're seeing these programs being discontinued wholesale across the country. Keating: Visteon in particular to name one, right? Visteon has basically said that [section] 1114 overrides that whole modification. Butler: The discretionary language in the contract. So [*] if you see a distinction, I'd love to hear your views of it. Keating: Well, I definitely gave a lot of thought to the Visteon case, and my problem with the Visteon case is that my feeling is if something is a claim outside of bankruptcy then it should be a claim inside of bankruptcy and if something is not really a claim outside of bankruptcy, if it's not a contractual right to payment, bankruptcy shouldn’t make it one. I think I would say, [and] this goes back to the Supreme Court and Butner, bankruptcy should take state law entitlement as it finds it, absent of some clear federal bankruptcy policy to the contrary. I guess in Visteon maybe the judge was claiming [section] 1114 was the federal policy to the contrary. It seems to me that if you have a non-vested retiree medical benefit promise that in fact outside of bankruptcy could be terminated by the employer, then the same should be true in bankruptcy. I have to say though, there's a matter of contracts doctrine, the notion of these non-vested retiree medical benefit, promises or programs, have always been a puzzle to me, because I've never understood the notion of, “okay, we don’t really owe you this retiree medical benefit obligation for life, we can stop it at any time we feel like it.” Yet, “yeah, we are paying it, we are paying it even though we don’t actually have to, and even though we could stop it at anytime,” it's always been a strange concept to me. Yet if outside of bankruptcy that’s how courts are willing to construe it, that it is something that the employer can, in fact, walk away from, if that’s how nonbankruptcy law treats it, then I think that’s how bankruptcy law should treat it as well. Keach: Thank you. Mr. Togut. * Language clarified in transcription process. 20 Al Togut: Yes. By the way, I'm Al Togut, the co-Chair [of the Commission]. [*] I wanted to ask you [*] a multi-part question, and just so you understand where I'm coming from, I represented the official retiree committee in Nortel. It seems to me, I'm asking if you share this view or you don’t, and if you don’t why not, that there's two kinds of retiree benefits fundamentally. When Jack Butler talks about terminating the plan, that can be viewed as terminating the promise to employees in the future that for continued performance you will get benefits [and] you can distinguish from that the employees who are truly retired, who have fully performed, who took a lesser pay because factored into their compensation were these benefits. I have a question about your feeling about terminating the benefits for a fully performed employee versus the promise to provide the benefits in the future for future performance. That’s one part of this. The other part of this is taking a case like Nortel, the whole idea of terminating retiree benefits and the whole idea of Visteon, is that there's a greater good, and the greater good is we are trying to save a company, and so in the process of saving the company you have to cut back on expenses, and trim it down so that it can continue to survive. But, [then] there's a chapter 11 with no company being saved, a straight out liquidation. To exaggerate the facts a little more, you take a case like Nortel where they had a windfall in generating $7 billion for the intellectual property, they never expected they'd get anything close to that. At that point, in a straight out liquidation the retiree benefits were sought to be terminated to enhance the return to other groups of creditors. I'm asking is what the distinction between a fully-performed employee and having the promised benefits terminated, and a distinction between saving a company, so it can emerge from chapter 11 and operate versus a straight our liquidation. Your view on those four possibilities? Keating: Let me take the first one. I think the first issue comes down to the common law of vesting, and there's an entire common law of vesting around retiree benefits, and if it's possible for a court to find that even with a person who is fully retired, that has started to received benefits, that those benefits aren't, in fact, vested. That’s [*] what I was saying before this weird concept of, “gee, you’ve got these retirees they are not even giving anything to the company, then you're not contractually bound to pay them these benefits, and yet you’ve been doing it?” Oh, and now you're going to stop.” It's possible that a court could determine, “Yeah, those were or weren't vested because those retirees when they were workers, even then they knew that even after they retired, the company could change or terminate the benefits at any time, it was right in the contract.” I think that’s rotten, but as a contracts matter, as I understand the vesting common law, I think it's possible. * Language clarified in transcription process. 21 I certainly think if I were a judge I would have less trouble in finding lack of vesting with a worker who was still working and had some options with respect to the promise that I'd made to them about what's going to happen after they retire versus taking away the benefit from someone who has already done all their [work], put in 40 years and they’ve been retired and they’ve been getting the benefit. I think if I were a judge and I had discretion I would be more inclined to figure out a way to find that that one was vested, but I think it's possible that they could find it's not. Your second question I think raises a great issue that I've addressed in other papers on this. I say I've addressed it, I haven’t resolved it, but here is the issue which is frustrating. One of the problems I see with section 1114 is, ultimately, section 1114 needs to define the relative priority of the retiree, because one of the weird things about [section] 1114 is that it was modeled on section 1113, but it's like apples and oranges. I mean, [section] 1113 is an executory contract, both sides still have something to give, it's a labor contract. [In] section 1114, you're talking about someone who gave what they're going to give to the debtor, and now they're just trying to claim it. As a claimant, they ought to have a relative priority attached to their claim, so that we know where they stand. In your scenario, the language of section 1114 has this, "Shall pay … shall pay unless, shall pay unless” [and] you can come to court and show that if you did pay that that would make it impossible to a reorganization. It's kind of a nebulous priority, and in your case, it shows how we really need [*] this backup administrative expense priority for the retiree benefits under [section] 1114. You see, I think even that priority a bit unclear. I think the case that you raised where you’ve got this chapter 11 liquidation, so there's not going to be a reorganization, there's not going to be a continuing company who has regular cash flow to paying retiree benefits. I think that highlights the fact that these retiree medical benefit claims, they're just a claim and a mega-claim, and Congress, why didn’t you tell us what priority, what relative priority you wanted to put on that mega-claim when you did section 1114, instead of assuming that tall cases were going to be like LTV where the company is clearly going and is going to have a cash flow. In answer to your question, I don’t think [section] 1114 really answers the question very well. That is, the question of the relative priority of the retiree claim as against, secured creditors, unsecured creditors with priority, unsecured creditors without priority, I think it's a puzzle the way that it was written, because again, Congress tends to write reactive legislation, and [section] 1114 was a very reactive piece of legislation. It was written in the aftermath of the LTV case and it addressed what was going on in that case, but these retiree medical benefit issues come in a lot of different forms, and sometimes ones that we can't imagine very well, like the one that you just talked about. * Language clarified in transcription process. 22 Keach: To pick up on that theme for just a second and then we'll have to wrap up. Isn't it the case of both sections 1113 and 1114 suffer from the same problem? Keating: Absolutely. Keach: That is, that they were written for a presumed kind of reorganization that happens very infrequently at the moment, and that is a sort of bootstrap reorganization with the company continuing in place largely in its existing form with, one hoped, a better balance sheet but even the language of the provisions don’t seem to accommodate the idea that you have companies that are being sold in 363 sales or liquidated. In fact, looking at the problem you just expressed in terms of not being told about the priority, in fact, we are told what the priority would be in chapter 7, which is nothing like it would be in chapter 11, and so that in and of itself suggests the kind of schizophrenia around this point, and maybe the point we can close with isn't this just a problem of the externalities of the kinds of chapter 11s we see having overwhelmed the language. Keating: Yeah, [*] I've also talked about the lack of priority for retiree benefits in [chapter] 7, and the kinds of best interest of creditors test conundrums that that can be created when the unsecured creditors who aren't retiree creditors can say, “well, gee, I'm getting a lot less in this [chapter] 11 because these retirees who are just going to be the same as me in the [chapter] 7, are getting this special priority, and the going concern surplus in this case isn't as big as the retiree claim, so I want to ask you to deny confirmation on the basis that this plan doesn’t meet the best interest of creditors test.” As far as section 363 goes, I know in reading the transcript for the testimony in March, there was a lot of talk about new provisions that would deal with [section 363 [sales] and particularly trying to, in effect, force any [section] 363 sale to consider, if not require, that the buyer keeps collective bargaining agreement obligations in place and retiree medical benefit obligations in place. Of course, if you were to make that hard and fast, then you might just end up with more piecemeal liquidations if that had to run with land as it were. It might stop the [section] 363 sales and you might end up with just less value maximizing transactions in bankruptcy. Keach: As Chris Levine, who is not here often says, we could have drafted the Bankruptcy Code on an index card, or could just say, “we pay everybody,” but it probably wouldn’t work very well. Thank you very much. Brandt: Can I just correct one thing though on the record that you mentioned? I'm Chair of the Illinois Finance Authority and so I deal with pension fund issues in Illinois on a daily basis. * Language clarified in transcription process. 23 As I read your statement, your parents are members of the Chicago Teachers’ Union, but their pension plan is not operated by the State of Illinois, it is in perfect shape, will never be affected by any legislation in Springfield, and is terribly solvent, thankfully, because the City of Chicago has it as a separate pension plan, separately funded. Keating: They don’t seem to believe that, but I'll tell them that tonight. Brandt: I understand. Keating: I'll tell them they can rest easy. Brandt: The CTU's Pension Plan has been for almost 35 years divorced from any other pension plan, there's no oversight from Springfield, it is run under the oversight of the City of Chicago. [*] Keach: We do have to move on to Professor Lipson, who has been waiting patiently. Our next witness is Professor Jonathan Lipson, who's from the Temple University School of Law. Professor Lipson is going to talk to us about controlled discovery and examiners, among other things. Professor, we have read you paper and we would appreciate it if you could summarize and then we'll get to the same kind of questioning you’ve been watching up till now. Thank you. Jonathan Lipson: Thank you very much for inviting me to discuss this with you today. I wanted to start by thanking all of you guys, the Commissioners and the American Bankruptcy Institute for organizing this. I think it's an extremely important project and in some ways it's unfortunate that Congress isn't doing this, but we are very lucky to have you guys doing it instead. I also want to thank to Michelle [Harner] and Sam [Gerdano], because it seems that they're doing a great job of managing the whole process. Most of my work as an academic has looked at the problem of information flow dealing with troubled companies. Regardless of what your politics are about bankruptcy, I think most people would agree that you need an effective flow of information to restructure troubled companies. Then I want to talk about two [*] proposals that I gave you in my written statement. First, is the problem of controlled discovery, as you’ve described it Bob. I think the problem is well understood by the Commission and I think most bankruptcy practitioners and it's simply that, given claims trading, given private distressed investors, given complex hedging strategies, given complex capital structures, it appears to be the case that it is increasingly difficult to understand who, to quote * Language clarified in transcription process. 24 Abbott and Costello, is on first, in many cases, whether before bankruptcy or in chapter 11. Obviously that’s important for [*] at least two reasons. One is economic and one really goes to the integrity of the system. The economic issue has to do with the fact that if it is difficult to discover who is in a position to control a case, it is probably going to be more costly to renegotiate the capital structure of the company and therefore to reorganize it, whether outside of bankruptcy or inside of bankruptcy. Fights in cases like American Airlines and so on are in essence, [are] about controlled discovery and compliance with rules that would in a sense, force people to disclose their ability to control some aspect of the case. There are other economic costs that the problem of control discovery creates that I describe in the paper, I won't belabor them now, but we can talk about them in the Q&A. The other issue is systemic integrity. If you don’t understand who is in control of a company or a case, you might start to worry that folks who are in the control of the company or the case don’t necessarily have the interest of the process at heart. Maybe they're not acting in some way and in accordance with whatever it was Congress thought it was doing in 1977 and 1979. It also makes it more difficult for people like me and Michelle [Harner] to study the system and understand what's really going on, because the information that we need is simply not, in many cases, available. The proposal that I gave to you, [and] I've written about it elsewhere, is to create a system of what I call positional disclosure, and the basic idea is that we would ask distressed investors that obtain a material position in or affecting a distressed company to disclose that position or set of positions in real time online electronic registries. Why does this not already happen? Well, there's a gap in the law that federal securities laws require disclosure of the ability to obtain control of solvent companies under Rule 13D of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, but that only applies to voting equity, and what do we know about insolvent companies when they are in the slide into bankruptcy or in the vicinity of insolvency, equity is not what really controls the case for the company, it's going to be the debt in some way. [Rule] 13D doesn’t apply to debt. Once a company is actually in bankruptcy, if it ends up in bankruptcy, we have [Bankruptcy] Rules 3001 and 2019, as amended, which certainly make an effort to produce information about the ability to control a case, but they are either imperfect or costly in a variety of ways. Having investors make this disclosure in real time on a electronic registry, I think probably ends up being [*] better for investors as consumers of the information because they can rely on it, and better or the producers of the information because it's cheaper to comply. * Language clarified in transcription process. 25 It sounds simple but, you know, I recognize that there are many, many complicated subsidiary questions that system would create, and I've discussed some of those questions in other work and I'm happy to discuss those questions with you. That’s the first proposal, how to deal with using positional disclosure to deal with the problem of controlled discovery. The second proposal in some ways, I think, is to many people more mundane but in some ways I think more of a hot-button issue for lawyers especially in large cases, and that is the question of what to do about bankruptcy examiners. As Bob mentioned that the outset in [section] 1104(c) of the Bankruptcy Code speaks as if bankruptcy examiners are going to be mandatory if either certain conditions exist, if there was fraud or something of that sort, or you have a debtor with qualifying unsecured debt in excess of $5 million. You might think that that means we are going to have lots of bankruptcy examiners, and there is certainly authority in the Congressional record for the idea that bankruptcy examiners would be fairly common in very large cases. In fact that’s not all what has happened, I've done fairly extensive study of the use of examiners, in chapter 11 and my research shows that even the very largest cases, you're not likely to find them requested in more than 15 percent of those cases, and they're [only] going to be appointed, that is the request is going to be granted in fewer than half of those. Those are the largest cases, cases involving more than $100 million, virtually certain to satisfy the qualifying language of the mandatory element of [section] 1104(c). People don’t want them very often and judges are very uncomfortable in granting requests for them, even when it appears that they're statutorily required. When you look [*] at smaller companies, [and I] haven’t published this yet, but I can give you a preview. We got a sample of about 570 small cases, mainly cases that are not publicly traded or have $100 million in assets, and there, you go from an appointment rate of 6.7 percent, which is what you see in the big cases, to an appointment rate of about 1 percent. There were a total of 10 examiners in the sample of small cases that I looked at from 1991 to 2007. It's pretty clear that people either don’t want examiners or judges, are not comfortable with giving them examiners or some combination. Why? Well, it's obvious, I think people are very concerned about the costs and benefits associated with having a bankruptcy examiner. The question then becomes, well, if you are concerned that, for example, people might be using the mandatory language, seemingly mandatory language of [section] 1104(c) strategically, which certainly people suggest happens sometimes, then what do you do? Well, I proposed in other work that you eliminate that mandatory feature and you replace the mandatory $5 million number, which is problematic for a bunch of reasons, * Language clarified in transcription process. 26 including that it doesn’t actually account for inflation since 1978 with a presumption that an examiner should be appointed if in the interest of the estate, and then set forth some criteria that would guide a judge in understanding whether or not an examiner will be in fact, in the interest of the estate. It's a presumption that could obviously be rebutted, and part of the goal of replacing mandatory shall with a presumption, is that it would then deter parties who might attempt to use it strategically from doing so. In the event that there really is a request, force the information out. If somebody really has a good reason for asking for one, put them to the test, and if they don’t, put it to rest. I've provided some sample language that I'm sure can be radically improved by folks on this Commission, but I think you all get the basic idea. Those are two suggestions that I have, and [when] Michelle ]Harner] asked if I'd be willing or able to do this, and I said, "Of course, what would you like me to talk about?" She said “anything you want,” which is really dangerous. It's like [how] the most expensive piece of medical equipment [is] the pen and the blank prescription pad. I've tried to limit myself to these two things, and I'd be happy to discuss those or, really, almost anything, except medicine, with you. Keach: Judge Carey? Judge Carey: Professor, I was one of those judges who Mr. Keach referred to earlier who refused to appoint an examiner when the statutory standard had been met, and I failed to do that because there was nothing for the examiner to examine, I found. Did I do something wrong? [*] Lipson: Yeah, it's sort of a Donald Rumsfeld problem, right, "You don’t know what you don’t know." Yet, I obviously wasn’t in your courtroom at the time, I couldn’t begin to tell you. [*] One of the things the second step of this research project finds is that even amongst large cases, we've looked at more large cases than in the first study, the courts in Delaware are very, very unlikely to appoint examiners and indeed there’s a statistically significant inverse relationship between a request for an examiner and getting one appointed if you happen to be in Delaware. I think examiners are in part about systemic integrity, so if you have confidence in the lawyers, if you have confidence in the other professionals in the case, that they're doing their job, it's not obvious to me why you would have really any good reason to doubt them and therefore appoint an examiner simply for the sake of doing so. The answer [*] is by and large trust judges, and by and large trust professionals, so I think what my proposal is seeking to do, is in essence bring the statute into line with reality, that the profession and the bench have voted with their feet, and they voted in a way that was different from what Congress initially anticipated. * Language clarified in transcription process. 27 Given the sort of sausage-like history of the provision, as Bob suggested earlier, it's not obvious to me that Congress really meant it and so maybe this is simply coming back to some kind of equilibrium that in fact is more useful. So, no, I don’t have any reason to believe you did anything wrong. Brandt: Professor, trust me, if it's in there they meant it, and that would be a good way to approach it. Keach: Yeah, but it probably was a compromise. I wanted to ask you some questions about controlled discovery, but let me just follow-up on this point, and one of the things that always struck me about this provision in general, [section] 1104 as a whole, is that it doesn’t get used very much to the frustration of a lot of people because both of the instruments are sort of, [well] one is a very blunt instrument, which causes all kinds of havoc like termination of exclusivity, displacement of management et cetera, and so nobody really wants to go there except in the most extreme circumstances. The examiner role is insufficiently defined so that it's not clear that it has the sort of tools to be terribly useful, and so that’s why it doesn’t get used very much. There was a flurry, I can remember, historically, of the beast called “an examiner with expanded powers,” where we all got creative and started to try to define useful examiners, diplomat examiners and mediator examiners and the like, and then that flurry died. My personal theory is that the externalities conspired to give other people control that was sufficient enough to not have to worry about that problem anymore. Looking at that history, and then looking at that thesis, wouldn’t it be better if we just overhauled this section in ways that created useful individuals, so the courts would want to appoint them, and they could do jobs efficiently, and at some defined as opposed to undefined cost? Lipson: Well, I hate to sound like a law professor, but what do you mean by useful, [because] it really depends, right? I think one could understand that [section] 1104 is what Congress thought it was doing at the time. These are obviously legacy positions, in a sense. I mean, examiners have been around in one form or another for many years, it's not something that, in fact, sprang into existence in 1978, examiners were appointed in equity long before the Chandler Act enacted them. Keach: I mean, just to follow up, and I gave you a piece just from experience. I'm largely the debtor side chapter 11 lawyer in my district, and I can tell you one of the first things I learned from one of my mentors was if you think that somebody might try to move for a trustee in your case and you think they might win, move for the appointment of an examiner, because it was always seen as a defensive mechanism because examiners don’t actually do anything that’s going to hurt the case. By the time the report comes out we'll have confirmed the plan and moved on, so what I mean by useful is something other than drafting a report that may or may * Language clarified in transcription process. 28 not see the light of day. Now, we've seen, I think, in Tribune and other cases, probably the most recent example would be Judge Gonzales' report which may never see the light of day, but we've see examiner's reports generate meaningful settlements and drive cases, so it's not that they can't be useful, but I guess the question is, should we think about just overhauling the statute in ways greater than fixing [section] 1104(c)(2)? Lipson: It's an excellent question, and I don’t know that I have a ready answer to it. I guess if I had to answer the question one way or the other at this point, I would say probably not. I think the system by and large works. Again, that’s because I by and large have confidence in judges and I by and large have confidence in lawyers, and the fact that we are not using these folks much doesn’t mean we don’t want their appointment and power out there on the books. [*] I interviewed a bunch of lawyers for the first phase of [my] examiner study, and the person who had been an examiner on several case said, "You know, they are high bore instruments, they're very rare but when you need one, you really need one," and you can really use them, and judges sometimes find them very valuable because they are a mechanism through which the judge can exercise discretion and influence the case or help the case along in ways, that the judge couldn’t do personally, whether with expanded powers or not. Yeah, it's certainly interesting to think about other kinds of things, you could easily imagine an entirely reformulated chapter 11 system, as we were talking earlier about, going back to the 1973 study that, would say, well maybe this should all be done by a bankruptcy administration and not involve courts at all. There are all sorts of different ways to re-conceptualize the system. I think that the other reason I would be a little resistant to really radically reform [section] 1104 is that it's, like anything else in the law, something that professionals know pretty well, and I think that professional competence depends in significant part on familiarity with the tools that you have. You may not want to use those tools a lot, but it doesn’t mean you don’t want them. Unless you have serious doubts about the integrity of the lawyers, or the integrity of the Bench, or the process generally, I guess I probably wouldn’t radically change [section] 1104(c). Whether you might do something different with trustees is a question I haven’t thought specifically about, but you're correct, request for trustees are even less common than request for examiners. More common than either will be requests to convert a dismissed case. That’s true about the large cases and the small cases, and I spend as much time thinking about exactly why that might be but, again, I think my instinct at this point without having too much time to reflect on it would be, no, I wouldn’t radically overhaul [section]1104, but I might work around the margins of it. Keach: Mr. Brandt. * Language clarified in transcription process. 29 Brandt: Judge Houser and I had a discussion about this on a panel some years ago and one of the issues we talked about, and not in the large cases such as Revcor or the others, but the mid-sized smaller case,, was if there was a motion for a trustee, often the cost and the hubbub to do the hearing was almost going to kill the case, and the mid-range ground was to appoint an examiner because one of the examiners primary duties was to respond quickly to the court [on] whether there should be a trustee and in effect [*] maybe skirt the issue of some of the evidence or needs and get the question called rather quickly. The problem became that examiners then sought to prolong their appointments and they never got quite around to saying there should be a trustee or shouldn’t, and as Bob says, they were often doing reports until the confirmation, and that always struck me. I mean, I remember Judge Houser, and I'm not putting words in your mouth, suggesting to me that sometimes the judges wanted the examiner to actually come back and do what the statute says and that is, offer a recommendation as to whether the immediate need for a trustee exist or not. Would something like that, if we put some teeth into that particular aspect of it and solve some of the issues you raise? Lipson: Do you mean sort of a pre-examiner examiner? Brandt: No. I mean, if the examiner actually did the primary duty that the Code says the examiner should do, first report to the court on whether there's a need for a trustee. Lipson: I'm not sure I read the statute necessarily in quite the same way. I mean, I think that the statute is a little more open-ended and flexible than that, but I think it is true, as Bob suggested earlier, that the examiner is a fallback position in many cases. Brandt: Or is a ROM Trustee at some point? Lipson: Yeah, the ROM Trustee is sort of the judge’s little helper. There are all sorts of ways you can view it depending on your view of examiners, but I think that the problem that you're articulating is a very important one, which is you give an examiner some rope and they're going to keep clawing on the rope. You say, “You’ve got a month, and here is a budget, go figure out the answer to this question. Don’t come back to me with 10 more questions and the request for another three months, and $8 million and more in your budget." Sometimes examiners come back and ask for that anyway, and sometimes they don’t. [*] If you go back and look at the older cases I think there was more of what you described earlier; which is the examiner really stretching things out. In the same way that debtors in possession stretch out exclusivity forever, and judges got smart and figured out that that wasn’t really such a good thing. Congress also got into that game. * Language clarified in transcription process. 30 I think the system is capable of responding to those abuses, and indeed, I have just been working with New York City Bar Association on a book that they're publishing on the best practices for examiners and helping those folks who have to appoint examiners or people who would be examiners or might request them, to understand exactly how they keep that railroad running efficiently. As I said, I don’t think I've ever encountered anybody who seriously thinks we should eliminate the position entirely, but I think there are concerns about cost, and that concern about cost can be expressed in many ways. Certainly if the question in the first instance is,should a trustee be appointed or should this case be converted or dismissed, I don’t see why that isn't a very simple question. [*] Brandt: In response to Judge Houser's dialogue with me, we were trying to find some research, whether we could find any examiner who, shortly after their appointment, let's say, within 20 days, suggested to the court there needed to be a trustee and their work here was done, and frankly, we couldn’t find one. Lipson: Yeah, and I don’t think I've ever seen that either. You can imagine that selfinterest might be part of that, but [*] there's nothing that would preclude an examiner from being asked that question. Keach: Professor Lipson, I want to switch to the topic [*] of this whole issue of the conduct of claims trading parties,[*][which] is interesting because it seems to me it goes fundamentally to the question that’s been debated, particularly since DBSD I guess, which is does creditor motive actually matter? It seems to me somewhat obvious if we are talking about somebody who has a completely external motivator, like a swap tied to an event or a short position in a related case. The kinds of things where I hypothesize and I think it gets a little bit more difficult [is] as we move away from those kinds of obviously conflicting positions. I guess the point I want to get to bluntly is, don’t we have to answer the question about how much we care about creditor motivation before we answer the question about how much discovery of positions that’s required? Lipson: Well, we don’t ask it now [and] we don’t ask it of equity investors under Rule 13D or 13F. Keach: We do ask it now if they vote for plans, or it potentially it can be asked if they're voting for plans for their clients. Lipson: You can't solicit, you can't solicit a vote on a plan under the Code. Keach: Well then, you can designate a vote for bad faith and Adelphi and DBSA would suggest that conflicting positions could be grounds for doing so. * Language clarified in transcription process. 31 Lipson: Absolutely, yeah. Good faith obviously matters, and it's mattered for a long time, long before DBSD or anyone. [*] If I understood your question correctly and help me out here if I'm not, it's really going to assume you don’t have outliers. Keach: Let me just flip and ask it even more directly. You’ve hypothesized that we should develop a system for disclosure of positions, and I guess my question is, why? In other words, what about that information makes it important to the smooth administration of a chapter 11 case? Lipson: It's, as I say in the written testimony and as I've said in other papers, I think that I believe lawyers when they say that the transformation of the chapter 11 process over the last 20 years has just made it more costly to renegotiate. So if you assume that chapter 11 is really kind of the tip of the iceberg, that when companies are in trouble, they're going to try to renegotiate with their stakeholders long before bankruptcy, or at least before bankruptcy, maybe not long before bankruptcy, and that most of what happens in Chapter 11 as a judicial matter, is really only the tip of the iceberg and an awful lot of what really matters is going to happen outside of the courtroom in a conference room somewhere. In the olden days, when nobody was really trading and plans were very limited, and in the olden days when management was probably was going to stick with the company and you were going to have turnaround specialists and you weren't going to have [section] 363 and whatever, everybody was chained to the negotiating table. That meant, among other things, that you didn’t really have to spend a lot of time getting confident that people, other people in the room have the positions they claimed to have. One person I interviewed a few years ago, a banker, said, "You sit in these meetings and somebody says, "I'm from Citadel and I have all of the bonds or something”, how would you know if she didn’t.” You can verify it, there are probably ways you can do it, you can get people to sign things, maybe they'll lie, maybe they won't. You could litigate it under certain circumstances, see NorthWest, but it all adds costs and delay. I think if negotiations require conditions of trust to be successful, there are a couple of ways you can get that, and one is through disclosure. The other thing is that I think that I'm only interested in material position and I don’t think everybody's position should be disclosed. I think a much harder question is, what's material? I think that if I'm correct that these are costs that the parties amongst themselves bear, they ultimately probably would benefit from having a system of improved disclosure, pre-bankruptcy as well as in chapter 11, for the same reasons that we think that investors in the larger securities markets benefit from something like Rule 13D. There seems to be something about taking control, creeping through the process of taking control that matters in both closed negotiations and the larger marketplace. It really is more about the cost of negotiating than it is about the cost of adjudicating. * Language clarified in transcription process. 32 Brandt: What would you suggest that be material, I mean 5 percent on the outside for the SEC, but in a bond it's probably 20 or 25 to 30 percent before it really can give you a controlling position. Lipson: I think that’s probably right. You have to sort of start from the end, which is, what would a plan likely look like? Keach: 33.1 percent. Lipson: Yes, 30, whatever blocking position in [section] 1106 would be kind of plausible. As I say, defining material here is not easy. Brandt: I agree with Bob and I think blocking position, but I'm not sure the level of materiality, it's some threshold below that because it's indicates intent on a runner basis much like the SEC requires for stock. Lipson: That’s right, and 5 percent obviously isn't the majority of anything and yet that’s what the SEC says. Brandt: Could you see somebody like SEC having their role expanded to cover disclosure for this kind of stuff and run the compliance? Lipson: Maybe. [*] Keach: Do you mean for claims and equity, both? [01:50:00] Brandt: Yes. I mean, for that trading. [*] Because we have this phrase "loan to own" I mean, [and] at some you are essentially trading in equity instruments, they just aren't called that yet. Lipson: Exactly and that’s where the gap in law is. The SEC got out of the business of bankruptcy in 1978, they didn’t like it, and nobody like them being in that business. Brandt: [*] I mean, let's say it wasn’t outside the SEC or something like, how would you see the cost being managed for that compliance? Lipson: That’s the question. I think the idea behind online registries is that it's not that hard to submit something [electronically]. Brandt: You'd still have to have some enforcement mechanism that will cost money. Lipson: That’s right. Well it depends, you can public enforcement and you can have private enforcement. You could, for example, leave it to the parties to say, we do already under the 1934 Act. I think you’ve not disclosed something materially, and you should have, and maybe there's a private cause of action that private individuals can bring. Maybe you also have a regulatory apparatus that supports * Language clarified in transcription process. 33 it. There are great questions and I haven’t answered all of them, in part because I don’t think we understand the extent of the problem. [*] Butler: I just want to take a breath for a second and go back because your testimony focuses on controlled discovery, but the fact is that [*] the secondary distress markets we have now, that we didn’t have 20 or 25 years ago, have a lot of benefits as well as costs. Those benefits include providing liquidity to thousands of stakeholders in cases who are able to cash out and go away at some discount or at some price that they agree to in the market. It's a marketplace transaction. That has, I think, [*] saved a lot of businesses who've been able to cash out and move on. Not that I'm talking to the target but other stakeholders who are able to cash out their positions and move on. The distressed trading place has, first and foremost, provided liquidity and it is unregulated. There are lots of day trades, someone's on something today, that’s on something tomorrow, and I think many of us who are involved in the system, live in a world where you negotiate with somebody in the room one day and find out the next day that they're not in the room anymore. The deal you had yesterday, you’ve got to redo tomorrow, that’s troubling, but that’s the flip side of providing liquidity to stakeholders. I guess what I'd like to hear you comment on a little bit, is the balance of the two. I mean, it's not just an information issue, it's a liquidity issue for stakeholders and when you balance those things, you’ve got to provide, I think, a marketplace where people want to play and where people want to believe they're being treated fairly. At least if they were distressed trader sitting next to you, I think they would say to you, "Hey, to do the kind of disclosure you're talking about is extraordinarily prejudicial because it would disclose to other people out investment strategy which is not something that is anyone's business but ours and why is that?” And maybe at some point it is [our business]. [*] I'm just trying to get you to, if you could, to sort of broaden your testimony in terms of how you see all these [interact]. Keach: Just to tweak that question, the conflicting point, as Jack and I would say, is the point is, when you're enter chapter 11, maybe chapter 11 is different. Lipson: I think the question is: liquidity for whom? It’s not liquidity for the debtor, so it's got to be liquidity for folks who are selling out of their positions. So you could say, “well, the trade sells, and that then enables them to re-lend to that debtor?” Probably not, but maybe it provides liquidity, maybe that’s beneficial. Butler: No, I'm sorry. I was talking liquidity to stakeholders. That’s not a bad part in the bankruptcy system. [*] Lipson: Correct. That’s right, and so it provides liquidity to the trade creditors, right? * Language clarified in transcription process. 34 Butler: Right. Lipson: I certainly don’t believe that claim shedding is evil or inherently problematic. What I'm focusing on is how to make it a more smoothly-functioning market, and I think, you know, you’ve phrased the problem in the right way, which is that any change of the sorts creates cost and you have to ask yourself are the benefits commensurate with the costs? Part of the problem is that we know that a lot of this is going on, and we know that it creates problems, we don’t know how significant the problems are so I don’t have a model statute, for example, to give you, because I don’t know for sure exactly what should be required, but I'm pretty confident this is a significant concern. The goal here is to have a smoothly functioning market, it's not to impede the market at all, it is to promote liquidity, provided that the creation the liquidity doesn’t result in other collateral cost. Berman: Don’t you need integrity within that marketplace? Lipson: That’s right, and I think [that’s] part of the economic costs and their social cost. The economic costs are the costs of the parties, maybe that’s great maybe it's small, maybe you have a smaller group of people that all know each other, and they trust each other and it's not a problem. But there is also the question of systemic integrity and nobody wants to go back to the bankruptcy ring or anything like that and [*] I don’t think that’s right. I do think that other things equal a little more transparency is probably better than a little less. [*]These were all the arguments that were made back in the 1960s when [Rule] 13D was added, and it seems like the equity markets have managed to survive, and adjust so I'm always a little suspicious of the claim that if we have to tell people what we are doing, we can't do it anymore, we'll drive up the cost, so much so that we can't do it. There's no evidence to support that. Brandt: You were talking about disclosure of majority positions, and I give Jack the differences, but day traders, you're talking about at some point of the threshold [*] where the disclosure triggers, and as to only those who have begun to accumulate and for that purpose. The only other issue and the question I had was, who would pay for that? I find it manifestly unfair, although I think the system needs to be there for disclosure, as Geoff says, that the debtor would wind up paying for the disclosure cost to some bureaucracy because other people are buying the debt? Lipson: Yeah, you hope not, right? They're already paying the cost of dealing with Rule 2019 fights, and so it doesn’t seem like adding to the debtor's burden is the way to go here. I think it's like any other exchange. Folks want to participate in the exchange, pay for the cost of the exchange, which [*] is what you would expect at minimum in any well-functioning market. Now as for day traders, I mean, maybe you make an exception if you're going to be in and out in a day. There are lots of ways you can carve out special exceptions * Language clarified in transcription process. 35 to balance the stuff out. As I said, I don’t have model language to give you, but I do think this is an important concept to focus on and account for both the benefits and the cost, but I'm confident that there is a gap in the system now. Keach: You’ve largely focused, I think, on control positions, and I tried to make the distinction in my opening remarks between arbitrage and control positions. Isn't this part of sort of the bigger problem and the fact that the debt trading market is, in fact, unregulated, which has led to this problem of the ad hoc committees, and [Washington Mutual] decision about when it's insider information? Should we be accommodating trading by having special disclosure purges in bankruptcy? I've never yet been able to figure out why a chapter 11 debtor would ever want to purge its information to let people trade, but isn't it actually just part of the larger problem of, should the debt markets be more like the security markets? Lipson: I think that’s right, so when I say in my written testimony that I think much of chapter 11 or the world of distressed companies generally, has become a secondary market for the trading of debt in order to obtain control of the distressed companies, that’s right. The key is, that I don’t think you need to create the same regulatory apparatus that we have securities law. What do we know about the federal securities laws? They are super-expensive to comply with and they have some significant benefits but, boy, pretty costly too. I think that it is not difficult to learn from the mistakes, if you will, of the Security Exchange Regime, and take the better pieces of it, while still trying to avoid some of the excessive cost at the margin. I think the answer is, and this goes back to the question about would you have the SEC do this, I would not. [*] I don’t feel like I have my arms around the problem long enough to know whether, or to what extent you would want regulatory involvement. You could imagine the U.S. Trustee’s Office might be perfectly adequate, maybe not. Brandt: The extension of what you're talking about, the definition of insider trading, somebody accumulating 20 percent of the debt while they're on the Committee, I mean, if you were going to have this kind of regulatory enforcement scheme you’ve got very fertile ground. What happens in our business says what would be prohibited in some extent or least frowned upon in the equity markets. Lipson: That’s right, and you don’t currently have private causes of action except at the margins in these kinds of cases. There's no reason that you couldn’t have a much narrower class of private cause of action as the enforcement mechanism, so you create a much higher hurdle. In effect, you do what Congress did with the PSRLA and the SLUSA and make it much more difficult to bring security fraud actions, but you do that from the outset so that if you want private enforcement, you make it clear it’s only going to be in anyone's interest to try to enforce it when there's a really serious violation. That’s part of what the term "material" would go to. * Language clarified in transcription process. 36 Keach: We do have to wrap this up because we are a little bit over. [*] I want to thank you very much for your thoughtful paper not to mention your body of work in general in this area, and I want to thank you for coming today. Lipson: Thank you very much for having me. Keach: Thank you. * Language clarified in transcription process. 37