Costs of Fisheries Management: The Cases of Iceland, Norway and Newfoundland Ragnar Arnason Department of Economics University of Iceland and Rögnvaldur Hannesson Centre for Fisheries Economics The Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration and William E. Schrank Department of Economics Memorial University of Newfoundland May 1999 Introduction The need for fisheries management stems fundamentally from the fact that fish resources are common property. It is well known, both from theory and experience, that common property resources will be overexploited and possibly irreversibly depleted unless subjected to appropriate fisheries management. Due to the pervasive external effects involved in the fishing activity, fisheries management is clearly beyond the reach of any single agent. Fisheries management requires either collective action at the industry level or outside intervention. Taking it for granted that the purpose of fisheries management is to increase the flow of net economic benefits from the fishing activity, the costs of operating the fisheries management system itself are obviously among those that have to be subtracted to arrive at the net benefits of fishing. This means that the cost of management will, in general, influence the optimal management of the fishery. In spite of these rather obvious truths, the cost of fisheries management has hitherto received scant attention in the academic literature on fisheries economics.1 A possible explanation for this omission is the implicit assumption that management costs are generally small relative to their benefits and consequently of minor importance. Examination of the actual fisheries management costs presented in this study shows that this assumption is far from the truth. The existence of significant fisheries management costs raises the question of how these costs should be financed. Who should pay and why? This is a well known problem in public finance and the pricing of public services (see e.g. Samuelson 1969, and Atkinson and Stiglitz 1980). More recently the same question has been increasingly framed in terms of who should be the provider of management services, the government or the industry (Andersen, Sutinen, and Cochran 1998, Arnason 1999). Although largely absent from the academic literature, management costs and how they should be financed are receiving increasing attention in practical fisheries management worldwide. In New Zealand and Australia a significant part of the cost of fisheries management is recovered from the industry, and in Australia attempts are under way to increase cost recovery.2 Management cost recovery is a component of the Icelandic ITQ fisheries management system. It has recently been introduced in certain fisheries in Canada and the United States (Milazzo, 1998), and it has been considered in Great Britain (Hatcher and Pascoe, 1998). 1 Thus, the most influential theoretical studies in fisheries economics (Gordon 1954, Scott 1955, Smith 1968, Plourde 1970, Clark and Munro 1975) as well as the textbooks (Clark 1976, Anderson, 1986 and Hannesson, 1993) all derive optimal harvesting programs ignoring the cost of implementing these programs. Empirical modeling, presumably taking its cue from the theoretical models, also largely ignore the costs of management (Arnason, 1990, Bjørndal 1987, Ólafsson et al. 1994, Placenti et al. 1992), and Schrank, Roy and Tsoa (1986). Noteworthy exceptions are Sutinen and Andersen (1985) and Anderson and Lee (1986). 2 About one half of the costs of the Australian Fisheries Management Authority, which deals with the Commonwealth fisheries of Australia, is classified as “recoverable”, and it is the policy of the Commonwealth government to recover all of these (DPIE, 1994). In New Zealand about 5 percent of the value of fish landings is collected for the purpose of cost recovery. This covers a large part, although not all, of New Zealand’s fisheries management costs. 2 A common argument for cost recovery is that the industry itself is the main beneficiary of management and hence should pay for it.3 This approach seems to derive from ideas of justice and fairness. A more economic approach to this problem would focus on the resource allocation effects of different methods of financing management costs. From this perspective, recovering management costs from the industry has certain obvious advantages. For instance, it might provide a much needed link between the provision and use of fisheries management services. Currently, the fishing industry is the user and, presumably, the primary beneficiary of these services while the predominant provider of the services is the government, which also, in most countries, bears most of the costs. It stands to reason that a closer link between the cost of providing fisheries management services and the benefits or otherwise of using them would tend to further efficiency in the use of economic resources for management purposes. When links between the costs and benefits of fisheries management are largely absent, what is it that determines the level of fisheries management services? Will they be under-provided or over-provided? These are crucial questions, which we will not try to answer in this paper. However, the information on fisheries management costs in Iceland, Norway and Newfoundland, presented in the last part of this paper, may throw some light upon this issue. The fisheries of Iceland, Norway and Newfoundland are all sub-Arctic North Atlantic fisheries, based on largely the same species employing similar fishing technologies, but somewhat different in value.4 Nevertheless, it turns out that the level of management costs, both in absolute terms and as a percentage of the total value of landings, differs a great deal between them. To us these large differences constitute prima facie evidence of how a weak link between payment of the costs and the enjoyment of the benefits of fisheries management services may cause deviations from the appropriate provision of these services. Thus, Newfoundland has by far the highest fisheries management costs measured as a percent of the value of landings. In spite of this, Newfoundland seems unlikely to have enjoyed the greatest benefits from fisheries management, as indicated for instance not only by the recent collapse of her most important groundfish stocks but also by the apparently low economic rents generated by her fisheries. By contrast, while the resource rents in the fisheries of Norway and Newfoundland probably are low or nonexisting the high prices of individual transferable quotas in the Icelandic fisheries indicate the existence of substantial economic rents (Arnason, 1996). Yet fisheries management costs are decidedly the lowest in Iceland. Components of fisheries management Governments spend money on fisheries for purposes other than fisheries management. Grants and subsidies are examples of expenditures which are not due to fisheries management. The same applies to expenditures on navigational aids such as 3 See, e.g., Haynes, Geen and Wilks (1986), and Milazzo (1998). Actually, the Norwegian fishery is the largest with a landed value close to one billion USD on the average. The landed value of the Icelandic catches has been close to 800 million USD and the landed value in Newfoundland about 200 million USD (Arnason et al. 1999, Hannesson, 1999, Schrank and Skoda, 1999). 4 3 lighthouses, positioning systems, fishing harbors, and search and rescue operations at sea. It is appropriate, therefore, at this point to discuss briefly what kind of activities constitute fisheries management, the cost of which is the focal point of this paper. Fisheries management essentially comprises the following set of activities: Research (biological and economic) Formulation, dissemination and implemention of management policy and rules Enforcement of management rules. Any sensible fisheries management must be based on an understanding of the marine environment in which a fish stock is located and an assessment of the size and productivity of the stock at each particular time. Also, since the purpose of fisheries management is to increase the economic return from the fishery, it must be based on a thorough understanding of the economics of the fishing activity and measurement of the relevant economic parameters. To achieve the double aim of preservation of the fish stocks and maximization of the economic return from the fishery, total catch and fishing effort must be constrained either directly or indirectly. Fisheries management techniques are, among other things, methods for constraining either total catch, fishing effort, or both. Enforcement of these constraints is, for obvious reasons, an integral part of the fisheries management activity. Fisheries management as a public good Fisheries management services exhibit many of the characteristics of public goods. Public goods have two characteristics, non-rivalry in consumption and nonexcludability. Non-rivalry in consumption means that two or more persons can use the good simultaneously without interfering with one another’s use of the good, while non-excludability means that no one can be excluded from using the good. 5 As already stated, fisheries management services consist primarily of (i) information generation, (ii) the establishment of fisheries management rules and (iii) the enforcement of these rules. Information, once generated, can be used by anyone without reducing it. Thus, the informational or research part of fisheries management is close to being a pure public good. Very much the same applies to the design of a management system and its enforcement. No-one participating in the industry can be excluded from enjoying the benefits. Also, the benefits are little if at all diminished by the number of participants. Given the public goods characteristics of fisheries management, the market system by itself is ill suited to provide these services. Non-excludability essentially means that it is difficult to charge for the services. Therefore, private industry can hardly survive in 5 A lighthouse is a good example, and a pertinent one in this context, of a public good; it does not harm other boats if an additional boat uses a lighthouse as a navigational aide, and it would not be possible (nor desirable) to exclude anyone from navigating with the aid of the lighthouse. Pure public goods exhibit the full measure of these two characteristics. In the real world there may not be many pure public goods. Thus, for instance, a public park is a public good but usually not a pure one. It can be enjoyed simultaneously by more than one individual, but beyond a certain point an additional individual would diminish the others' enjoyment of the park. 4 this area. Moreover, non-rivalry in use means that it is doubtful that it would be economically appropriate to charge for these services. It does not necessarily follow from these arguments, however, that the government should actually provide fisheries management services.6 As pointed out above, it is normally the fishing industry that primarily benefits from fisheries research and management. Therefore, it is in its own interest to ensure that these services are provided. Indeed, there is a presumption, often referred to as the Coase Theorem7, that under the appropriate conditions agents will overcome externality problems by negotiating the appropriate collective action, provided this maximizes the overall net benefits. In our view, this argument does not really apply in fisheries. There are two reasons why the industry cannot be expected to undertake the appropriate level of information collection and fishery regulations on its own initiative, even if such activities are beneficial to the industry. First, the industry usually lacks the legal authority to deal with the problems that must be solved in order to make fishery regulations successful. This is most obvious for fish stocks that migrate between the jurisdictions of different states or into the high seas; such problems must be dealt with at the intergovernmental level. Also, the industry typically is not authorized to bar new entrants or to impose restrictions on its members.8 Such attempts would probably run afoul of competition or anti-trust regulations, and there are indeed examples of such cases from the United States.9 Second, and more fundamentally, information provision and regulation, as discussed above, exhibit strong public goods characteristics that invite free riding behavior on behalf of industry members.10 For these two reasons, imposition of fisheries management and information generation from above may be necessary to overcome the problems of under-provision of these services if their provision were to be left to the industry itself. Government services are not costless, however. A bureaucracy is needed to deal with regulations, gathering and processing of information, etc. Professionals must be hired to do stock assessment and process information gathered about fish stocks, and the necessary equipment, such as research vessels, must be in place. The cost of these activities must be defrayed somehow. The sums involved are not trivial. In the Commonwealth fisheries of Australia the expenditure on fisheries management has been estimated at 28 million Australian dollars in 1991/92 while the total value of landings was about ten times that (273 million).11 Fisheries management costs in the 6 Provision of fisheries management services by government does not necessarily imply that these services are being paid for by public funds. 7 Put forward by Professor Ronald Coase, of the University of Chicago (Coase, 1960). 8 This is changing, however, in some countries. The governments of the United Kingdom and the Netherlands have delegated some of their management prerogatives to industry bodies (the so-called Producers’ Organizations). Similar developments have occurred on both coasts of Canada. 9 White (1954) describes how the Atlantic Fishermen’s Union in New England limited the supply of fish in order to regulate the price. This limitation would have had a conservation effect, except insofar as it involved discarding of fish at sea. The Supreme Court of Massachusetts ruled against this practice. 10 Balland and Platteau (1997) discuss the possibility of under-provision of fisheries management in a self-regulating industry. 11 Hundloe (1992). In addition, there are fisheries under the jurisdiction of the individual states. These are much more important than the Commonwealth fisheries; the total landed value of Australian fisheries was 1170 million Australian dollars in 1990/91. 5 United Kingdom are reported to have been about 45 million pounds in 1996/97, which corresponds to about 7.5% of the value of all landings of fish (Hatcher and Pascoe (1998). Government expenditure in the United States on fisheries management amounts to 15 percent of the gross revenue (Milazzo, 1998, pp. 62-63). The expenditure on fisheries management in Norway has been about 8% of the value of landings in recent years while in Iceland it has been about 3%, and in Newfoundland 15-25%. Even if the definition of costs, undoubtedly, is not identical in these studies, if only because of different accounting practices across countries, these figures clearly show that (i) fisheries management costs are high and (ii) vary substantially from one country to another. Cost recovery from industry We suggest three important reasons why cost recovery from the fishing industry has been moving up on the public agenda in several countries. First, the increasing financial burden of various social obligations undertaken by governments in industrially developed countries, combined with the reluctance among the general public to pay higher taxes, has been putting government finances under an increasing strain. This has given rise to an increasingly critical scrutiny of the public services that are being provided and how they are being financed. Second, related to the first reason, is the public demand for more efficiency in production in general. The incentive effects associated with paying for public services from general government revenue may be undesirable, as there is no link between the value of the services provided and the cost of providing them. If those who benefit from a particular activity are also the ones who pay for it there would be a link between the value of these activities and their cost. Establishing such a link, therefore, is likely to enhance economic efficiency by providing incentives to determine whether and to what extent a particular service is worthwhile. The third reason for the increasing interest in management cost recovery from the fishing industry is the growing realization that many fisheries, far from being a subsistence industry, can actually yield substantial economic rents, provided they are properly managed. Therefore, there is no need to subsidize them by providing them with management services free of charge. In fact, due to the common property problem, such supports may even be counterproductive. From this perspective, it is no surprise that cost recovery is furthest along in fisheries where an efficient fisheries management system has already been adopted.12 As far as efficiency is concerned, the question of whether management costs should be recovered from the industry may be said to have two major aspects: (i) (ii) the optimal taxation aspect, incentive effects. Cost recovery as optimal taxation The benefits of fisheries management materialize in the form of a greater net production of goods and services. This need not mean a greater production of fish. 12 Such as New Zealand, Australia, Iceland and some fisheries in Canada. 6 Economic overexploitation means that too much manpower, equipment and other means of production have found their way to the fishing industry. Sometimes, perhaps often, this means that the long run productivity of fish stocks has been harmed to the extent that more fish could be caught in the long run by using less of these factors of production. But economic overfishing always means that in the long run more of goods and services other than fish can be produced by reducing the input of manpower, capital, etc., in the fishery and directing it elsewhere. However, in the short run there may not be much economic gain, because of immobility of labor and capital. The general level of taxes, and how they are levied, has an impact on the real side of the economy. Both direct taxes on incomes, and indirect taxes such as the value added tax, affect work effort and whether it is directed to production of marketed goods and services or to activities out of reach of recorded market transactions. Taxes on the products of specific industries, or income generated in such industries, affect the allocation of resources by making such industries less profitable than otherwise, thus reducing the level of production in such industries. Would it be better, from the point of view of optimal taxation, to have the fishing industry pay its management costs? Defraying these costs from general government revenue adds to the general burden of taxation and the deadweight loss associated with that taxation. Having the industry pay these costs through a tax on incomes in the industry or a levy on its production would make it less profitable and discourage the use of factors of production in the industry. In fisheries which are imperfectly managed and where there is still a tendency to use too much manpower and capital this would be a desirable effect, as it would mitigate against excessive use of factors of production. Consider, for example, the case where a purely “biological” management regime is introduced, for the purpose of achieving maximum sustainable yield. One way of keeping total landings within the maximum sustainable yield limit, used, for example, in the United States and Canada, is to stop the fishery when that limit has been reached. Rebuilding fish stocks through such management would eventually make the industry more profitable, but without any entry regulations the industry would expand, until it would once more break even. This expansion would amount to an increase in the real costs of the industry in the form of excessive fishing gear, investment in unnecessary boats, etc., and a waste of resources for the economy as a whole. If the industry were to pay for the cost of management it would incur financial costs that would replace some of the real costs it would otherwise incur before it reaches open access equilibrium. Having the industry pay the costs of management would thus save some real resources for society. Curiously, perhaps, this argument for having the industry pay the management costs becomes weaker or evaporates altogether when the industry is regulated by individual transferable quotas. In this case the limit on the total catch would ensure resource conservation while the transferability of quotas would provide incentives for maximizing the value of the catch and minimizing the cost of taking it. Cost recovery from the industry would have no bearing on the size of the industry; entry into the industry would be effectively closed by the quota system itself. Yet there is another argument favoring cost recovery in ITQ fisheries; in an economically efficient industry rent would be generated, the amount of which would depend on the productivity of the stock, efficiency of the fleet, and the market price of fish, besides 7 other factors. If designed appropriately, cost recovery would only reduce the rent captured by the firm, without having any effect on the economic efficiency in the industry. From the point of view of optimal taxation this would constitute a gain; the tax burden on the general public could be reduced with no detrimental real effects on the fishing industry. Incentive effects of cost recovery It has already been mentioned that paying for government services out of general government revenue provides a weak link or no link at all between what these services are worth to the user and what they cost. This leads to well known problems of the appropriate supply of public services for which the user does not have to pay. Excess demand for fisheries management services is perhaps not particularly likely to come from the industry even if they are free of charge; in fact some industry participants tend to see at least some of these functions as an unwelcome intrusion into their business practices. The drive for increased fisheries management may be more likely to come from government ministries and agencies responsible for management, with the restraint being provided by ministries of finance concerned with the overall government budget. Having the industry pay for fisheries management would establish a link between what fisheries management is worth to the industry and what it costs. Clearly, the industry would be interested in maximizing the value of the services that it gets for its money and in minimizing what it pays for any given amount of services. It is likely that the industry would demand, and in all probability get, influence over management decisions if it would have to pay the management costs. This raises the question of compatibility between the interests of the industry and the interests of society at large. It has already been noted that fisheries management is a public good, benefiting the industry as a whole and the society of which the industry is a part. But is there a perfect harmony between the interests of the industry and those of society at large? Does the public derive benefits from fisheries management which are distinct from what the industry derives? It goes without saying that the industry will only be interested in management services that benefit the industry directly. Having the industry pay the full cost of management and granting it a commensurate influence over how the money is spent will therefore lead to negligence of management activities that are of benefit to the public at large but of little or no benefit to the industry. Are the interests of the industry compatible with the public interest? Marine research is to fisheries what geological research is to petroleum and other mineral industries. It can be argued that marine research has utility far beyond the fishing industry. Nonetheless, the marine research typically funded by ministries responsible for fisheries and their subordinate institutions is typically targeted for the benefit of the fishing industry. There seems little doubt that the industry has an incentive to contribute to that kind of research, but even marine research that is designed to meet the needs of the fishing industry may have benefits for a larger 8 audience as well. It can be argued, therefore, that this kind of research would be underprovided if the industry alone were to be responsible for it. Stock assessment is a kind of marine research that is specifically intended to benefit the fishing industry by providing estimates of current stock abundance and making it easier to evaluate the consequences of today’s catches on the future availability of fish. This type of research, however, is of limited direct benefit to the public at large. Provided the industry takes a long term interest in its resource base it would have a strong interest in accurate and timely stock assessments. Therefore, having the industry pay for stock assessment is likely to provide incentives for providing such assessments at the lowest possible cost and to focus research priorities on whatever is most useful for the industry. The industry itself might even take an active part in the stock assessment process by letting its own vessels take samples of fish, fish at random for assessment purposes, etc. In fact such activities have become routine in Iceland, where parts of the fishing fleet conduct random sampling under the direction of fisheries biologists for short periods every year. In order to ensure efficient utilization of the resources various regulations are necessary; setting of total allowable catches when appropriate, regulations of gear design (e.g., mesh size), protection of juveniles and spawning stock, etc. As for stock assessment, this is potentially an area where “user says, user pays” would have a beneficial effect. Assuming that firms have a sufficiently long-term perspective, or equivalently a rate of time discount that is not excessive, it is in the interest of the industry to put in place regulations necessary for ensuring that the growth potential of the fish is utilized optimally and that the present catch of fish does not diminish future productivity of the stock unduly. A plethora of fisheries regulations now in place in various countries are put in place for a quite different purpose, however. There are regulations that stipulate the size and design of boats, which gear may be used where, what type of boats may fish where, etc. Such regulations more often than not serve no purpose of efficiency; it would seem immaterial whether a fish is pulled up on a hook or caught in a net, except that some types of gear are more selective than others and hence use the growth potential of the fish more efficiently. Neither would it seem important, as far as efficient use of resources is concerned, whether a fish is taken by a small or a big boat. Such regulations may be of use in limiting controversies among different parts of the industry, but often they are just a way of favoring one industry group against another. While it would seem to be in the overall interest of the industry to eliminate such regulations, their very existence is often a sign of an industry fragmentation and controversy that would prohibit it from acting in concert, which adds an additional reason why governments need to be involved in fisheries management and detracts from the relevance of the Coase Theorem. Surveillance and enforcement are obviously needed to make any regulation effective. It has been argued that the industry should not pay the cost of such undertakings, any more than other industries pay for law enforcement on land; law enforcement being a collective good to be provided by the state.13 In our view this argument misses the point. The purpose of commercial fishing is to maximize the net economic benefits from the fishery. It follows that the overriding (and perhaps the only) criterion for 13 See Hundloe (1992), pp. 34-36, and Roy (1998), p. 22. 9 fisheries management payment arrangements is that it be as economically nondistorting as possible. Recording landings is a part of surveillance whenever there are limits to how much can be caught, whether it be at the aggregate or vessel level. Monitoring landings serves a wider purpose, however. Catch data, both aggregate landings and samples derived from these for age structure analysis, are an important input for stock assessment and usually play a major role therein, except for direct acoustic methods. Accurate landings data may therefore be crucial for an accurate stock assessment. Indeed, one of the criticisms levied at management by catch quotas is that it distorts landings data, due to the incentives to highgrade and to underreport. It is, therefore, strongly in the collective interest of the industry to collect accurate and timely landings statistics. In some fisheries in Canada fishermen have been willing to pay for supervision of landings, recognizing the collective good character of this activity and the incentive of each individual in a quota managed fishery to cheat. Some fisheries management costs may not be due to the activities of the industry but to competing claims on fish resources. Interference of marine mammals with the catches of fish, and a desire on behalf of some groups and governments to preserve these animals, have in recent times given rise to a number of regulations. It is conceivable that preservation of marine mammals and other environmental demands will impose further constraints on the activities of fishing fleets and how much fish they will be allowed to catch. The benefits of these constraints are external to the industry while such preservation would impose costs on the industry in the form of catchable fish being eaten by seals or sea birds and in the form of costly fishing gear that avoids the incidental catching of these animals. To the extent such claims are deemed legitimate, the role of the industry as a rule maker must be more proscribed than otherwise, with fisheries management becoming a public concern for a much broader range of players than those who are active in the industry. To the extent the industry would be obliged to pay for this kind of management such payment would amount to a special tax on the industry earmarked for environmental benefits for the public at large, rather than a payment for privileges the industry enjoys. Similarly, other non-use benefits of marine resources, and the management necessary to safeguard the resources for these purposes, are of no concern, and are possibly detrimental to, the industry. An example of such a non-use value is the viewing of fish as wildlife, for which purpose areas have been set aside as marine parks. Having the fishing industry pay for such activities would again amount to a special tax on the industry for the benefit of other user groups. In fact, it appears that management of marine parks could be taken care of by government bodies distinct from those dealing with commercial fisheries, as is done, for example, in Australia. The Cost of Fisheries Management in Iceland, Norway and Newfoundland As noted above, actual fisheries management costs are usually far from trivial compared to the landed value of the catch. To throw more light on this we shall in this section report on our examination of fisheries management costs in Iceland, 10 Norway and Newfoundland, studies more fully documented elsewhere.14 Our basic sources of data are government expenditures on the fisheries as recorded in the accounts of the relevant ministries. In all three countries these expenditures are extensive and varied. Our definition of fisheries management, however, is restricted to tasks performed to deal with the problems posed by the common property character of the resources. Thus, we have attempted to exclude from our estimates of fisheries management costs all other expenditures on the fisheries such as port and lighthouse operations, weather forecast services, communication services, quality control, supports for processing and marketing of fish products, etc. In our study, we have adopted common definitions of cost categories as far as possible, so as to make the figures comparable. Different reporting and accounting practices in the three different countries involved make it impossible, however, to achieve this fully. Another problem is that the fisheries of Newfoundland are managed by the federal government in Ottawa. We have omitted overhead costs of the federal government from the figures for Newfoundland while all overheads of the local administration in Newfoundland have been included. Since some of the local overhead costs are not due to fisheries management as we have defined the term, there are biases in opposite directions, the net effect of which is unclear but probably negative, since significant Ottawa costs relate to fisheries management in Newfoundland. Management costs (Mill. USD) Catch value (Mill. USD) 120 1600 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 1989 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 0 1996 20 Norway 1995 40 Iceland 1994 Nfld 1993 60 Nfld 1992 Iceland 1991 Norway 80 1990 100 Figure 1 Management costs and catch value in Iceland, Norway and Newfoundland in US dollars, at each year’s prices and exchange rates. Figure 1 shows the management costs and the value of the catch in Norway, Iceland and Newfoundland in a common currency (US dollars), at each year’s prices and exchange rates. The value of the landings is by far the lowest in Newfoundland, being about a quarter of the value of the landings in Iceland, while the value of the Norwegian landings is higher than in Iceland, except for 1990 when they were about the same. The management costs, on the other hand, are highest in Norway and 14 These studies are further documented in Arnason et al., (1999), Hannesson (1999), and Schrank and Skoda (1999). 11 lowest in Iceland, with Newfoundland in between.15 Figure 2 shows the costs of management, measured as a percentage of the total value of landings. Measured in this way, the management costs are highest in Newfoundland and lowest in Iceland. As previously mentioned, the cost figures for Newfoundland are probably too low because of the omitted central government costs. The management costs in Newfoundland varied between 15 and 26 percent of landed value over the period 1989 - 1996. Norway’s management costs are more than twice as high as the Icelandic costs, again expressed as percent of the value of landings. While the Icelandic costs have been rather stable around 3 percent of landed value, the Norwegian costs have fallen considerably, from 13 percent in 1990 to about 8 percent in 1994-1996. Cost as a share of catch value Percent 30 25 20 Nfld 15 Norw ay 10 5 Iceland 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 0 Figure 2 Management costs measured as percent of the value of landings. 15 The cost data for Newfoundland are reported for fiscal years, which begin on April 1, while the catches are reported for calendar years. The cost data are related to the catch value in the calendar year in which the fiscal year begins. The cost and catch data for Norway and Iceland refer to calendar years. 12 2000 300 1500 Costs Costs 100 40000 Costs 500 Catch 0 30000 20000 10000 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 95-96 93-94 50000 1000 0 91-92 60000 Catch 400 200 Catch Iceland (Mill. krónur) Catch 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 89-90 Costs Newfoundland (Mill. Can. $) 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 10000 6000 Costs Catch 4000 Catch 8000 2000 1996 1994 1992 0 1990 Costs Norway (Mill. kroner) Figure 3 Management costs and value of landings in domestic currency. Figure 3 shows management costs and the value of landings for each country in domestic currency. This allows us to make a quick comparison of trends. The fall in the cost/catch value ratio in Norway is due primarily to an increase in the value of landings. In Iceland management costs have risen more than the value of the catch. This increase is explained by increased research and enforcement activity while landed values have remained fairly steady. The gyrations in the Newfoundland cost ratio are due primarily to variations in the value of landings, and the high cost ratio in Newfoundland is due to the comparatively low value of the landings rather than the level of the costs being higher than in the other two countries (cf. Figure 1). Costs by categories Figures 4 - 7 give breakdown of management costs into major categories, both in absolute amounts (US dollars) and as shares of catch value. Again, it is necessary to stress that the cost categories may not be entirely comparable across the three countries. The correspondence is probably closer for the Norwegian and Icelandic data than the Newfoundland data. One common pattern of the cost categories in Figures 4 - 7 is that absolute expenditures are generally greatest in Norway while the 13 expenditures measured as a fraction of the catch value are highest in Newfoundland. 16 Hence it does not appear possible to explain differences in expenditure between the three countries by different emphasis on management tasks to be carried out, not at any rate at this level of aggregation. Coast guard/Enforcement and surveillance Iceland 5.00 0.00 Figure 4 Costs of enforcement and surveillance in US dollars. exchange rates. 1996 1996 1994 1992 Iceland Norway 1994 Norw ay Nfld 10.00 1992 Nfld 15.00 1990 Percent of catch value 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 Mill. USD Coast guard/Enforcement and surveillance Each year’s prices and The single most expensive fisheries management undertaking in the three countries is monitoring and enforcement at sea (Figure 4). In Norway and Iceland this is done by the Coast Guard while in Newfoundland the Department of Fisheries has had its own enforcement and monitoring vessels. Recently, however, the Canadian Coast Guard has been reorganized and put under the control of the Department of Fisheries and Oceans. Norway spends the equivalent of about 50 million dollars annually on Coast Guard activities related to fisheries,17 more than twice the amount that is spent in Newfoundland. Nevertheless, the lower value of the Newfoundland landings blows up the Newfoundland expenditure in relative terms. Iceland’s expenditure is roughly one-half of Newfoundland’s, and lower still in relative terms. The high surveillance cost in Norway may only partly be explained by the size of the Norwegian exclusive economic zone; it is much larger than that of Iceland, but not much larger than the Canadian zone around Newfoundland. The exclusive economic zone of mainland Norway is 875.000 km2, the zone around Jan Mayen is 292.000 km2, and the zone around Spitzbergen is 836.000 km2. For comparison, the Icelandic zone is 758.000 km2 and the Canadian zone around Newfoundland outside the 12 mile limit is 1.5 million km2. The second largest cost item is marine research (Figure 5). Note, however, that we have defined marine research narrowly as research related to stock assessment and 16 This is due to the relatively low landed catch values in Newfoundland. It should be noted that this low value of landed catch is not due to the dramatic decline of the groundfish fishery off Newfoundland, as this has been fully compensated by an increase in Newfoundland's shellfish catches. 17 For Norway, 75 percent of the activities of the Coast Guard are assumed to be related to the fisheries, a figure provided by the Coast Guard. The same allowance has been made for the Icelandic Coast Guard. 14 prediction. To this end we have attempted to exclude research of a less applied nature. In Norway the expenditure on marine research is not much more than onehalf of the expenditure on the Coast Guard. In Newfoundland the expenditure on marine research has in some years been almost as high as the expenditure on surveillance and enforcement, but expenditure on marine research has been falling in recent years. In Iceland the expenditure on marine research is roughly comparable to the expenditure on the Coast Guard.18 Marine research Norway Iceland 1990 1996 1994 1992 Iceland Nfld 1996 Norway 1994 Nfld 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1992 Percent of catch value 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1990 Mill. USD Marine research Figure 5 Costs of marine research A third cost category is the activity carried out by the Directorates of Fisheries in Iceland and Norway, and the regional administration in Newfoundland (Figure 6). In Norway this expenditure is about the equivalent of 13 million dollars per year. In 1990-92 the cost in Norway was ten times higher or more than the cost in Iceland while the difference shrank markedly in 1993 and subsequent years. This is due to the establishment of a Directorate of Fisheries in Iceland (“Fiskistofa”) that took over the monitoring and enforcement operations of a semi-private institution (“Fiskifélag Íslands”) and the Ministry of Fisheries. This change led to increased activities and a corresponding increase in the Icelandic costs. Nevertheless the Norwegian costs are still about five times the Icelandic costs. It should be noted that we have attempted to remove the costs of aquaculture management, product quality control and other items not associated with management of fish stocks from the cost figures for the Norwegian Directorate of Fisheries. In Newfoundland the cost of regional administration is roughly mid-way between the cost in Norway and Iceland, and it has been shrinking over the period considered. Still, relative to the landed value of catch, the Newfoundland costs are higher than the other two. 18 Note again that only 75 percent of the expenditure on the Coast Guard in Norway and Iceland has been attributed to the fisheries. 15 10 Norw ay 5 Iceland 1996 1994 1992 1990 0 5.00 4.00 Nfld 3.00 2.00 Norway Iceland 1.00 0.00 1996 Nfld 1994 15 1992 Mill. USD 20 Directorate of Fisheries/Regional administration 1990 Percent of catch value Directorate of Fisheries/Regional administration Figure 6 Cost of Directorate of Fisheries/Regional administration 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 Norway 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 Iceland 1990 Mill. USD Ministry of Fisheries Figure 7 Cost of Ministry of Fisheries Finally, there is the cost associated with the Ministries of Fisheries (Figure 7). For Newfoundland we do not have such data attributed to Newfoundland. For Norway and Iceland the cost of running these ministries turns out to be very similar, or the equivalent of about 3 million US dollars per year. Note that we have attempted to remove expenditure on aquaculture, fish processing and marketing from the Norwegian data. In Iceland aquaculture is under the auspices of the Ministry of Agriculture and therefore not included in the data. However, there probably still remain some cost items in the Icelandic data that relate to fish processing and marketing rather than management of fish stocks. It is therefore possible that the Icelandic costs reported above are slightly overestimated. 16 Conclusion Our comparative study of fisheries management costs in Iceland, Norway and Newfoundland shows that their fisheries management costs cannot be characterized as trivial. In Newfoundland they have varied between 15 and 26% of the value of landings. In Norway they have dropped from 13 to 8%, mainly because of an increase in the value of landings which may or may not be sustainable. In Iceland fisheries management costs have remained rather steady at about 3% of the value of landings. It is important to realize that these numbers have been arrived at on the basis of a rather narrow definition of fisheries management, namely as activities intended to counteract the problems caused by fish stocks being common property. Management expenses of this order of magnitude are by no means insignificant. They appear even more substantial compared to the attainable economic rents from the fisheries which are but a part of the landed value of the catches. This clearly has important implications. First, it is now clear that the implicit assumption in most fisheries economics models that fisheries management costs are insignificant (and can therefore be ignored) is not justified. Henceforth, when calculating optimal harvesting and investment paths one must take the management costs of implementing these paths explicitly into account. Second, these high fisheries management costs immediately raise the question of economic efficiency in the management activity. Can the same level of benefits be produced at lower costs? Judging from our comparative data on Iceland, Norway and Newfoundland, where the country with the lowest management expenditures (Iceland) is probably the one which manages its fisheries most successfully, the answer seems to be an unequivocal yes. Third, can fisheries management expenditures of the magnitude discussed be justified in the sense that the benefits exceed the costs?19 This question we cannot answer. We may point out, however, that it seems highly doubtful that the current economic rents in the fisheries of Newfoundland can justify this level of expenditure although potential rents, in a fully rationalized fishery, may well exceed current management costs. For Norway the potential rent in the fishing industry in all probability exceeds the current expenditure of roughly 10% of the value of landings, but there is limited willingness in political circles to realize that potential.20 The current rents in the Icelandic fisheries undoubtedly exceed the current 3% level of management expenditure. The discrepancy between the costs of fisheries management and the actual benefits generated by this management is, we believe, fundamentally the result of the absence of a direct link between those who benefit from the expenditures and those who pay for them. The general taxpayer has very little incentive to investigate the use of the small fraction of his tax dollar that is spent on fisheries management. This is all the more likely the higher is the number of taxpayers contributing the money. The same perverse incentives apply to members of the fishing industry. They will be happy to enjoy any perceived benefits of fisheries management without worrying about 19 This can still be the case even when the expenditures are unnecessarily high. The potential economic rent in Norway’s fisheries has been estimated at 20-30% of the value of landings, before subtracting management costs (Hannesson and Steinshamn, 1996). 20 17 excessive management expenditures as long as they do not pay for them. Fishermen are likely, however, to offer less resistance to paying for those components of fisheries management that they understand to be beneficial to themselves. In the absence of cost recovery, the resistance to spending more money on fisheries management will most likely come primarily from conscientious bureaucrats at the ministries of finance or other institutions concerned with overall public expenditure. If the fishing industry is a small part of GDP and fisheries management costs are only a small part of the overall budget that resistance is likely to be small, particularly if the industry is located in politically sensitive areas, as the case is in Newfoundland and Norway. 18 REFERENCES Andersen, P., J.G. Sutinen and K. Cochran (1998): Paying for Fisheries Management. Paper presented at the IXth Conference of the International Institute of Fisheries Economics and Trade, Tromsø, Norway, July 8-11, 1998. Anderson, L.G. (1986): The Economics of Fisheries Management. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. Anderson, L.G. and D.W. Lee (1986): Optimal Governing Instrument, Operating Level, and Enforcement in Natural Resource Regulation: The Case of the Fishery. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. August 1986, pp. 678-90. Arnason, R. (1990): A Numerical Model of the Icelandic Fisheries. In A.G. Rodrigues (Ed.): Operations Research and Management in Fishing. Kluwer. Arnason, R. (1996): Property Rights as an Organizational Framework in Fisheries: The Cases of Six Fishing Nations. In B.L. Crowley (ed.). Taking Ownership: Property Rights and Fishery Management on the Atlantic Coast. Atlantic Institute for Market Studies. 1996, pp. 99-144. Arnason, R. (1999): Costs of Fisheries Management: Theoretical and Practical Implications. Paper given at the XIth EAFE Annual Conference, Dublin, 7-10 April 1999. Arnason, R. et al. (1999): Government Expenditures on Fisheries and Fisheries Management in Iceland. In Arnason and Hannesson (1999): The Costs of Fisheries Management. Center for Fisheries Economics, The Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration (forthcoming). Atkinson, A.B. and J.E. Stiglitz. 1980. Lectures on Public Economics. McGraw-Hill N.Y. Balland, J.-M. and J.-P. Platteau (1997): Wealth Inequality and Efficiency in the Commons. Part I: The Unregulated Case. Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 49, pp. 451-482. Bjørndal, T. (1987): Production Economics and Optimal Stock Size in a North Atlantic Fishery. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 89, pp. 145-164. Clark, C.W. (1976): Mathematical Bioeconomics. Wiley, New York. Clark, C.W. and G. Munro (1975): The Economics of Fishing and Modern Capital Theory: A Simplified Approach. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol. 2, pp. 92-106. Coase, R. (1960): The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3, pp. 1-44. 19 Department of Primary Industry and Energy (DPIE, 1994): A Review of Cost Recovery for Commonwealth Fisheries. Canberra. Geen, G., A. Kingston and D. Brown (1991): Cost Recovery for Managing Fisheries. Industry Commission, Submission 91-4. Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra. Gordon, H.S. (1954): The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery. Journal of Political Economy, Vol 62, pp. 124-42. Hannesson, R. (1993): Bioeconomic Analysis of Fisheries. Fishing News Books, Oxford. Hannesson, R. and S.I. Steinshamn (1996): Grønne skatter og fiskerinæringen. SNFRapport No. 2, 1996, Stiftelsen for samfunns- og næringslivsforskning, Bergen. Hannesson, R. (1999): Management and Enforcenet Costs in Norway’s Fisheries. in Arnason and Hannesson (1999): The Costs of Fisheries Management, Center for Fisheries Economics, The Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration (forthcoming). Hatcher, A. and S. Pascoe (1998): Charging the UK Fishing Industry. Centre for the Economics and Management of Aquatic Resources, University of Portsmouth. Haynes, J., G. Geen and L. Wilks (1986): Beneficiaries of Fisheries Management. Bureau of Agricultural Economics, Discussion Paper 86-1, Canberra. Hundloe, T.J. (Commissioner, 1992): Cost Recovery for Managing Fisheries. Industry Commission, Report No. 17, 3 January 1992. Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra. Milazzo, M. (1998): Subsidies in World Fisheries. A Reexamination. World Bank Technical Paper No. 406, Washington D.C. Olafsson, S. and S.W. Wallace (eds.) (1994): Nordic Fisheries Management Model. Nord 1994:4. Placenti, V., G. Rizzo and M. Spagnolo (1992): A Bio-economic Model for the Optimization of a Multi-Species, Multi-Gear Fishery. Marine Resource Economics, Vol. 7, pp. 275-95. Plourde, C.G. (1970): A Simple Model of Replenishable Resource Exploitation. American Economic Review, Vol. 60, pp. 256-66 Roy, E. (Chairperson, 1998): Inquiry into the Government’s Fisheries Cost Recovery Regime. Report of the Primary Production Committee, Parliament of New Zealand, House of Representatives. Samuelson, P.A. 1969. Pure Theory of Public Expenditures and Taxation. In J. Margois and H. Guitton (eds.) Public Economics. St. Martins N.Y. 20 Schrank, W.E. et al. (1987): Canadian Government Financial Intervention in a Marine Fishery: The Case of Newfoundland, 1972/73 – 1980/81. Ocean Development and International Law, Vol. 18, pp. 533-584. ------ (1995): The Cost to Government of Maintaining a Commercially Unviable Fishery: The Case of Newfoundland 1981/82 to 1990/91. Ocean Development and International Law, Vol. 26, pp. 357-390. Schrank, W.E. and B. Skoda (1999): The Cost of Marine Fisheries Management in Eastern Canada: Newfoundland 1989/90 to 1997/98. Unpublished manuscript, Memorial University of Newfoundland Department of Economics. Schrank, W.E., N. Roy and E. Tsoa (1986): Employment Prospects in a Commercially Viable Newfoundland Fishery: An Application of ‘An Econometric Model of the Newfoundland Groundfishery’. Marine Resource Economics, Vol 3, pp. 237-263. Scott, A.D. (1955): The Fishery: The Objectives of Sole Ownership. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 63, pp. 116-124. Smith, V.L. (1968): Economics of Production from Natural Resources. American Economic Review, Vol. 58, pp. 409-431. Sutinen, J. and P. Andersen (1985): The Economics of Fisheries Law Enforcement. Land Economics, Vol 61, 387-97. White, D.J. (1954): The New England Fishing Industry: a Study in Price and Wage Setting. Cambridge, Mass. Harvard University Press, Westheim Fellowship. 21