Law and Culture from the Perspective of Textiles Laura F. Edwards Duke University William Cary may have been a Virginia state legislator, but he was clueless when it came to textiles. While attending the 1839 legislative session, his wife, Ophelia, wrote him regularly with explicit, pointed directions about what kinds of cloth to buy. Ophelia’s concerns were not unique. By the late-eighteenth century, women—poor women, both free and enslaved, as well as wealthy white women—had become savvy participants in the textile market, as both consumers and producers. That context explains the tone of authority that Ophelia adopted when talking to her husband about cloth. She felt confident in having him buy sheeting, which had been standardized by 1839. But she was hesitant to let him purchase satin for a dress, because that kind of fabric varied widely, and she doubted his ability to judge the quality and to bargain effectively. After scouring the stores, William sent her samples of fabric that he thought satisfactory, but which produced a flurry of worried correspondence from Ophelia about the shade (“jet black, not the blue black, which will fade more and spot”) and the price (“do try and get it at $1.25 per [yard]”). Finally, she lost patience and directed him to get “some lady to pick it.” Presumably a lady—any lady—would be more knowledgeable than her husband. As I hope to explain in my new book project, Only the Clothes on Her Back: Women, Textiles, and National Development in the United States, this anecdote provides insight into broad questions about law and national development between the Revolution and the Civil War. It is also about the scholarly conceptions of law and culture. The current historiography tends to frame analyses of law and politics in the developing nation state in terms of the property that white men could own: land, slaves, and other forms of capital. Yet most Americans did not own those forms of property. If they owned or possessed anything at all, it was textiles (both cloth and clothing). Although historians have tended to dismiss textiles as disposable goods that held little value, cloth and clothing were not only valuable, but also economically important at this time. They were also a form of property that people—even married women and the enslaved—could control, even if they could not own it legally in their own names. Their ability to control this form of property funneled those without property rights, in particular, into textile production, because they could market these kinds of goods and, if they traded for more textiles, keep the proceeds. That situation, in turn, turned textiles into a form of currency and credit. People traded for other goods with textiles. They also invested in them, because they were a reliable way to store wealth and leverage it. In fact, a whole semiunderground industry catered to those who did, with used clothing market and pawnshops providing a ready means to turn cloth into cash with no questions asked. By shifting the perspective away from the property that the minority owned to the property that the majority possessed, textiles also decenter the nation state, which did not completely control the rules of the textile trade. When women and poor men participated in the trade in cloth and clothing, they moved in legal arena that overlapped with, but that was not completely controlled by the nation state. More to the point, the textile trade reveals the juridical reach of the United States in this period as limited: the United States, as a nation state, did not yet hold a monopoly on the law, resulting in overlapping jurisdictions. Historians of empire have produced an extensive literature that explores the existence and implications of overlapping legal jurisdictions. Nineteenth-century U.S. 2 historians have not, even though there is striking evidence of this situation. There were different areas of governance within the United States—local, state, and federal. But they overlapped and even conflicted. Even the various parts of state governments did not always coordinate and ended up bumping into each other. And the authority of states was often at odds with federal authority. But legal jurisdictions also existed outside local, state, and federal government, defined through rules observed and enforced in specific cultural and, particularly, economic contexts. The claims of free women, the enslaved, and poor men to textiles were recognized as a matter of course in daily interactions in local communities and in local courts. The expectation that these people could control textiles was central to the markets in these goods. Storekeepers would never have stayed in business if they refused the trade of free women, the enslaved, and poor people. It was presumed that women could buy cloth without their husbands’ permission. Enslaved people often put what resources they had into textiles, because this kind of property was the least likely to be questioned or seized by whites. The underground market in used (and stolen) clothing was predicated on the assumption that everyone—even those without property or even property rights—had clothing. It was so commonplace to see poor people buying clothes or trading what they had for something else that no one gave it a second thought. The cultural place of clothing buttressed people’s claims to it. In property law, clothing was personal property. But clothes were personal in a more profound sense as well, linked as they were to specific individuals in ways that did not extend to other forms of property. That was why married women, enslaved people, and servants who ran away often put on stolen clothing. They were trying to hide—to be someone else. 3 Unfortunately, clothing could also betray fugitives while they were still in the area, because others were as likely to recognize the garments as the person. That situation spoke to one of the functions of the used clothing market, which was to “launder” stolen clothes that needed to be passed along quickly before they were recognized. (By launder here, I mean “launder” as a transfer meant to obscure the property’s origins, not “launder” as a process of washing a garment with soap and water to remove stains and odor.) These economic practices took place under the cover of law, even though not all of these legal practices were of the nation state. Legality came from other sources. One was the world of commerce, which had its own legal culture. To be sure, the commercial world depended on laws backed by the power of the nation state that regularized the ownership and exchange of other forms of property (and of textiles when they took the form of commodities, rather than clothing or small lots of cloth). But, as the literature from the early modern period has shown, merchants also followed rules generated of necessity and created through practice—rules that, with time and use, acquired the kind of power associated with law. In the nineteenth century U.S., those kinds of practices folded a wide range of people into networks of economic exchange that were not governed or even sanctioned by the laws of the nation state. Textile merchants and manufacturers had no choice, because their primary market was people without credit or even property rights. In its first decades, the laws of the nation state ran alongside a market in which people without property or property rights could possess and trade in cloth and clothing. Property law, as defined through state and federal jurisdictions, acknowledged the 4 existence of the other practices through which people claimed textiles. Most states’ laws, for instance, recognized women’s claims to household items that they brought into marriages, which often included textiles, as well as their claims to items of personal attire, such as clothing and jewelry. More often the recognition was tacit, expressed through a lack of action. State law remained silent when free women claimed textiles they produced as well as wore. State law was also conspicuously silent on the subject of enslaved people’s possession of clothing. The people involved in the textile were operating at the local level, but they were connected to a much wider economic network, of merchants and manufacturers, whose businesses reached across the globe, but whose interests also remained tied to local areas and the people who produced and bought textiles in there. These economic networks and legal arenas reached both geographically and juridically above and below the nation, but they were not necessarily “bigger” or “smaller” than the nation. In fact, the language of big and small suggests how dependent current scholarship is on the nation, even in the conceptualization of dynamics that are not about the nation. The literature rests on geographic hierarchies that subordinate the local (small) to the regional (big), national (bigger), and transnational or global (biggest) scales. In U.S. history, that hierarchy is grounded by the nation, which we break down into regions (North, South, West) and against which we define local areas. In U.S. history, recent work in transnational history often leaves the nation in place to look to dynamics that are bigger and, presumably, more meaningful than those within the nation. The market in textiles suggests that these hierarchies are not particularly descriptive of dynamics in the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries because the 5 juridical reach of the nation was limited. When it came to the markets in cloth and clothing, many Americans leaped from the local to the global without really having much to do with the nation state in which they lived. The people enmeshed in these networks also experienced those spaces—local, regional, national, global—differently from how that experience is imagined in conventional historiographical frameworks, which tend to characterize localities as isolated places, subordinated to national laws and global forces (both of which were bigger than and separate from localities). This is what I mean when I say that textiles reframes our understanding of the nation state’s history. It is a perspective upends some of the basic historiographical wisdom: that women and enslaved people had little experience with or relationship to property because state and federal laws limited or prohibited property ownership for them; that the place of women and poor people within the developing capitalist market was solely as exploited labor; that these people’s relationship to law and governance was primarily one of exclusion; that local areas and the people who lived there were provincial and unrepresentative of broader historical patterns; that the experiences of propertied white men are the formative and representative experiences of the nineteenthcentury United States, such that the history in this period can be told in terms of the extension of rights and privileges enjoyed by those white men to other people. Factoring in the presence of the textile market also changes our view of law and culture—if not the categories, then the relationship between then. First, what we have conceived of as “law” becomes more fragile and more contingent. What historians have seen as the growth of the nation state is actually better described as a challenge: a challenge to assert its legal authority in a context where it was not the only game in town. 6 From that perspective, it seems all the remarkable that the nation state ultimately did acquire that legal authority. Second, what we have conceived of as culture may have more to do with law than we thought. The United States, as a nation, developed in relationship to experiences with law, property, and government that Americans acquired outside the juridical purview of the nation state. When Americans did interact with the legal power of nation state, as they increasingly did in the years during and after the Civil War, they brought those experiences with. They often expressed themselves in the legal language of the nation state: the language of rights, of civic belonging, and the laws and duties of citizenship. But, as we know from recent scholarship, the content of their claims did not always match the formal definitions of terms that they used, at least not as those terms were defined within governing institutions at the state and federal levels. Americans, particularly enslaved Americans, made all kinds of substantive claims on the federal government during and immediately after the Civil War—claims that were outside the federal government’s jurisdictional scope, but that nonetheless suggest experience with property and law gained elsewhere. Americans who could not own property, for instance, had a sophisticated grasp of value and economic exchange such that they could readily translate goods and labor into abstract units—not an easy concept or set of calculations. Americans who had no rights also had a sophisticated understanding of law as a sovereign authority that should regularize economic exchange and social relations, if not produce justice. Americans of all kinds imagined lives within the juridical confines of the nation state that resembled the one that they had lived outside it: a world where they could claim their labor, possess property, and define their own destinies. When they expressed themselves, they spoke like Ophelia Cary did, in a tone 7 that was pointed and firm, one that was about issuing orders, not making requests. Other historians have documented such claims in detail and explained their presence in terms of particular cultural communities—or identity politics, as the political culture of enslaved people, of women, of laborers, or of immigrants. But this legal culture also cut across and through these different groups of people, suggesting that it had common roots. Some of those roots, as I see it, were in the whole range of dynamics opened up by that market that existed below and above the nation state—a world made visible through textiles. Those dreams and experiences were of America but not of the nation. 8