Chapter II . Impacts of Climate Change on Human and Natural Systems Professor Planck, of Berlin, the famous originator of the Quantum Theory, once remarked to me that in early life he had thought of studying economics, but had found it too difficult! Professor Planck could easily master the whole corpus of mathematical economics in a few days. He did not mean that! But the amalgam of logic and intuition and the wide knowledge of facts, most of which are not precise, which is required for economic interpretation in its highest form is, quite truly, overwhelmingly difficult. – J. M. Keynes (1933) The first act of our drama has recounted how scientists have uncovered the fact that we are changing our global climate – that the unintended actions of our daily lives as we drive our cars and heat our homes and watch our favorite TV shows have vast and long-lasting impacts on the world around us. We now turn to the second act, which is to map out the impacts upon human and non-human societies of those changes. We say that predicting future climate changes is a truly monumental task because of the complexity of the interactions among the different parts of the atmosphere-ocean-biosphere system. We now turn from the hard sciences to what might be called the “very hard sciences,” understanding and predicting how human activities as well as natural systems will respond to climate change over the coming decades and beyond. Of all the issues involved in global warming, this is the most difficult one and subject to the greatest uncertainty. Figure II-1 uses our little flow diagram to indicate where we are in the circular flow of global warming science, economics, and politics. Having described the climate system in the first chapter, we now discuss the impacts of global warming on different systems – both natural and human. I-1 Chapter 2’s coverage Rising CO2 concentrations along with other greenhouse gases lead to climate change (temperature, precipitation, sea-level rise, …) Economic activity and fossil-fuel use leads to CO2 emissions (driving, air conditioning, construction,…) Climate-change policies adopted to reduce emissions and adapt to warmer world (carbon taxes, cap-and-trade, regulations,…) Climate change imposes ecological and economic impacts (farming, coastal structures, species loss,…) Figure II-1. Schematic of coverage of Chapter 2 This chapter discusses how climate change will affect different earth and human systems. ______________________________________________ Impacts for our grandchildren It is good to begin by thinking about how the current analysis might look to you, our grandchildren, looking back on this period from several years in the future. You have read our assessment of the science in the last chapter. You might first start by asking whether we correctly understood the science – both the natural and the social science aspects. Did we miss something really important? Then, after you read this chapter on impacts, you might ask, Did we overestimate the vulnerability of ecosystems and the resilience of economic systems? You might then consider whether historical forces simply overwhelmed our efforts. Technological change may have made global warming much worse (say because someone invented a personal airplane that drinks fuel) or much better (perhaps because of some fundamental breakthrough in non-fossil energy technologies). Perhaps the horsemen of the apocalypse of famine, war, and pestilence made global warming a I-2 minor issue in the survival of humans. Or perhaps our projections proved reasonably accurate. Then, as you reach the final chapter, you can ask whether we were able to meet the challenge. Did the world’s richest country, the United States, take the first steps to slow its CO2 emissions? Or was it continually locked in partisan wrangling between warring schools of doomsters and deniers, and caught in the vice of well-funded lobbies who prevented even the smallest steps? Did China and India join the effort, or were serious policies limited to a few rich countries of northwest Europe? These are the questions that you might ask yourself as you read this assessment made in 2010. As you judge our efforts, remember that we, like people in every generation, are prisoners of our times, our cultures, our received wisdom, and even our interests. We try desperately to escape from these prisons. Did we? An Overview of Impacts Analysis Four central issues for impacts Before beginning our assessment of the impacts of climate change, we need to frame the issues. The first and central point is that concerns about climate change are all about impacts. The average mean surface temperature of the earth per se is of no intrinsic concern any more than is the temperature on the moon or Pluto. We are concerned about the effects of warming and other physical changes on physical, biological, and human systems. This central point implies that sensible policies will depend upon our assessment of the many costs, benefits, thresholds, and plateaus in the many areas that are affected by climate change. The second point is that reducing impacts of climate change will impose costs. The costs of climate-change policy reflect the fact (at least today) that reducing CO2 emissions will require using costlier technologies and therefore reduce real incomes. For example, a low carbon economy might require much more fuel-efficient cars. We can indeed improve fuel efficiency, but we will need to spend more on the car. For example, a hybrid gas-electric car might improve fuel efficiency by 10 percent, but the costs of the batteries and other systems might cost $3000. We will examine the costs in more detail in the next chapter, but the basic point is that (at least after some point) reducing emissions will require sacrificing goods and services in other areas. The third point – which is more controversial – is that sensible global warming policies will require some balancing of costs and benefits. This point is actually quite intuitive. We could stop global warming in its tracks by banning all fossil fuels today. I know of no one what advocates such a policy – both because it shares a level of wackiness with advocating shooting down UFOs, but primarily because it would be extraordinarily expensive. At the other pole, we could do nothing at all forever. Some I-3 people actually do appear to take this position, but that proposal appears to me to extremely myopic or disingenuous. So policies must lie somewhere between wrecking the economy and wrecking the world. I will discuss some ideas about how to balance the objectives of economics and the environment in the next chapter, but the basic point is that some kind of balancing is required. The final question is whether, after a careful weighing of objectives, a firm target for policy emerges. I call this a “focal policy” because it is a policy that is obvious or consensual. Most people would agree on focal policies such as no AIDS, no smallpox, no financial collapses, no nuclear meltdowns, and no nuclear wars. For climate change, there is a great temptation to create focal policy targets as well because that tremendously simplifies analysis and policy. Setting a firm target would be sensible if there is a threshold beyond which all sort of dangerous effects appear. Indeed, our review of tipping points in the last chapter suggested that the many serious tipping points would potentially be encountered when global temperature passes 3 °C. As we will see in the next section, there has been a serious attempt to establish a focal policy for global warming at 2 °C. The next chapter will examine whether such focal policies have a good analytical basis. Current approaches to targets Scientists and nations have been struggling to understand the dangers of unchecked climate change for several years. Where do we stand as of 2010? Here is a very brief summary. The framework for all climate change deliberations is the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, ratified in 1994. The objective was stated as follows: “The ultimate objective … is to achieve … stabilization of greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere at a level that would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system.” This lofty goal is unfortunately extremely vague, because there is no definition or way to determine what would be a “dangerous anthropogenic interference.” Over recent years, scientists have refined this concept. In the first set of international agreements, in Kyoto in 1997, countries agreed on climate policies but not on any recognizable objectives. They agreed to cut emissions but had no target for climate change or even for long-run goal for emissions reductions in the agreement. Take a time ship forward for 13 years to the meeting in Copenhagen in December 2009. This meeting failed to agree upon policies extending the Kyoto Protocol. But it did adopt a target for climate policy. In the Copenhagen Accord, countries recognized “the scientific view that the increase in global temperature should be below 2 degrees Celsius.” [1] This was the first time that any policy target had been established at an international level, and in this respect it is a major advance. Was the 2 °C target based on a strong body of evidence that suggests that there is a threshold at 2 °C? Is there I-4 strong evidence that there would be “dangerous” or at least serious consequences if the earth’s climate system passes this threshold? Was there an attempt to balance the dangers with the costs? These will be among the important question addressed in the chapters that follow. The Economic Fundamentals Global Warming as an Externality Before plunging into a discussion of different impacts, I begin with some fundamentals of the economics of climate change. The economics of climate change is straightforward. Virtually everything we do directly or indirectly involves the combustion of fossil fuels, producing emissions of CO2 into the atmosphere. The carbon dioxide accumulates over many decades and leads to many potentially harmful impacts. But those who produce the emissions do not pay for the privilege, and those who are harmed are not compensated. Unlike the pain and benefits of a market activity like producing and enjoying a slice of pizza, the costs and benefits are external to the market. They are therefore called “externalities”—i. e., interactions whose values are not reflected in market transactions. Economic life is full of externalities. Some are harmful, such as when someone dumps garbage on your lawn; others are beneficial, such as when a researcher discovers a polio vaccine. But global warming is the monster of all externalities because it involves so many activities, affects the entire globe, and does so for so many decades and even potentially centuries. Economics teaches one major lesson about externalities: Markets generally operate inefficiently in the presence of externalities. In the case of harmful externalities like pollution, markets will produce too much. There is no invisible hand that will correct these market failures. Governments must step in and regulate or tax the activity. (Recall the dashed arrow in Figure II-1, which represents a non-market or non-natural intervention.) Global warming is no different from other externalities; it requires affirmative governmental actions to prevent the harmful spillovers. However, there is one respect in which global warming differs from externalities like water pollution or toxic wastes or drunk driving. It is a long-lived (or stock) global externality, one whose impacts are indivisibly spread around the entire globe for long periods of time. These features of global warming will occupy us in the next chapter when we consider the politics of dealing with global warming. The ABCs of impact studies The central question we need to deal with in thinking about policies to deal with global warming is, What damaging consequences might occur if global warming continues unchecked? It will be useful to describe how scientists undertake impact studies. The methodology of impact studies is straightforward and comes in three steps: I-5 A) First, we draw upon the modeling projections from the climate scientists to calculate the impact of global warming for a particular time, place, and sector on variables such as temperature, precipitation, sea level, and so forth. B) Second, we estimate an “impact multiplier” that indicates how much that sector-time-place would be affected for every unit of climate change. C) Finally, we need to estimate the size of the sector in the target year. The total impact is then the product of A x B x C. We then take the product of the change in the climate times the impact multiplier times the size of the sector, and that yields the total impact for a given time-place-sector. ABCs for agriculture in Africa We can illustrate the ABC methodology using one of the most carefully studied sectors, agriculture. For this example, we rely on a compilation of studies by the IPCC. Studies tend to concentrate on a scenario with 4 °C local temperature change. We take this scenario and apply it to low-latitude regions such as sub-Saharan Africa and use wheat as the crop. Let’s go through the ABCs of this example. A’) Start with a set of climate models that has a good track record and have detailed regional resolution. According to climate model calculations, the mean temperature increase for low-latitudes (which we use for sub-Saharan Africa) is very close to that for the world as a whole. The 4 °C increase is estimated to occur around 2120 in the Yale-RICE model. B’) According to the IPCC compilation, the yield for wheat in low latitudes is nonlinear, but is estimated to decline by 18 percent when the local temperature increase is 4 °C. (You can look at the graph from which this is drawn discussed later in the chapter as Figure II-9.) C’) We then finally need to estimate the output of wheat in 2120. The requires estimates of African GDP, the share of agriculture in GDP, and the share of wheat in agriculture. A rough estimate yields total production of wheat of $260 billion in 2120 in 2005 U.S. dollars. Applying the ABC methodology, we estimate that global warming with cause a decline in African wheat production of $47 billion in 2120. [2] Using historical trends, this would imply a loss of about 0.07 percent of GDP for Africa from wheat yield declines at a 4 °C warming. This represents an infinitesimal decrease in the average growth rate for Africa over this period – a decline of 0.0007 percent per year in the average growth rate. This would compare with an assumed growth in per capita consumption of 3.5 percent per year over the period. [3] Your first reaction to this example is probably that this is an absurd exercise. How can we possibly know the growth of African GDP, the share of agriculture, the I-6 share of wheat in agriculture in 110 years? Should we not also note that the studies predict anything from a yield decline of 60 percent to a yield increase of 30 percent? Perhaps you might ask, Why not focus on something a little closer at hand, perhaps 2030 or 2050? Fair enough. If we take 2050, models suggest that unchecked emissions will lead to about 2 °C warming. If we consult our studies shown in Figure II9, we see that the average of the studies suggests that African wheat yields including the CO2 effect will actually improve by about 5 percent. This example is useful for a number of points. First, it illustrates the ABC model of impacts. Second, it also shows the long chain of reasoning that is involved in calculating impacts. Third, it illustrates how uncertain impacts can be and that we may not even know whether impacts are positive or negative for some sectors. [4] You might be tempted to throw up your hands at this stage and simply say, “Let’s stop here. Just stipulate that the impacts are terrible and figure out a way to stop all this madness. With all the uncertainties and tipping points and potential problems, we don’t need any of these dubious economist’s exercises. Just say no.” There are two problems with this reaction. First, someone might say, “I think you are being hysterical. These problems are way in the future. We can handle them the way we have handled other problems such as polio and horse manure and the ozone hole. Just wait a few years and technologies will solve the problem.” Without some serious rebuttal to this argument, it is like two people arguing about whether aliens are a risk to our life style. Second, and more serious, is that we still have to choose how much to slow global warming. As we noted above, there is a long distance between the pole of doing nothing and the pole of abolishing fossil fuel use immediately. As long as we need to balance costs and benefits, we need to have a rough idea of what the benefits of slower warming are. And that is the point of impact studies. Three Central Issues for Impacts Analysis The ABC model is a useful template for studying the impacts of climate change. However, before investigating the overall results of impact studies, we should step back and consider the landscape. In doing this analysis, three overarching issues emerge. The first is that climate damages are closely linked to economic growth. But this point then raises a deeper issue: If the different economies do indeed evolve and grow rapidly over the coming decades, how can we possibly forecast the economic structures a century or more from now? As a third point, I propose a strategy for thinking about long-term impacts, which is the distinction between managed systems (such as the economy) and unmanaged systems (such as natural ecosystems). I will conclude that our major longterm focus should be on those impacts that are intrinsically unmanaged or unmanageable. I-7 Climate change damages from economic growth Economic studies indicate that the severity of damages will depend critically on economic growth over the next century and beyond. The following table will illustrate the point. [5] This shows two alternative future trajectories calculated from the YaleRICE model with no climate change policies. The “standard” scenario is the one used to make the central calculations of climate change and the one we will focus on in this chapter. For the standard run, we see that per capita consumption grows sharply over the coming decades. The average annual per capita growth rate is 1.7 percent per year for the 21st century and 0.9 percent per year for the 22nd century. By the end of this period, global per capita consumption is almost three times the current level for the United States. The rapid growth with no climate-change policies lead to rapid changes in global temperatures. These growth projections are standard to integrated economicclimate models. [6] Now compare the standard trajectory with the “no-growth” trajectory. In this case, we assume that there is no further improvement in overall productivity – no growth in “total factor productivity,” to use the economist’s technical language. This means in effect that there would be no improvements in computers, in telecommunications, in Internet speed, in health care, or in other areas where we have witnessed rapid growth in recent decades. The future in the no-growth projection is dramatically different. There is virtually no growth in average consumption – it averages 0.07 percent per year over the entire period. But climate change is also very small. Global mean temperature rises to between 2 and 2 ½ degrees. Most climate specialists would probably be comfortable with the trajectory of the no-growth scenario. Finally, examine the damages shown in the last three rows of Table II-1. These damage estimates are drawn from different impact studies that we will review later. For the moment, take these as illustrative for this discussion. In the standard run, with both high output and a large temperature change, the damages are very substantial. By contrast, in the no-growth scenario, the damages are very small. So a first important point is that the climate problem arises largely in association with rapid economic growth. But this also means that we will on average be richer in the future and will be better able to afford steps to slow climate change. And while the climate damages may be a substantial percent of output, consumption-with-growthwith-damages in 2100 or 2200 will be much larger than consumption-without-growthwith-damages in 2100 or 2200. The fact that our living standards are likely to be much higher is no excuse for doing nothing today, but it is also a reminder that we are bequeathing a much more productive economy along with a degraded climate. If you compare the per capita consumption in 2100 or 2200 in the two economic scenarios, it would take an enormous amount of climate damage to offset the fruits of technological change. I-8 Economic scenario Per capita consumption (2005 $) 2005 2100 2200 Standard No-growth 7,000 36,200 90,300 7,000 7,500 8,100 0.73 3.27 5.32 0.73 2.19 2.45 -0.6 17.2 193.4 -0.6 0.2 0.8 Global mean temperature (°C) 2005 2100 2200 Damages from climate change (trillions of 2005 $) 2005 2100 2200 Table II-1. Economic growth and climate damages ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Should we conclude from this example that our problem is too much economic growth? That we should aim for zero economic growth? Few people today draw this conclusion. [7] It is like tossing out a bag of groceries because the milk is sour. The appropriate conclusion, economists suggest, is to fix the market failure by repairing the flawed economic externality involved in climate change. Throw out the sour milk and fix the faulty refrigerator. Exactly how we will do this is discussed in the third chapter. Managed versus unmanaged systems The central distinction we should focus on in analyzing the impacts of climate change is the difference between managed and unmanaged systems. The idea of “management” originates in the science of ecology but can be more generally applied. A managed system is one that can adapt to shocks through interventions. On a geological scale, the management might be migration, selection, or other kinds of changes that reduce or mitigate the impact of the shock. On the time scale that we are considering, most management occurs through human interventions. For example, a farmer may introduce an irrigation system to optimize the soil moisture for wheat production. By contract, an unmanaged system is one that is largely free from human intervention. It might be unmanaged because humans choose to leave it alone (as with a wildlife reserve) or because it is unmanageable because the process is too large for humans to control (as with the tides or violent storms). I-9 If we move to the subject of this discussion, we can see the role of management in the impact of climate change. Indoor living is an example of a managed system. With the use of well-designed and engineered structures, equipment, and monitoring devices, humans have modified their indoor structures so that they can live in virtually every environment from Antarctica to the tropics to outer space. By contrast, walking outside without any clothing is a good example of an unmanaged system. The fact is that humans could not long survive in most parts of the globe if they were forced to live outdoors without the management of clothes or shelter. Another example – particularly important for the impacts of global warming – is the distinction between managed and unmanaged ecosystems. An ecosystem is a system of living plants and animals along with the physical environment in which they interact. One of the most important ecosystems for humans is agriculture. Some parts of agriculture are heavily managed. For example, hydroponics is a method of growing plants using water and nutrients without soil. Some hydroponic establishments are essentially food factories. They can easily survive heat, drought, and hail. At the other extreme is the food system of hunting and gathering cultures, such as were practiced by virtually all humans until about 10,000 years ago. These techniques are highly dependent upon climatic patterns. The main way that management entered the picture was through mismanagement from deforestation or overfishing and overhunting. Human history is full of civilizations that declined or disappeared because they depended upon unmanaged food supplies that dried up with drought or cold periods. A particularly thrilling account of how past societies declined is in Jared Diamond’s Collapse. [8] He recounts the perils of deforestation, soil erosion, water mismanagement, overhunting, and overfishing by Greenland Norse, Easter Islanders, the Polynesians of Pitcairn Island, the Anasazi of southwestern North America, and the Maya of Central America. He emphasizes the role of mismanagement, but we might also understand the decline as coming from narrowly based economic structures heavily dependent on unmanaged systems. In other words, when most economic activity is involved in hunting and gathering food, and the food supply dries up because of the interaction of climate change and human activities, there is little resilience and the society must migrate, decline, or perish. There are multiple strategies by which living organisms or societies can manage themselves to increase their resilience in the face of environmental shocks. One mechanism is migration, by which birds and mobile animals can follow food supplies. Another mechanism, of which humans are particularly fond, is building structures to warm or cool themselves, shelter themselves against storms, and make devices to further increase management of their environment. Most species have not survived all the shocks during the 4 billion years of life on Earth, but it is remarkable how adaptive I-10 strategies have allowed so many species to survive periods from hothouse periods to snowball earth. We need to be careful to distinguish unmanaged systems from unmanageable ones. Hurricanes are currently unmanaged in part because they are unmanageable, but in the future, as technologies improve, countries might attempt to weaken hurricanes or throw them off a deadly track. Indeed, Microsoft chief Bill Gates actually filed a patent application in 2008 for a technique to reduce hurricane intensity. Similarly, sea level rise, which appears to be one of the most secure results of climate change, might be managed by cloud seeding or even by some fantastic device that pumps water back onto the top of Antarctica. In the extreme, some have proposed “geoengineering” approaches that would offset the warming by increasing the reflectivity of the earth. We will examine the potential of such approaches in the next part. In the long span of economic history, the trend for human societies has evolved from depending on largely unmanaged ecosystems to a highly managed economy. This point is seen in the declining share over time and with economic development of agriculture, which is probably the least managed major sector of the economy (we turn to this point below). Even within agriculture, forestry, and fisheries, economies have increasingly moved to manage these sectors with the use of fertilizers and irrigation in food production, fish farming for fisheries, forest management techniques in forestry, and recycling for wood and other products. Many people resist farmed fish, nonrecycled paper, and genetically modified organisms, but these technologies are in part a reaction to the vicissitudes of unmanaged systems. From the point of view of human welfare, perhaps the most important example of managing human affairs is the rise of modern medicine. Even as late as two centuries ago, illness and death were often thought to be visited upon people by evil spirits or the gods, and if a child died at an early age, there were several more waiting to sit at the table. Today, health care is the largest single sector of the economy, comprising 16 percent of total output. While most of our bodies are “natural” in the sense that they are driven by complex biological mechanisms, in a century we may find that even our bodies are increasingly made up of manufactured parts. All this sounds like some horrible science fiction story, but if you imagine how the modern world would look to a time traveler from 5,000 years ago, you can get an intuitive feel of how foreign managed human societies may appear in a century or more. Why is the distinction between managed and unmanaged systems important for our topic? The reason is that it helps identify those areas where climate change is of greatest concern and those areas where adaptive forces are likely to work to mitigate climate-change damages. I-11 Heavily managed systems Most economic sectors Manufacturing Services Health care Energy production Most of human activities Watching TV Surfing the Internet Having a baby Partly managed systems Vulnerable economic sectors Agriculture Construction Transportation Forestry Non-market activities Beaches and coastal ecosystems Wildfires Water systems Unmanaged or unmanageable systems Hurricanes Sea-level rise Wildlife Ocean acidification Table II-2. Selection of managed and unmanaged systems ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Table II-3 provides a list of major activities and sectors, dividing them into heavily managed, lightly managed, and unmanaged or unmanageable. [9] We see that most of the economy is in the heavily managed sector; these activities are likely to be relatively little directly affected by climate change. At the other end of the spectrum are activities that are with current technologies and practices unmanaged or unmanageable. These are the areas where we need to focus our attention in considering the harmful impacts of climate change. I-12 Other times, other places, other customs The last section, with its closing reflections on the science fictional nature of human futures, is a warning about the most profound difficulty in undertaking impacts analysis. This difficulty is the need to project (or to imagine) the social, economic, and ecological structures in the distant future. Recall that scenarios with the largest climatic changes also involve rapid economic growth. This means that to estimate the impact of a 3 °C warming requires imposing our estimated impacts upon a society that has evolved for almost a century. To grasp the difficulty of this task, we can recall the changes that have taken place over the last century. Go back to 1910. In that year, Europe was under the thumb of three defunct empires, the Ottoman, Czarist, and Austrian empires. The United States had no central bank, no income tax, and no votes for women or blacks. The nuclear model of the atom had not yet been discovered, and people had no idea of how traits were transmitted from parents to children. The most advanced computational device was the Monroe Calculator, which could operate about 3 operations per second as compared to a current workstation which can operate around 1 trillion times faster. Our economic statistics suggest that output per hour worked has grown by factor of 10 over the last century, but that undoubtedly underestimates the changes because of the introduction of new and improved products and unmeasured health improvements. Now perform the experiment of trying to project the impact of global warming on the world in 2110. In some areas, where we are relying primarily on fundamental physical laws, we can be reasonably confident about our estimates. For example, if we are confident about our temperature projection, then the sea-level rise due to thermal expansion of the oceans is relatively (emphasis on the world relatively) straightforward. And in fact we see good agreement among physical models about this impact. [10] At the other end of the spectrum are potential impacts that are so contingent of future economic and social structures that projections are necessarily extremely tenuous. One example, which features prominently in many gloomy scenarios, is “environmental migration.” One report projects that “unless strong preventative action is taken, between now and 2050 climate change will push the number of displaced people globally to at least 1 billion.” [11] A report on national security and climate change quotes a high military strategist, “More poverty, more forced migrations, higher unemployment. Those conditions are ripe for extremists and terrorists.” [12] In reality, there has been almost no research on the impact of global warming on human migrations. Consider some of the issues if we were doing such a projection for 2100. We would need to have a reasonable description of national boundaries, populations, and per capita incomes of major countries. What would be the boundary of the European Union? Would there even be a European Union? Would people be more or less inclined to migrate? Are they more or less attached to their families, communities, and cultures? Would transportation costs be much lower, perhaps with I-13 personal aircraft that could zip across borders in a flash? In addition, we would need to understand immigration policies along with the technologies for enforcing these policies. Would the southern borders of the US and the future EU be more or less porous than today? What kind of personal identification systems would be available? Would electronic detection and monitoring be so advanced, with advanced hybrid road-air-water robots patrolling the borders, that even a coyote would hesitate to cross? Perhaps we could take a stab at answering these questions and making projections of migration (although I doubt it would be accurate). But our job would be only half-done. We would then need to measure the impact of global warming on the incomes of countries, and measure the impact of the income changes on migration changes. To be realistic, we could probably make an estimate of the impact of global warming on today’s world, incomes, borders, and technologies. But these are likely to change so dramatically over the coming century that it would be foolish to suppose that we could make an accurate projection of global warming on migration for more than a few years. The point about environmental migration is an example of the more general point about the role of impacts to climate change in managed systems. Human societies and economies are heavily managed systems. If climate change increases air pollution or exposure to heat waves or migration, we would expect that societies would take steps to reduce vulnerabilities through tighter pollution regulations and air conditioning and immigration policies. Moreover, if countries continue to improve technologies and living standards, we would expect that poor countries (who can today barely afford such investments) will increasingly be able to protect themselves and become “climate-proofed” the way Minneapolis or Phoenix are today. While there is no law of nature or economics that proves that historical trends will continue, it seems likely that the poorer countries will follow the paths of protecting their peoples and societies from environmental extremes in the way rich countries have. Not exactly the same way, with better technologies, with local customs and traditions, and perhaps with fewer mistakes. The lesson is that we are likely to overestimate the economic impacts of climate change if we simply take our estimated changes and impose them on current societies, particularly for the heavily managed parts of our societies. I-14 Perspectives on Vulnerability Vulnerability by economic sector It will be useful to examine the extent of vulnerability for different sectors of the economy. For this purpose, we can examine the national economic accounts by detailed industry for the United States for the period 1948-2007. The industrial composition of the U.S. is representative of high-income countries today. It is likely to be representative of the structure of middle-income countries in the middle or end of this century. For this purpose, we classify industries into three groups: heavily impacted sectors, moderately impacted sectors, and lightly or negligibly impacted sectors. Detailed studies on impacts indicate that the heavily affected or vulnerable sectors are likely to be agriculture and forestry. These are sectors where productivity might be affected by more than 20 percent in extreme scenarios. A second group of industries are ones that are affected by weather and climate, but can adapt at modest costs. An example here is the transportation industry. Extreme weather (such as snow or heat) can cause delays and impose costs, but the costs are likely to be relatively small, less than 10 percent for most climate scenarios. A third group of industries are ones that are likely to be directly affected little or not at all by climate change. An example of an industry that is negligibly affected is neurosurgery. Consultations and operations take place in highly controlled environments, in all climates, and variations of the kind envisioned are unlikely to have a measurable effect on this activity. Table II-4 shows an estimate of the vulnerability of the U.S. economy over the last six decades. [13] The results are striking. To begin with, the share of the heavily impacted sectors today is very small – roughly 1 percent of the economy. The moderately impacted sectors constitute about one-tenth of the economy, with the major affected sectors being coastal real estate, transportation, construction, and utilities. These estimates are probably exaggerated because some parts of the heavily or moderately affected sectors are likely to be insensitive to climate change. The group of lightly affected sectors comprises most of the economy, rising from 79 to 89 percent of the total market economy. I-15 Share of total national income in sector Sector by impact 1948 1973 2007 Heavily impacted sectors 9.3 3.9 1.1 Farming Forestry, fishing 8.2 3.4 0.8 1.1 0.6 0.2 Moderately impacted sectors 11.7 11.1 9.7 Real estate (coastal) Transportation Construction Utilities 0.2 0.2 0.3 6.0 3.9 2.9 4.2 5.0 4.4 1.4 2.0 2.0 79.1 85.0 89.3 4.9 6.9 8.5 2.8 1.4 2.0 13.3 13.4 6.7 12.7 8.5 5.0 6.4 6.7 5.8 9.0 7.8 6.5 0.1 0.2 0.3 2.6 3.4 4.2 2.4 4.0 7.9 0.6 0.8 1.0 18.1 24.2 37.2 11.1 14.6 12.6 100.0 100.0 100.0 Lightly or negligibly impacted sectors Real estate (non-coastal) Mining Manufacturing Durable goods Nondurable goods Wholesale trade Retail trade Warehousing and storage Information Finance and insurance Rental and leasing services Services and residual Government TOTAL Table II-3. Vulnerability of the U.S. Economy by sector, 1948-2007 ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― The second striking feature of the sectoral data is the sharp decline in the most vulnerable sectors. The share of the heavily impacted sectors has declined from around 9 percent of the economy in 1948 to around 1 percent today. This trend is largely due to the declining share of agriculture. The share of the workforce in agriculture is similarly declining, with the share of workers in farming being only 1 percent in 2008. I-16 The declining share of agriculture is seen around the world, not just in the United States. Figure II-4 shows trends in the share of agriculture for major countries since 1965. [14] The downward trend is most striking in Asia, which shows how rapid economic growth drives people off the farm and into industrial cities. The five countries with the largest share of their output in agriculture in 1970 had declines in that share by almost half in the next 35 years. 50 45 High income East Asia Latin America South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa Share of agriculture in GDP (%) 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Figure II-2. Share of agriculture in major groupings of countries, 1965-2008 ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― What is the point here? If countries do show the rapid growth in output and emissions found in the standard projections, then market economies will generally become increasingly less vulnerable to climate change. This pattern is not inevitable, but the pattern is so pervasive and striking across time and space that it seems one of the central findings of the economics of climate change. I-17 Evidence from time-use surveys The results on the sectoral distribution of national output is deficient because it omits non-market activities. These include environmental services, pollution, health status, home production, leisure time, and many other valuable human activities. While the need to supplement the standard economic accounts with non-market sectors has been discussed for decades, little progress has been made in developing comprehensive accounts. One interesting approach that provides a perspective on non-market activity is the way a population uses its time. Time is the ultimate resource, forever limited to 24 hours per day. We will consider the case of the United States, which has very detailed time-use data. We can use the time metric as another way of examining the climatesensitivity of human activities. The basic idea is the following. Suppose that a person spends a great deal of leisure time in outdoor recreational activities – perhaps skiing in the winter, birdwatching in the spring, and scuba diving in the summer. With a changing climate, these activities might well be disrupted because the snow line changes, bird migration patterns are disrupted, and coral reefs dissolve. If this were the case, we would observe a great deal of the time spend in activities that are climate sensitive, and these hours would be greatly disrupted by climate change. To examine this question, I looked at the American Time Use Survey for the year 2007. This covers all civilian adults, whether or not they are in the labor force. I then classified time use into three categories, similar to those in Table 2. For example, I assume that spiritual activities and writing emails are unaffected by climate; that travel and attending meetings are moderately affected; and that working in agriculture, gardening, and engaged in outdoor sports potentially significantly affected. The categorization is subject to alternative judgments but the results are so striking that they are unlikely to be significantly changed by alternative assumptions. Table II-5 shows the results of this exercise. The life style of the statistically average American appears to be at the other extreme from the skier-birdwatcher-scuba diver example. The numbers are very similar to the sectoral breakdown of economic activity in the last Table. A little more than 1 percent of time use is significantly affected by climate (for example, outdoor sports), while another 8 percent is potentially moderately affected. However, most activities take place indoors and are unlikely to be severely stressed by climate change – examples here are sleeping, answering emails, and watching TV. Most of our time use and daily life is largely unaffected by climate. With the exception of a few outdoor activities – such as golfing, skiing, and farming – our lives are spent indoors in our houses or in malls or in businesses that are largely climate controlled environments. [15] I-18 Perhaps Americans will change their ways and start sleeping under the stars, eating their meals in the park, praying on the mountain-top, and surfing the web at the beach. Until that point, human activities appear be relatively insensitive to climatic influences. Activity Average hours per day, civilian population Heavily impacted sectors 0.35 Lawn and garden care 0.21 Exterior maintenance, repair, and decoration 0.06 1.90 Moderately impacted sectors Work in moderately affected sector 0.35 Travel related to purchasing goods and services 0.28 Recreation in outdoor activity 0.18 Lightly or negligibly impacted sectors 21.76 Sleeping 8.57 Watching TV 2.62 Religious and spiritual activities 0.15 24.00 TOTAL Table II-4. Distribution of time use of Americans, 2007, with illustrative examples of each category. ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Four major areas of concern We described above a useful way to separate areas of major concern in terms of whether the systems under consideration were managed or unmanaged. We listed four areas that were ones that appeared on the unmanaged end of the spectrum, and we discuss each of those briefly in this section. The four are sea-level rise and coastal systems, wildlife and species preservation, hurricanes, and ocean acidification. These are not the only important areas, but they illustrate some of the areas where global warming may prove particularly damaging and where and potential adaptations may be difficult to achieve. I-19 Sea-level rise and coastal systems One of the major concerns over coming decades and centuries is the impact of sea-level rise on coastal systems and human settlements near the coast. We begin with the scientific background and projections and then discuss the potential impacts. Sea-level rise (SLR) has two major components: thermal expansion and melting of terrestrial icecaps. Water density is a function of temperature, salinity, and pressure, but the relationships are highly non-linear. On average, as the oceans warm, they will expand, thereby raising sea level. This part of SLR is well-understood and can be carefully modeled. Current estimates indicate that for the A1B scenario (which is closest to the estimates of integrated assessment models discussed in the last chapter [16]), thermal expansion will raise the oceans by about 0.20 meters (8 inches) by 2100. This is only slightly more rapid than the rate of SLR over the last century. [17] The other major component of SLR is melting ice from glaciers and icecaps. What frightens scientists here is the vast quantity of water locked up in icecaps. There are three major areas that scientists have examined. The first is the Greenland Ice Sheet, or GIS, which has about 7 meters of SLR-equivalent of ice. (This means that if the GIS were to melt completely, sea level would rise about 7 meters, or 22 feet.) A second area of concern is the West Antarctic Ice Sheet (WAIS), which has ice with a SLR-equivalent of about 5 meters. The balance of the Antarctic Ice Sheet has a much larger quantity of ice, but this area is so cold that there seems little risk of melting for at least 1000 years. Modeling icecaps is extremely complex, and most models do not make projections beyond 2100. The last round of estimates projected a range of SLR from melting glaciers and icecaps between 0.04 and 0.20 meters by 2100. So at the outside, land ice might contribute as much as thermal expansion. It must be emphasized, however, that this is a very active area of scientific research, and we must be prepared for “inevitable surprises” in the future. [18] We have used the Yale-RICE model to make very rough projections of climate change for different scenarios over the coming centuries. The model includes all sources of SLR, not just thermal expansion, although the dynamics of the icecaps are very uncertain. The projections are consistent with standard ocean-climate models but additionally are linked to the economic and emissions models. For this exercise, we have compared two different emissions trajectories. One is unconstrained emissions, in which countries take no policies to reduce emissions, and most fossil resources are used. We also showed the results of this scenario in the last chapter. The second represents a very ambitious target such as the one set in the Copenhagen Accord mentioned at the beginning of this chapter. This second scenario limits global mean temperature to 2 °C over 1900 averages. Figure II-5 shows the SLR projections for the two scenarios. [?? Mislabeled. need to redo fig.] The top half shows the two scenarios along with the comparable estimates I-20 from the IPCC report. Note that the Yale-RICE model has significantly higher estimates of SLR than the last round of IPCC projections. This result arises because the Yale-RICE model uses parameter estimates that suggest more rapid responses of ice sheets. A second point seen in the top graph is that the difference between an aggressive and an uncontrolled path is relatively small over the first few decades. This closeness of the control and no-control lines shows the tremendous inertia in the earth system, which is one of the recurrent themes of climate change. The bottom half of the figure shows projections for 1000 years. It should be emphasized that these are highly uncertain because of difficulties of modeling the response of the icecaps, but they are consistent with current model estimates. [19] These projections are very sobering. They indicate that even with extremely ambitious climate policies there will be substantial SLR over the coming centuries. The model suggests that limiting climate change to 2 °C will still lead to around 2 meters (6+ feet) of eventual SLR. However, the model suggests that an uncontrolled climate system will lead to SLR of more than 10 meters over the next millennium. This upper-end result is produced by a combination of more thermal expansion and substantial melting of the Greenland Ice Sheet and discharge from the West Antarctic Ice Sheet. While these projections are not part of the scientific consensus, they are consistent with some of the gloomy projections of several climate scientists. [20] I-21 0.80 Unconstrained Limit T < 2 °C 0.70 IPCC: B2 Sea-level rise (meters) 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 2000 2020 2040 2060 2080 2100 14 Unconstrained 12 Sea-level rise (meters) Limit T < 2 °C 10 8 6 4 2 0 2000 2100 2200 2300 2400 2500 2600 2700 2800 2900 3000 Figure II-3. Projected sea-level rise for uncontrolled and temperature-limit scenarios Figure at top compares our sea-level rise projections with those of IPCC models of roughly the same temperature trajectory over the next century. Bottom panel shows much more speculative projection over the coming millennium. Note that even in the case of strong climate-change policies, there will be substantial rise. [21] ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― I-22 What are the potential impacts of SLR over the coming century (perhaps ½ meter) or over the longer term (up to 10 meters)? On a geological time scale, sea level has risen and fallen by even more than this. At the height of the last ice age, the ocean was approximately 130 meters lower than today. This was the (very cold!) time when humans migrated across a land bridge between Asia and the Americas. In earlier periods, when glaciers were largely absent, sea level was much higher, perhaps 200 meters higher in the age of the dinosaurs. However, the pace of SLR over the coming century and beyond is unprecedented during the period of human civilizations. Ecologists are particularly concerned about the impact of the rising ocean as it interacts with human settlements. I will concentrate here, however, on the economic dimensions. We can first examine the total population, output, and land area of the globe at risk from sea-level rise. Figure II-6 shows the cumulative total for these three important magnitudes. This indicates that approximately 4 percent of 2005 population and output are in regions that have elevation at or below 10 meters. This is significantly more than the land area at risk, which is about 1 percent, because people and economic activity tend to cluster near coastlines. [22] .05 Population Share of global total .04 Output .03 .02 .01 Area .00 0 2 4 6 8 10 Less than elevation of (meters) Figure II-4. Share of global totals at or below different elevations ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― We might care about the global total if people, output, nations, and ecosystems could migrate freely around the world. However, most people are relatively immobile I-23 in the short run, although there is much mobility in the longer run. We should also examine, therefore, the distribution of human settlements in the “red zone” below 10 meters. Table II-6 shows countries at risk. For this tabulation, we rely on the Yale GEcon data base, which has developed a data set on area, population, and output for the entire globe. [23]This metric considers the fraction of the 2005 population that is at or below 10 meters of elevation. The top part of the table shows the 10 countries that are most at risk for sea-level rise. These countries have more than half of population and output at risk. The most at-risk countries are relatively small, but there are two populous countries on the list, the Netherlands and Bangladesh. The bottom part shows the 10 most populous countries and data on the fraction of population, output, and area at risk. Aside from Bangladesh, most countries have less than 10 percent of population and output at risk. However, the three most populous countries have between 5 and 10 percent of populations living in the long-run red zone. Sea-level rise is one of the most worrisome impacts of climate change because it has such important effects and because it is difficult to stop once it is underway. While the loss of land may be small, often the land is among the most precious parts of our natural and human heritage. However, we must also caution that there are steps that societies can take to reduce the damages. A good example is whether to “retreat or defend” against the rising seas. Defending often takes the form of building dikes and sea walls to protect existing structures and towns. This is the strategy that the Netherlands has taken for centuries. In some cases, a strategy of retreat is a sensible long-run strategy. It is prudent and not defeatist. This is in fact the strategy that nature has adapted to the long-run changes in sea level over geological time. It is easy to overlook the fact that waterfront properties do not disappear with sea-level rise; the location just moves. [24] Alas, this is little comfort for property owners who find their property values destroyed and their inland neighbor getting a windfall. But over a period of decades and more, allowing natural processes to shift sand, beaches, ponds, and dunes is likely to protect the overall value of land and ecosystems much better than the propensity to adopt a Maginot Line mentality and protect every parcel. This is yet another example of the great value of migration – of people, capital, and in this case sand and ecosystems – in reducing the long-run costs of climate change. I-24 Fraction at risk: Country Most at-risk countries Bahamas Maldives Bahrain Kiribati Netherlands Tonga Gambia Bangladesh Kuwait Guinea Bissau Most populous countries China India United States Indonesia Brazil Pakistan Bangladesh Russia Nigeria Japan Mexico Population, 2005 Output, 2005 Total population, Area 2005 (000) 100.0 100.0 91.9 91.8 74.9 69.0 63.2 60.1 48.8 48.2 100.0 100.0 60.3 91.2 76.9 58.1 62.9 58.0 9.5 48.2 100.0 100.0 65.9 9.0 76.3 17.5 30.5 50.6 7.8 29.2 323 295 725 99 16,320 99 1,617 153,281 2,535 1,597 9.0 7.3 6.1 2.8 2.9 6.8 60.1 1.8 3.7 0.0 3.2 14.4 7.2 5.9 3.6 1.7 3.5 58.0 1.0 12.9 0.0 2.9 1.8 2.8 2.9 7.5 1.4 2.4 50.6 2.4 2.3 0.0 3.3 1,304,500 1,094,583 296,507 220,558 186,849 155,772 153,281 143,150 141,356 127,773 103,089 Table II-5. Countries at risk from sea-level rise Table shows the fraction of 2005 population and output as well as area that is at or below 10 meters. ――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――――― Ocean Acidification Another particularly troubling issue associated with rising CO2 concentrations is carbonization and acidification of the oceans. This is an interesting issue because the problem here does not result primarily from warming but from the carbon itself. Rising CO2 concentrations in the atmosphere are quickly mixed into the upper layer of the I-25 oceans. While this reduces atmospheric concentrations, it also causes changes in ocean chemistry. The chemistry is relatively straightforward. When CO2 dissolves in the oceans, it makes the oceans more acidic and lowers the concentrations of calcium carbonate. [25] Several marine organisms form shells from calcium carbonate, including corals, mollusks, crustaceans, and many plankton. Because climate change and ocean acidification are both caused by increasing atmospheric CO2, acidification is sometimes referred to as “the other CO2 problem.” I will refer to it as ocean acidification. There are several important features of ocean acidification. First, it is dependent primarily on the carbon cycle and does not have the uncertainties associated with climate modeling. While there are over 1 million Google hits on “global warming hoax,” as of summer 2010 Google does not record a single instance of “ocean carbonization hoax.” Second, the entire phenomenon was only recently recognized, with the first major publications appearing in over the last decade. Indeed, the biological problems were not even recognized in the IPCC Third Assessment Report of 2001. This is a sobering exhibit in the category of “inevitable surprises.” Third, the major predictions of the ocean acidification hypothesis have been confirmed by measurements in the world’s oceans. Marine scientists are just beginning to reckon with the consequences of acidification on ocean organisms and ecosystems. Field experiments indicate a complex set of responses. In many of the organisms studies (particularly corals and mollusks), the rate of calcification and reproduction slows with higher CO2 concentrations, and this is especially pronounced at high latitudes. This will lead to a major redistribution of species, with those depending upon calcification declining and their predators and the non-calcifiers increasing. We have evidence of a sharp increase in ocean CO2 during an episode known as the Paleocene-Eocene thermal maximum (PETM), 55 million years ago. Based on earlier episodes of spikes of atmospheric CO2 like the PETM, it appears that most species survived, but we should expect extinction of some species. Ocean acidification is one of the most troubling features of CO2 accumulation. It is a polar example of an unmanaged and probably unmanageable system. The quantities of CO2 involved are massive – in the order of 4 trillion tons of CO2 in the upper oceans by 2100. Moreover, the geoengineering solutions to the climate change issue that have been discussed and will be considered in the next chapter will do almost nothing to solve the ocean acidification problem: a technology that reduces incoming radiation and cools the early to offset the warming from accumulating CO2 will not undo the CO2 accumulations in the atmosphere and oceans. Moreover, while it is somewhat reassuring that the earth has experiences similar episodes of spikes in CO2 concentrations similar to that which humans are causing, the distribution of species in earlier periods was different, and we do not have the entire record of how different I-26 species fared in those periods. Because the system is so complex, even with the most talented and diligent scientists trying to understand its consequences, we are unlikely to have a full account of the impacts of ocean acidification until it is upon us. Hurricanes Hurricanes are another example of an unmanaged system that is clearly affected by global warming. Hurricanes differ from sea-level rise and ocean acidification in being extremely local and highly differentiated in impact. Hurricanes are the name given to the North Atlantic versions of a spectacular natural phenomenon known as “tropical cyclones.” If sustained winds reach 74 miles per hour, they are called “hurricanes” in the North Atlantic Ocean. [26] Tropical cyclones are giant heat engines fueled by condensation of warm water, with a positive feedback loop whereby stronger winds lead to lower pressure, increased evaporation and condensation, and yet stronger winds. The genesis of hurricanes is incompletely understood, but one important necessary condition is seasurface water temperature of at least 26.5 ˚C (80 ˚F). Moreover, there are thermodynamic upper limits on the strength of hurricanes, determined primarily by ocean temperature. Begin with the historical trend of hurricane damage. The data for the U.S. are the most complete, and we have gathered data on the storm characteristics and economic damages for 233 hurricanes that have made landfall in the United States between 1900 and 2008. These include all storms since 1933 and 30 storms before 1933. Figure II-7 shows the trend in normalized hurricane damages since 1900 (normalized damages are hurricane damages divided by GDP). Hurricanes caused an average damage of 0.05 percent of GDP over this period, with the maximum being slightly less than 1 percent of GDP in 2005. One interesting feature is that, unlike many other sectors such as agriculture, environmental damages from hurricanes appear to have an upward trend. The impact of Hurricane Katrina is also clearly shown as a spike in 2005. Statistical analysis indicates that, after correcting for the number of storms and their intensity, damages have risen around 2½ percent per year faster than GDP. The reason for this increased vulnerability is a puzzle. It is pretty clearly not primarily due to global warming, but may be due to the fondness people have for being near the coast. [27] I-27 Damage/GDP (percent) 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 00 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 00 10 Figure II-5. Normalized costs of hurricanes, 1900-2008 This figure shows the ratio of damages to GDP for all hurricanes for the given year. The effect of global warming on tropical cyclones has been studied intensively; the basic physics is clear if complex. Global warming might affect hurricanes in several dimensions, including the frequency, size, intensity, lifetime, and geographic distribution of tropical cyclones. Of the five, the only clear link from basic physics is between global warming and cyclonic intensity. As sea-surface temperature rises, the “potential intensity” or upper limit of cyclonic wind speed increases (holding other factors constant). Early calculations by MIT hurricane expert Kerry Emanuel indicated that each degree C of warming of sea-surface temperature (SST) would lead to an increase of 5.5 percent in potential intensity (maximum wind speed). Using several global circulation models (GCMs), Knutson and Tuleya found a slightly lower impact of 3.5 percent increase in maximum wind speed per degree C. Statistical analysis by Emanuel indicates that the distribution of actual hurricane intensity would increase with the increase in potential intensity. There have been several assessments of the impact of global warming on hurricanes. The impact is similar to that of rising sea levels in that the physical effects can be estimated using models, but the socioeconomic impacts will depend upon how humans adapt to increased storm intensity and rising sea levels. We have estimated that the I-28 impact of warming over the 21st century will lead to a doubling of hurricane damages in the U.S. if no measures are taken to reduce vulnerability. This would lead to increased damages of around ½ percent of GDP, or about $75 billion per year at current levels of output. While the is not a substantial fraction of GDP over the next century, it could be devastating to individual communities, as was seen in the case of New Orleans in 2005. Societies can take many steps to reduce vulnerability to more intense hurricanes. Better hurricane forecasting, as an example, has dramatically reduced the fatalities from hurricanes over the last half century. This would not protect immobile structures, however. In the longer run, vulnerable immobile structures depreciate, and incentives should be in place so that they will migrate to higher and safer ground. It does not take much migration to offset the impacts of higher hurricane intensity. The following will illustrate the order of magnitude estimates. About 3 percent of the U.S. capital stock is below 10 meters of altitude and lies in the path of hurricanes. Assuming that the major vulnerable items are structures, this amounts to about $600 billion of capital. The average lifetime of structures is less than 50 years, but we will take this number for simplicity. Assume as a polar case that all of the vulnerably capital is replaced with houses, roads, and hospitals in safer locations as it depreciated. The only cost would be the relocation costs. If these relocation costs were half of the replacement capital costs, the cost of securing the nation’s capital from hurricanes would cost about 0.03 percent of GDP per year. [28] This example illustrates how farsighted planning for the impacts of climate change can reduce the damages significantly. But we must again emphasize that the patterns of winners and losers makes orderly planning extremely difficult. Inlanders may feel little sympathy for rich people in fancy houses whose vulnerable coastal properties are threatened; highlanders may not wish to contributed tax dollars to protect vital structures such as dikes and levees for those threatened by flooding; thriving towns will be disinclined to transfer resources to towns whose tax bases are declining. Moving all the facilities in a coastal town to a more secure location may reduce vulnerability, but that will provide little solace to those who are attached to their homes and communities. So in reality the process of adaptation to more intense storms is likely to be contentious and messy at best, and may lead to counterproductive measures and fiscal or violent conflicts at worst. Wildlife and species loss A final example of a vulnerable sector is wildlife, and more generally species and ecosystems around the globe. The history of speciation and extinction shows distinct periods of surges and extinctions. Major extinctions have occurred during abrupt climatic changes caused by asteroid collisions, volcanic eruptions, glaciations, or sealevel rise. In the worst case, the Permian-Triassic extinction about 250 million years ago wiped out about 90 percent of all species. In the last 10,000 years, many of the most dramatic extinctions were due to human interventions. For example, more than half of I-29 the large mammal species of the Americas disappeared in a short period around the time of humans first arrived approximately 13,000 years ago. There is evidence that humans have had a similarly disastrous effect on species on other continents. For most of human history, as with the dodo bird, the disappearance of species was not mourned or sometimes even unremarked. So, history does not lend comfort on the adaptability of ecosystems and species to further economic expansion accompanied by rapid climate change. Scientists who have studied this question project very dire consequences of the warming if no policies are taken. The most recent summary by the IPCC concludes that about 25 percent of species on a global scale will be at increasingly high risk of extinction as global mean temperatures exceed 2 to 3 °C above pre-industrial levels. Our projections indicate that this temperature range will occur in the second half of the 21st century. We should add to this outlook the dangers to marine organisms of ocean acidification discussed above. A few comments about the dangers to species and ecosystems are in order. To begin with, many people feel there are strong ethical issues involved in extinguishing life. For some this is a religious issue. I would view it as a neglect of our responsibilities as stewards of planet Earth if we, even inadvertently through the indirect impact of our energy use, were to cause further widespread species losses. The evolution of polar bears, Monarch butterflies, cutthroat trout, South African protea – and, yes even those ingenious but irritating mosquitoes – is the greatest wonder of the world. To undo a substantial part of that heritage in a century is a terrible step. As Schopenhauer wrote, “The assumption that animals are without rights and the illusion that our treatment of them has no moral significance is a positively outrageous example of Western crudity and barbarity.” [29] Major difficulties arise when we attempt to translate the immorality of destroying life into action. The heart of the difficult is to determine how much we would be willing to sacrifice to prevent the loss of wildlife and species. Some may object that even asking this question invokes a crude materialism and that the balancing of life and money is itself an immoral act. But preventing loss of ecosystems and species is not a simple matter. It involves, as we will see in the next part, taking costly steps to change energy systems at very large costs. Moreover, there is inevitably a tradeoff between the stringency of our emissions reductions and the risk of ecosystem and species losses. Unfortunately, the natural and social sciences have been unable to make plausible estimates of the value of preserving ecosystems and species. In other words, we cannot make reliable estimates of the damages from climate change in this area. The first difficulty comes from the difficulty in making reliable projections of the species losses over time. We will illustrate the difficulties by examining an influential study by Thomas et al. This study concludes that between 18 and 35 percent of species are committed to I-30 extinction. The technique is to begin with the climatic range of an existing species (mammal, bird, frog, etc.) in a particular region, such as Mexico. Then, the team estimated how the size of the climate range would change under a particular scenario, such as a 3 °C increase for South Africa. They then apply a technique known as the species-area relationship, which states that the number of species is positively associated with area of the habitat. In general, for the regions considered, the climate range shrinks, which implies that the number of species will also shrink. For example, under the assumed 3 °C increase for South Africa, they conclude that 38 percent of the Proteaceae species will become extinct. [30] Perhaps the best documented examples of potential extinctions are the reef-building corals. Estimates of extinction rates are based on classification systems of how threatened the different systems are, but there are no reliable long-term population measures. [31] While these are impressive studies, they have severe limitations. For example, some of the species can be preserved, so the extinctions often refer to in situ survival. Secondly, the techniques are quite controversial and may not apply to a situation in which species have adapted to human habitations. And in other cases, the damage is being done by habitat destruction, overuse, overfishing, overhunting, and pollution that would occur even in the absence of climate change. A second difficulty arises because economists have not developed a reliable technique for valuing ecosystem and species losses. The difficulty can be described by comparing this issue with the economic impacts of damage to wheat production discussed above. When the production of wheat declines by 10 percent, economists typically value that at the market price of wheat. If climate change leads wheat production to decline by 100 million bushels and the price of wheat is unchanged at $5 per bushel, then the social cost is $500 million. It has been tempting for scientists worried about ecosystem and species losses to point to the economic damage that might occur with major losses. One common but unsubstantiated claim is that one-quarter of Western pharmaceuticals are derived from rainforest ingredients. [32] A caricature of these analyses is that when species disappear we are foregoing the miracle cure to AIDS that lurks in the Brazilian forest hidden in some undiscovered fungus. While such a tale is not impossible, the direct economic value of many of the species is likely to be next to nothing. Innovations in agriculture, forestry, fisheries, and pharmacology occur primarily in industrial and laboratory settings, not in the rain forest. As we noted above, economic output around the world is becoming increasingly less dependent on unmanaged systems. It is hard to conceive that a 10 percent loss in frog species will have a measurable effect on market economic activity. The point is not that these should be ignored. Rather, it is the moral imperative to preserve the natural world that we have inherited, rather than some hypothetical return on investment, that should drive our actions. I-31 Ecosystem and species losses are different from wheat or medicine because we have no market metric to use to value these losses. Some of the impacts will be market or near-market goods and services (such as the losses from harvesting timber or from the value of the catch as food). But the gains from species preservation are “public goods.” Public goods are commodities for which the cost of extending the service to an additional person is zero and for which it is impossible or expensive to exclude individuals from enjoying. Take global positioning systems as an example. These are used for hiking, missile guidance, and determining the distance of a golf ball from a hole. These are public goods because people who find their location are not reducing the value of signals for others. Similarly, the gain from preserving polar bears is primarily from the non-market gain and satisfaction of having such a beautiful animal on earth, as well as the moral gain from not destroying it. The difficulty comes in attempting to estimate the value of public goods. Since there is no market for moral gain or remote appreciation, we have no reliable measuring rod to calculate the gain from protecting species. Statisticians have devised measures known as “contingent valuation” to estimate the value. These are essentially highly structured surveys in which people are asked, in effect, “What would you pay to protect polar bears?” But these instruments are highly controversial, have proven unreliable, are subject to huge biases in use, and have no behavioral counterparts. As a result of both these shortcomings – incomplete scientific assessment of the risk and inadequate economic tools for valuation – it seems fair to conclude that we do not have even an order-of-magnitude estimate of the economic impact of ecosystem and species losses from global warming. But again, this does not mean we should simply throw up our hands and walk away from the problem. At the least, we need a better way of sorting out the urgent ecosystem and species preservation from those with a lower priority. Some biologists suggest that number of species is an impoverished measure of biological importance. Other metrics would emphasize such qualities as functional or behavioral diversity and the ability to rebound after an environmental shock that extinguishes many species or genera. This point was emphasized in an important finding of biologists Sean Nee and Robert May, who studied how much of the evolutionary history – the “tree of life” – is lost during extinctions. Their work had the surprising finding that approximately 80 percent of the underlying tree of life can survive even when approximately 95 percent of species are lost. [33] One of the major tasks of modern biology will be to develop better metrics of evolutionary importance to guide our conservation decisions. Impacts on Lake Wobegon One of the difficulties most people have with assessing the dangers of climate change is what might be called the Lake Wobegon syndrome. Remember that in Lake Wobegon, all the men are good looking, and all the children are above average. In this context, we must ask if everything is at risk with global warming. Clearly, all problems I-32 cannot be above average concern. We need to separate major from less major. If we are told to worry about everything, we end of worrying about nothing. The last section analyzed four problems that seemed indeed to be both genuine and relatively difficult to manage. In this section, therefore, I will discuss problems sometimes associated with climate change that may in fact be of lesser concern. This is not to imply that they are of no concern because assessment is so difficult. Rather, they are areas that would seem to be relatively low on the list of priorities that require the closest scrutiny and major investments. The three areas discussed here are agriculture, national security, and health. Each of these is discussed because they have featured prominently in discussions about the potential impacts of climate change. They all share a common feature as we look out a century or more in a world of continued rapid technological advance, however, because each is a heavily managed sector. That is, each of them has features in which climate plays a diminishing role over time and in which human decisions and technologies dominate the action. Unlike coastal properties, hurricanes, concerns about species preservation, and ocean acidification, the three areas discussed here are ones where technology will increasingly be in the laboratories rather than in the fields. Human health Among the frightening impacts of global warming is the potential for major increases in the burden of disease. Recent research reviewed by the IPCC concludes that climate change will have harmful effects on health through two mechanisms. The first is the direct effect of increasing the stress from environmental conditions due to heat waves, pollution, and floods; the second is the indirect effect that occurs because global warming may lower living standards, thereby increasing the range of some infectious diseases such as malaria and increasing malnutrition and diarrheal disorders. The most detailed assessment of health impacts of climate change has been undertaken by a team of health and climate scientists for the World Health Organization. They employ the useful concept of “DALY,” or disability-adjusted lifeyear. The DALY concept measures the loss in healthy years of life from different diseases. For example, if someone dies in an automobile accident at age 40, this would be about 40 DALYs lost. If a girl in Tanzania contracts malaria, her life expectancy would be reduced by about 33 years, so that would have a loss of 33 DALYs. [34] (Some scholars prefer “QALYs,” which are quality-adjusted life years, but public health specialists have generally focused on DALYs.) The researchers examine epidemiological evidence on the relationship between different diseases and climatic conditions. They then estimate the increased risk of disease from the changing climate. By combining these estimates, they estimated the total health risk from climate change. [35] Table II-7 shows estimates of the health losses from climate change in the mid-21st century using relative risk estimates of the WHO I-33 team. The team identified three major areas as concerns: malnutrition (from inadequate incomes), diarrheal diseases (from poor sanitation and health systems), and malaria (from a spread of malarial regions). We have taken the estimates using low adaptation and for unrestrained emissions. The temperature assumptions underlying the estimates in the WHO study correspond to the emissions and temperature projections for around 2050 in the Yale-RICE model, so we will generally identify these with impact for 2050. The top part of the figure shows the estimated disability adjusted life-years lost from each of the three sources for six major regions. According to the estimates, the major vulnerable regions are Africa and South East Asia (primarily India). Diarrheal diseases consist of about half the health risks, with malaria and malnutrition each being about a quarter. Note that these estimates exclude a number of major but quantitatively less significant risks such as flooding, other tropical diseases, and heat stress. The bottom part shows the increase as a percent of total losses and losses for that specific set of diseases. The total estimated losses from climate change consists of about 1.3 percent of all losses. This estimate is based on 2004 population and mortality rates. The increased health risk arises primarily for Africa and Southeast Asia. For the developed regions of North America and Western Europe, the increased health risks are minimal. [36] I-34 Increased risk from climate change Diarrhoeal diseases Total Malaria Nutritional deficiencies [Disability adjusted life years lost per 1000 persons] 14.91 6.99 7.13 0.80 Eastern Mediterranean 1.06 0.61 0.06 0.39 Latin American 0.26 0.24 0.03 0.00 South East Asia 4.53 2.34 0.02 2.18 Western Pacific North America and Western Europe World Total 0.35 0.27 0.08 0.00 0.02 0.02 0.00 0.00 3.09 1.56 0.85 0.69 Total Diarrhoeal diseases Malaria Nutritional deficiencies Africa Increased risk as percent of baseline mortality [Losses from climate change as % of all losses] Africa 2.92 1.37 1.40 0.16 Eastern Mediterranean 0.61 0.35 0.04 0.22 Latin American 0.16 0.14 0.02 0.00 South East Asia 1.71 0.88 0.01 0.82 Western Pacific 0.23 0.18 0.05 0.00 North America and Western Europe 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 1.31 0.66 0.36 0.29 World Total Table II-6. Estimated health impact of global warming to 2000 Table shows the disability-adjusted life years lost in different regions and from different sources as a percent of the total lost life years from all sources. ____________________________ We remarked at the beginning of this chapter that impacts analysis is a kind of house-to-house combat between analysts, messy data, and murky future trends. Nowhere is the terrain more treacherous than in mapping out future health impacts. Health is of great importance to people’s well-being and to economic performance. Health care is a large and growing part of the economy. The technology of health care is I-35 changing rapidly as new knowledge, drugs, equipment, and information technology transform the sector enormously. Moreover, the health status of poor countries has improved rapidly in recent years. Consider for example the 60 countries with per capita income less than $2000 in 1980. In these countries, life expectancy rose by 14 years in the last 3 decades. Moreover, the rise in health status is clearly associated with higher incomes. Economic studies indicate that a rise of 10 percent in per capita income is associated with life expectancy that is higher by 0.3 years. The major threat to the health in poor countries has not been climate change, but the AIDS epidemic. Health improvements in other areas have been offset in countries such as Zimbabwe, Botswana, Zambia, and South Africa, where the AIDS epidemic has lowered life expectancies by more than 10 years and perhaps as much as 20 years in the worst cases. [37] We can put the health risks in Table II-7 in the context of the overall health improvements in developing countries. For poor countries, life expectancy has increased 3½ years per decade over the last half century. The losses from climate change shown in Table II-7 amount to about one-third of a year of life expectancy (1/3 of a lifeyear per person) on a global basis. For Africa, they amount to about one year of life expectancy. This is approximately three years lost over the next half century using the pessimistic assumptions in Table II-7. Given the race between technology and income growth on the one hand and climate change on the other, there are two major problems with projections of health impacts. First, they assume minimal adaptations to the rising temperatures and health burden. For example, we might expect, particularly with rising incomes, that people would adapt their structures and life styles to the higher temperatures through such means as air conditioning; the models assumed no adaptation at all to heat stress. Similarly, there were no adaptations taken to the potential spread of malaria with warming, even with the higher incomes. Second, the modeling does not account for the sharp improvements in health care and life expectancies that have taken place and can be expected to take place with higher incomes. Note that by the end of the next century, the low-income regions are expected to have incomes close to those of today’s high income regions; moreover, this rapid growth is a central part of the scenarios that are producing warming in the first place. But modeling of the vulnerability to warming overlooks the likely improvements in public and private health that are likely to occur with rising incomes and urbanization. We can take the example of diarrheal diseases as an example. Diarrheal diseases are assumed to produce about half the health impacts of climate change by mid-21st century. The methodologies used in the projections assume that higher incomes reduce diarrheal diseases, and that countries with a per capita income of greater than $6000 have no diarrheal diseases. Yet the studies that produce rapid emissions growth assume I-36 rapid economic growth. For example, the Yale-RICE model used to develop the estimates used here project output per capita in sub-Saharan Africa to grow to $9500 by 2050. So the estimates of growing malnutrition and related diseases in the climatehealth scenarios are inconsistent with the estimates of growing incomes that produce the emissions that lead to the rapid warming. Another example of questionable assumptions is the incidence of malaria. The IPCC Fourth Assessment states that by 2100, there will be a 16 to 28 percent increase in exposure to malaria in Africa. [38] These are slightly higher than the numbers used in our estimates in Table II-7. However, these estimates assume that there are no socioeconomic adapatations in the coming years. Such adaptations would include available technologies such as avoidance of mosquitoes, use of repellants or mosquito nets, preventive medicines, and treatment with infection. More important, the projections would be completely wrong if technological improvements over the next century were to produce an economical malaria vaccine. We might not take seriously Bill Gates’s patent on hurricane intensity described above, but surely we should take seriously the Gates Foundation’s program on malaria. The points about diarrheal diseases, malnutrition, and malaria are example of the more general point about the role of impacts to climate change in managed systems that we have emphasized. Health care is one of the most intensively managed of all human systems. In the case of malaria or other diseases that are worsened by climate change, we would expect that governments would take steps to reduce vulnerabilities through health research, preventive measures, and alleviative care. We have also seen that human societies have, at least from the point of view of climate change, become increasingly managed and climate-proofed. While there is no law of nature that proves this trend will continue, it seems likely that the poorer countries will follow the path of climate-proofing over the next century – in housing, medical care, storm warning systems, and the like. National security One of the new concerns about climate change has been as a threat to national security. This has been voiced particularly in the United States. These concerns became public in 2007 with a report by the military research organization, the Center for Naval Analyses, and prepared by several former military officers. While not an official military document, this has been influential in defense circles. The report concluded, “The nature and pace of climate changes being observed today and the consequences projected by the consensus scientific opinion are grave and pose equally grave implications for our national security.” [39] The most recent National Security Strategy (NSS) of the U.S. issued in 2010 discussed climate change as an integral part of national security. However, it lists climate change as one of the elements of “International Order” rather than “Security.” It states, “The danger from climate change is real, urgent, and severe. The change I-37 wrought by a warming planet will lead to new conflicts over refugees and resources; new suffering from drought and famine; catastrophic natural disasters; and the degradation of land across the globe.” [40] Given this and other reports, these concerns warrant close scrutiny. To begin with, it is important to define carefully what is meant by a “national-security concern.” In this discussion, I will concentrate on the “hard” aspects of national security. In the NSS, the hard security concerns include “Disrupt, Dismantle, and Defeat Al-Qa’ida and its Violent Extremist Affiliates in Afghanistan, Pakistan, and Around the World,” “Reverse the Spread of Nuclear and Biological Weapons and Secure Nuclear Materials,” and “Secure Cyberspace.” That is, these are threats to the survival, viability, and welfare of the nation-state and its allies. Often, discussions of national security include other “soft” threats. In the NSS, for example, the discussion includes measure to strengthen education and human capital, enhance science, technology, and innovation, spend taxpayers’ dollars wisely, and sustain broad cooperation on key global challenges. These are a combination of foreign policy and even traditional domestic policy. I do not dismiss these important objectives. Rather, I would divide the problems into ones that are properly military in nature – which is discussed in this section – and those that are economic or humanitarian in nature – discussed elsewhere. One further warning is particularly important in examining the impact of climate change on military policy: We must be careful not to assume a static technological and political environment. In considering the impact on security in the late 21st century, we must allow for at least two major trends. The first is that, under the standard scenario that produces climate change, most countries will be much richer than they are today. We should not assume that African countries have incomes comparable to the West today and at the same time assume that large numbers of their populations are leading a nomadic existence herding starving cattle across the desert. Second, it seems highly likely that 21st century warfare will be increasingly dominated by information systems, remote control, and artificial intelligence. Just as the crossbow and the battleship have passed into the graveyard of military technologies, we should be wary of assuming that today’s technologies will continue to dominate future warfare. With these caveats, turn first to the question of whether climate change is thought to pose direct effects on American national security (I concentrate on American security because this is where the thinking is most developed). A review of the studies cited above find relatively few major direct impacts of climate change on national security. Some U.S. bases may be affected, particularly if they are vulnerable to sea-level rise. An ice-free Arctic ocean will change naval planning and submarine operations. More intense storms may occasionally interfere with naval operations. It is hard to see, however, why any of these would cause a major change in the strategic balance among I-38 countries; one exception world considering is how an ice-free Arctic would affect Canada and Russia. [41] There is an extensive literature on conflict and the environment. In his study of climate change and security, Rymn Parsons observed that “environmental problems do not themselves cause wars, but do exacerbate other problems and conflicts that can lead to war.” [42] In a survey of the literature on conflict and resources, Halvard Buhaug, Nils Petter Gleditsch, and Ole Magnus Theisen concluded, “No tested link between resource scarcity and civil conflict remains robust across various data operationalizations and model specifications. Tellingly, two recent reports from the Political Instability Task Force have abandoned the issue of environmental scarcity altogether.” [43] Another way of approaching the issue is to look at the indirect link between climate change and conflict. Most studies of national security emphasize that climate change may destabilize countries. The reasoning takes two steps. First, climate change will have damaging effects on sectors such as water, agriculture, public health, flooding, and loss of land. From an economic vantage point, these impacts will reduce the living standards of the affected populations – presumably sharply. The second step in the logic is that a sharp decline in living standards will increase the likelihood of mass migrations, political unrest, societal collapse, and failed states. Each of these steps needs to be examined carefully. We have discussed all of the damaging impacts elsewhere. Some appear to be significant, while others seem less central. The central question is whether these impacts are large and pervasive against the background of rising trend of economic growth and the relatively small calculated impacts of climate change. It would take much larger impacts of climate change than those now estimated to have the sudden and large impacts on incomes that appear to be assumed in the security studies. The second point – that the income shocks will lead to political disturbances – also needs careful attention. The impact of economic distress on military conflict and other disturbances is unclear. The literature on the determinants of military conflicts has looked intensively into the different sources but has not determined whether prior economic stress leads to war. In work by John Oneal, Bruce Russett, and myself, we examined several theories and variables, including democracy, per capita income, geographical variables, and the threat environment. I have extended that study by adding another set of variables that include whether one of the countries experienced a sharp economic decline in prior years. For this test, I defined economic stress as a period in which real GDP declined by at least 5 percent per year for two prior years, looking at the period since World War II. These periods of distress include about 3 percent of the observations. The presence of economic distress was associated with a lower probability of military disputes than other years, but the variable was statistically insignificant. While this exercise is hardly the last word, it does suggest that the causal I-39 linkage from climate change through economic distress to military conflict is not a tight or universal one. [44] In the end, concerns about national security turn out to be primarily concerns that the world of the late 21st century will be poorer and more unstable – that climate change will harm food production, water availability, and living standards so greatly that political structures will not be able to cope. This picture is not supported by economic studies of the impacts, but much remains highly unpredictable. Agriculture We close our discussion of specific sectors – the last house in our house-to-house combat with impact studies – with agriculture. We have seen that many of the gloomy predictions about the impacts of climate change actually lead back to agriculture. Two of the major health impacts – malnourishment and diarrheal diseases – suggest poor diets and poverty. The national security concerns arise in part because of potential conflicts from drought, bad harvests, poverty, water shortages, and international migration. Almost daily we read about global famine, decadal droughts, and major areas at risk. For example, the well-known Stern Review writes, “Declining crop yields are likely to leave hundreds of millions without the ability to produce or purchase sufficient food, particularly in the poorest parts of the world…. Once temperatures increase by 3 °C, 250 - 550 million additional people may be at risk – over half in Africa and Western Asia, where (1) the declines in yield are greatest, (2) dependence on agriculture highest, and (3) purchasing power most limited.” [45] The basic reasoning behind the gloomy forecasts for food production relies on two major negative factors. First, climate change is likely to lead to warmer climates with lower soil moisture in many regions of the world where climates are already warmer than would be optimal for food production. Work of my colleague Robert Mendelsohn suggests that current climates in many parts of Latin America, Africa, and Asia are already warmer than is optimal for food production, and further warming would disadvantage those regions even more. A second concern is that climate change may lead to declines in mountain snowpack and river runoff. This would reduce water availability for irrigation and harm agricultural productivity. These two factors have been extensively investigated with the use of climate projections and crop models. The crystal ball of future impacts for agriculture is just as cloudy as in other areas, but there are several factors that mitigate the potentially harmful impacts of climate change. These are carbon fertilization, adaptation, and trade. One important mitigation in agriculture is “carbon fertilization.” Carbon dioxide is an important fertilizer in many plants. The fertilization effect has been tested in the field in several experiments. Crop yields for wheat, cotton, and clover – particularly when combined with appropriate adjustments of other fertilizers – have increased sharply in field experiments. One review of multiple studies in the field found that I-40 doubling atmospheric concentrations of CO2 would increase yields of rice, wheat, and soybeans between 10 and 15 percent. Certain plants (the C4 variety like corn) are expected to show relatively small increases in yield. There are many questions about how fertilization will interact with other stresses, but the general view is that this is a significant offset to the warmer and drier climates that might occur in many regions. A second important factor is what is called “adaptation.” Adaptation refers to the adjustments that human or natural systems take in response to changes in environmental conditions. These take place on multiple levels. We can use the example of agriculture to illustrate how adaptation occurs. Some adaptation takes place even in unmanaged systems, such as when a species migrates to a more friendly climatic zone after climate change. In agriculture, we usually consider the most important adaptations to be those undertaken by farmers. Among the important adaptations in the short run are changes in sowing and harvesting dates, changing seeds and crops, modifying water supply through irrigation systems, changing techniques of production such as fertilizer, tillage methods, grain drying, and other field operations. In the longer run, farmers can move into new areas and abandon infertile ones, develop new varieties of seeds that are drought and heat resistant, and move land into other uses. One of the most important adaptations is the use of more water-efficient irrigation systems. [46] Figure II-8 illustrates the both the way that adaptation works and the biases that can occur when adaptation is not taken into account. The graph shows land value in different uses. Land value is used by economists to reflect the inherent productivity of land as determined by climate, location, and other variables. The horizontal axis measures temperature, while the vertical axis measures the economic value of an activity. We show four activities – wheat production, corn production, grazing, and retirement homes. For each of these, the illustrated shape of the curve is dome-shaped or concave, with a rising segment, a maximum, and a sharp decline when the temperature deviates too far from the optimum. [47] For this example, we consider only adaptations that involve changing the crop or land use. Studies of wheat yield without adaptation would do experiments and find that the yield or value followed the ABCF line; those for corn would follow the CD corn line; and so on. A study that examined the effect of warming without adaptation would assume that the value of the land at high temperature would fall from point C to point F. It would therefore find a very sharp decline in food production with climate change. In reality, as yields fall, farmers look around and find the best possible use for their land. In the example shown in Figure II-8, farmers would change to corn production. Then, as temperatures rose further, they would switch to grazing cattle. Finally, when the land becomes completely unsuitable for agriculture, they might sell to a developer who would build a retirement community and golf course. The value of the land with adapatation is shown as the upper “envelope” joined by points ABCDE of the I-41 values for the different activities. Clearly, with adaptations, the economic value of land is much higher than without adaptations. Figure II-6. Illustration of the value of land with and without adaptation _____________________ Studies of agriculture have looked extensively at impacts with and without adaptation, and it will be useful to examine a specific example. Figure II-9 shows a compilation of studies of the effect of climate change on the yields of wheat in low latitude regions. [48] The plot shows the results of 69 published studies at multiple simulation sites as a function of mean local temperature change. The red dots show the response without adaptations, while the dark green dots show with a limited set of adaptations. The green and red lines show the best statistical fit to the points. I-42 Figure II-7. Estimated impact of climate change on wheat yields for low-latitude regions The central results shown in Figure II-9 are that with adaptation the yields of wheat would be positive for climate change scenarios up to 3 °C. This is the change that would be expected around 2100 for low-latitude regions. They would begin to turn significantly negative after than increase, and would reach around minus 30 percent at a 5 °C temperature increase. Note that these estimates include projected impacts on precipitation and soil moisture. The same survey found that the break-even temperature change for rice is estimated to be around 4 °C. The adaptations varied among studies, but typically included changes in fertilizer treatments, planting dates, and shifts from rain-fed to irrigated conditions. They usually did not consider changing crops or new genetic varieties. They almost never considered the value of the land in non-agricultural activities. From an economic point of view, it would be very surprising to have a situation where no adaptations took place over a period of several years, and indeed the adaptations assumed in most studies are on the lean side of what is realistic. The third mitigating factor for agriculture is national and international trade. Increasingly, farming is a market activity not a subsistence activity. This means that a shock to agricultural productivity in one region is buffered by markets so that the impact on food prices is very small. To a first approximation, if wheat yields in Kansas decline by 10 percent because of climate change, there will be virtually no impact on food prices or on consumers. [49] I-43 Real farm prices, U.S. (1948=100) 100 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 Figure II-8. Trends in the prices of farm products, United States 1948 – 2009 Moreover, if this change takes place over a decade or more, the impact on the market will be lost in the noise. It is useful to recall that agricultural markets are constantly subject to supply and demand shocks. But the major shocks have been to lower food prices in most regions. Figure II-10 shows the trend in U.S. raw food prices relative to wages over the last half century. The downward trend in prices – not warming – is the major fact that American farmers are worried about. [50] The symptoms of a climate-induced food crisis would be a reversal of the trend shown in Figure II-9. What do studies show? A review of world food models by the IPCC showed a range of results. Those models with adaptation and highly developed trade models generally showed a decline in food prices relative to a baseline out to at least a temperature increase of 3 °C. These results are consistent with studies that find increasing agricultural yields up to 3 °C temperature increase, as shown in Figure II-9. [51] This concludes our discussion of Lake Wobegon effects. Our review of health, national security, and agriculture indicate that for the next few years climate change is likely to add noise to the background shocks in these sectors. Shocks are usually I-44 unwelcome, so few people would advocate increasing the variability that doctors and generals and farmers have to contend with. But relative to the background trends in these sectors, climate change would appear to be a concern that is … below average. Aggregate Assessments of the Damages from Climate Change Central estimates of overall damages We have taken a long excursion to examine the techniques used for assessing impacts and presented some of the major results. Having gone house to house, we can stand back and look at the village. We are clearly interested in much more than wheat in Kansas or sea-level rise in the Netherlands. What are the overall impacts as best as can be judged? Economists have struggled to estimate the aggregate damages from climate change for several years. The aggregate studies pull together studies for all the relevant sectors for different countries and where estimates are available. But be warned: There is no social science analog to the global climate models. We cannot look to some grand economic “model of everything” to estimate the impacts of climate change. Rather, estimating damages is like house-to-house combat, looking at each of the countries’ economic and social structures, geography, climate, and industry composition. However, many sectors in many countries have not been studied, so the aggregate estimates involve a great deal of guesswork and extrapolation. Additionally, some impacts are extremely difficult to value, particularly impacts on natural processes like ecosystems or species extinctions. But just as national accountants attempt to put together the “gross domestic product” to measure the entire output of an economy, similarly do environmental economists attempt to combine measures from different Damages as percent of output 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 -2 -3 I-45 Global mean temperature increase (°C) 3.5 areas to estimate the total impacts or damages from climate change. Figure II-11 shows the results of studies over the last two decades compiled by the leading scholar in this area, Richard Tol. [52] Several interesting findings emerge from these results. The first and major surprise is that, for the range of changes that have been calculated, the estimated impacts of climate change are relatively small. The largest damage estimate is around 5 percent of output. The most carefully studied scenario is one with a 2.5 °C warming (which we estimate to occur around 2070). For this amount of warming, the central estimate is around 1½ percent of global output. Additionally, impacts are estimated to be non-linear. This means that an additional degree is estimated to be increasingly costly with more warming. Another surprise (foreshadowed by our discussion of agriculture above) is that there may be a modest net benefit from the first degree or so of warming. Cautionary reservations about the estimates These results must be used with great caution, however. They include only the quantifiable impacts and are largely concentrated on the market or near-market sectors such as agriculture, real estate, land, forestry, sea-level rise, and human health. Since we have found that much of the economy is relative invulnerable to climate, it is not surprising that the market component of damages, particularly in high income countries, is relative modest. It is important to understand what these studies exclude. To begin with, they exclude several negative and positive items that are unlikely to add up to much in the aggregate, even for individual countries. Here are some examples of impacts that have been examined but are generally ambiguous or small. Generally excluded are the impact on energy expenditures (less space heating, more space cooling); lower expenditures on winter coats; the costs of cooling plants for electricity generation; increased accessibility of arctic harbors; greater cost of snowmaking for skiing; decreased amenities from winter recreation and greater amenities from warm-weather recreation; loss of income from fisheries; and so on. There is always the possibility that the list is a very large number of small numbers, which could add up to a large number, as in death with 1000 cuts. Given all the sectors in all the regions for all the possible scenarios, the aggregate impact of these “minor” impacts is hard to judge. Additionally, there are a few potentially very large impacts that are either too uncertain or too difficult to estimate reliably. We discussed above the difficulty of calculating the economic impacts of loss of biodiversity. This analysis is doubly cursed because the impacts are too complex to estimate and economists have no reliable methodology for estimate the value of biodiversity losses. Also, we might consider whether these figures should be increased because of risk aversion because the impacts are so uncertain. [53] Finally, there are the global scale singularities and abrupt events, which I discuss in the next section. I-46 Singularities and abrupt changes Background on abrupt changes Perhaps the major concerns, particularly among earth scientists, are the possibility that continued warming might lead to discontinuous, abrupt, or catastrophic climate changes and consequences. We have discussed these above, but they are worth further discussion. These concerns are variously called tipping points, singularities, mathematical catastrophes, and abrupt events. Such outcomes can occur in non-linear dynamic systems when a system crosses a threshold, and a sharply discontinuous behavior ensues. Look back at Figure I-14 on p. I-25. This shows how a tiny change in an influence can send a system into a completely new, different, and locally stable equilibrium. We are all familiar with examples of singularities in daily life. For example, if you lean to the side of a canoe, you will eventually pass the tipping point, the canoe tips over, and you are in the water. Tipping points are found in economics in the phenomenon known as “bank runs,” which were endemic in earlier days. If too many people lose confidence in a bank, they rush to the bank and attempt to withdraw their funds. Because banks typically have only a small fraction of their deposits on hand, they could not satisfy all depositors. Once people judge that there is likely to be a bank run, it is a self-fulfilling expectation because they run to the bank to get there before other people, who in turn are trying to get there before they do, and the bank is quickly out of cash. Lest this seems too archaic a notion, it is worth noting that exactly this phenomenon was responsible for the demise of investment banks Bear, Sterns in March 2003 and Lehman Bros in September 2003. In both cases, large investors smelled trouble and withdrew funds, but in the second case the government did not come to the rescue. The fleet and well-connected got their money out, while the laggards lost billions of dollars. Tipping points have many interesting features. One is that they often have multiple equilibria. For example, in the case of bank runs and the tippy canoes, there are “good equilibria” (sitting in the canoe and or with your money in solvent banks) and “bad equilibria” (swimming in the water or left with some worthless deposits). A second feature is that singular events can occur very quickly. Indeed, abrupt climate change is sometimes defined as changes in the climate that occur much more quickly than the change in the precipitating event. [54] In financial markets, the brilliant economist Rudy Dornbusch remarked that financial crises take much, much longer to come than you think, and then they happen much faster than you could imagine. [55] One of the more frightening aspects of tipping points and abrupt events is their inherent unpredictability. [56] I-47 Worrisome singularities What are the singularities in climate change? We must emphasize that, like financial crises or the tippy canoe, the exact timing of these is essentially impossible to predict. They can occur rapidly and unexpectedly, or perhaps they will never happen. With that said, three global-scale singularities have received considerable attention. The first, which we discussed above, is sea-level rise from abrupt melting or collapse of the major ice sheets of Greenland and West Antarctica. This would have major consequences for the entire globe, but particularly for coastal communities and many large agglomerations. The estimates of sea-level rise that I showed in Figure II-5 shows how the process might proceed without any abrupt events. But many specialists believe that the current estimates may not capture the processes correctly, and that they may occur much more rapidly. Scientists are hard at work in modeling these changes, and it seem likely that the pace and scope of deglaciation will be better understood in the coming years. [57] A second important singularity is change in ocean currents, particularly the Atlantic Thermohaline Circulation (THC), popularly known as the Gulf Stream. In the present era, ocean currents bring warm surface water to the North Atlantic. As a result, the North Atlantic community is much warmer, indeed habitable, than it would otherwise be. For example, Scotland is the same latitude at the peninsula of Kamchatka in eastern Russia, but its average temperature is about 12 °C warmer in Scotland than in Kamchatka. Although the THC has been stable for several thousand years, it appears that there were large and rapid shifts in the system during ice ages. A weakening or reversal of the THC would lead to a sharp cooling of the North Atlantic region. Climate models project increases in both temperature and precipitation in the higher latitudes. These changes make surface water less dense and thereby reduce the speed of the thermohaline circulation. Warm water now moves north, warms the North Atlantic, and then dives to return south. In a warmer world, that process would slow or even stop. This would tend to cool the North Atlantic relative to the rest of the world and actually warm other regions. The most recent review of the evidence on changes in the THC shows less dramatic changes than earlier modeling results. This is one of the few pieces of good news on impacts that has been recorded in recent years. For temperature projections that are roughly the same as the economic models discussed earlier, the North Atlantic circulation is projected to weaken by about 50 percent over the 21st century. None of the 19 models contained in the IPCC Fourth Report shows a complete shutdown of the circulation in the 21st century. In the models where the circulation weakens, Europe continues to warm because the cooling effect of the slowdown is smaller than the warming effects of the reduced circulation. [58] A third set of major global concerns is the long-term interaction between climate, the biosphere, and the carbon cycle. Some background on climate models will be I-48 helpful here. Most climate models begin with a given path of emissions of CO2 and other greenhouse gases. The CO2 gradually is distributed through different reservoirs, including the atmosphere, the oceans, and the biosphere in trees, crops, and soils. In the short run of a century or so, however, the only added CO2 comes from human additions such as burning fossil fuels. With a warmer climate and higher CO2 concentrations, there are many important feedback effects that may increase or decrease climate change. One set of feedbacks takes place in the oceans through reduced circulation and decreased chemical buffering, which will lower the uptake of CO2 in the oceans. This by itself is estimated to increase atmospheric concentrations of CO2 over the 21st century by about 20 percent. [59] Another set of feedbacks is the impact of warming on release of carbon dioxide (CO2) and methane (CH4). Begin with the methane question. Methane is a powerful greenhouse gas, and it gradually is transformed to the stable chemical compound of CO2. There are vast quantities of methane stored frozen in the form of methane hydrates, which are methane molecules trapped in ice crystals. Most of the methane hydrates are stored in sediments in the oceans, while a vast quantity is frozen in the ground in cold regions. The concern is that if either of these sources released methane into the atmosphere, this could add a sharp further warming to that already in train. A final concern involves the difference between the short-run and the long-run response of climate to human changes. Today’s climate models are basically designed to calculate the “fast feedback processes” – those involving the direct effects of increasing concentrations of greenhouse gases and the rapid feedbacks such as changes of water vapor, clouds and sea ice. (These are not very fast by economists’ standards as they occur over a few hundred years, but they are fast by geoscientists’ standards.) There may be “slow feedback processes” that amplify these effects. The slow processes involve ice-sheet disintegration, vegetation migration, and releases of greenhouse gases (such as the methane just discussed) from soils, tundra, and ocean sediments. For example, as glaciers and ice sheets melt, the earth becomes darker. This leads to a lower albedo (reflectivity), which in turn further warms the earth. Additionally, a warmer earth may lead to releases of CO2 and other greenhouse gases from the oceans and the biota, as described above. Preliminary calculation suggest that, when the slow feedback processes are included, the climate sensitivity may be twice as large as is calculated by the current suite of climate models. That is, the long-run sensitivity to CO2 doubling might be as high as 6 °C, instead of the standard 3 °C found in most models today. [60] While this is a very frightening prospect, it must be recognized that it has not been validated by multiple models. Furthermore, it applies when CO2 has been airborne for time periods of centuries to millennia. We might wonder whether it is appropriate to assume that we cannot devise technologies to control atmospheric concentrations of CO2 sometime in the next 1000 years, so this may be less alarming than would appear at first blush. I-49 Careful modeling of the economic, emissions, and longer-term climate models will be necessary to determine how central these slow feedback processes are to decisions about climate policy. Final Thoughts on Impacts At the end of this review of the impacts of future climate change, what should we conclude? The first point is to emphasize how difficult impact analyses are. They combine the uncertainties of emissions projections and climate models. Even if we overlook the uncertainties about future climate change, the reactions of human and natural systems to these changes are very poorly understood. In part, reactions of social systems are hard to forecast because they are so complex. Additionally, human can manage the environment, so that in many sectors a small investment in adaptation can offset the climatic changes. Moreover, the climate changes are almost certain to take place in a vastly different set of technologies and economic structures. However, we must look through the fog as best we can. One second set of findings, which many find surprising, is that managed systems are surprisingly resilient to climate changes over the coming decades. This finding applies particularly to highincome market economies with small agricultural sectors. While some might worry that this dooms poor countries to be highly vulnerable to climatic shocks, this overlooks the economic growth that underlies the projections of major climate changes. The two most populous countries of the world, with 2½ billion people, have seen their per capita incomes rise by a factor of almost 10 over the last half century. [61] Another half century of similar growth will raise the per capita incomes in India and China to around $50,000, with most people working in services and few left in agriculture. The vulnerability of poor countries to climate change in the late 21st century is likely to look completely different from today. A third major conclusion is that the most damaging impacts of climate change are likely to be in the unmanaged and unmanageable human and natural systems. We identified four areas important areas of concern – sea-level rise, tropical cyclones, ocean acidification, and loss of biodiversity. For each of these, the scale of the changes are (at least at the present time) beyond the capability of human efforts to stop. To put this in perspective, the total volume of ice in the endangered ice caps is around about 1,584,000,000,000,000,000 gallons. This is far beyond what we can easily store in some convenient location. The implications of sea-level rise and more intense hurricanes are easily comprehended, and in reality human societies can adapt to them without catastrophic losses. But the implications of ocean acidification and the potential loss of large numbers of species and of the tree of life is difficult to comprehend and impossible to value reliably. We cannot rule out the possibility that future technologies – the analogs of Bill Gates’s patent on hurricane modification – will change the outlook I-50 for these four areas. But the hurdles here are much higher than for areas which are managed systems such as health, agriculture, and security. Finally, given what we know about impacts, we want to know if there is a limit for which we can say, up to this point but no further. Scientists and policy makers at Copenhagen in 2009 determined that a temperature increase of 2 °C over pre-industrial levels was the maximum that was within the safety margin for Earth systems. What does our study of impact suggest about the Copenhagen target? My view is that the target is both too low and too high. It is too low given the identifiable damages and the high costs of attaining such an objective. But it is surely too high if we put a large weight on preventing the big four of intense hurricanes, ocean acidification, sea-level rise, and species loss – and if we believe along with many earth scientists that we have already passed the safe lower boundary for preventing these dangerous effects. I conclude, then, that the Copenhagen target is somewhere between too low and too high. So, like some murder mystery where the butler and the rich niece are both implicated in the poisoning of the rich dowager, the story is not over. The next chapter continues the drama by considering the costs of slowing climate change. We can then put together costs and benefits and propose a solution going forward to balance the twin objectives of preserving our environment for the future while economizing on losses in living standards today. I-51 Endnotes: These notes are for the curious or specialists who would like to know where the statements in the text are from or their statistical support. The Accord is found at http://unfccc.int/files/meetings/cop_15/application/pdf/cop15_cph_auv.pdf . 1 Here is a first problem with impact studies. Most studies focus on the grains such as wheat, maize, and rice. However, these represent only 15 percent of the value of production for the 20 major commodities in Africa. (See data from the Food and Agriculture Organization at http://faostat.fao.org.) So we do not really have a good sample of this very important sector. 2 Details are the following. For this example, we use the UKMO-HadGEM1 model, which is a highly resolved model. We downloaded the regional projections for 20802099 and then averaged those for the grid cells of sub-Saharan Africa. The area weighted average temperature increases were 3.40 °C for Africa and 3.43 °C for the globe. Because models tend to scale with mean temperature, we took the period for the 4 °C increase for the Yale-RICE model to be the period under consideration, which is 2120. The decline in wheat yield is estimated to be 18 percent at that temperature increase. (The compilation is provided in IPCC, Climate Change Impacts, p. 286.) African GDP is estimated to be $63.6 trillion; agriculture’s share is estimated to be 8.2 percent of GDP; wheat is estimated to be 5 percent of agriculture. [Source: wheat_africa_example.xlsx] 3 If you go through the many steps in the ABC methodology, you will suspect – quite correctly – that these results are very insecure. They do not take into account the uncertainties in the studies, or the substitution into different crops, or how much elevated levels of CO2 will fertilize different crops, or that new technologies might make wheat adaptable to the new climate. Moreover, the effect is highly non-linear, and if the temperature change is 3 °C rather than 4 °C, the estimated multiplier is zero and not negative. If you go back and look at the results, you will notice that, for every other crop and every other region, the impact multiplier is less damaging than for lowlatitude wheat. Above all, this technique cannot capture that in a world that is assumed to have dramatic technological changes, where African countries have per capita consumption equal to that in the high-income countries today, that the economy of Africa may have a completely different foundation and one in which wheat-as-weknow-it-today simply no longer is used. So while the methodology of ABC is simple in principle, impact analysis has turned out to be the most difficult area in all of climate change science. 4 I-52 The estimates were constructed as follows. The “standard run” follows the Yale-RICE model’s estimates of output growth in different countries with the associated CO2 emissions and temperature path. For the no-growth run, we assumed that population growth continues but total factor productivity remains at the 2005 level. The damage function uses the consensus estimates presented later in this chapter in Figure ?. We have fit a quadratic function to the data in the Tol survey and used that function to estimate damages. The quadratic function is that the damage/output ratio = -2.18T + 1.046 T2. 5 The conclusions about economic growth and climate change is a unanimous part of integrated assessment models and is not a peculiarity of the Yale-RICE model. Two other examples will illustrate the point. In the well-known Stern Review, which was generally thought to be very pessimistic, average output growth over the first two centuries was even more rapid than in the Yale-RICE model. Even with the damages estimated by the Stern Review, average living standards would still growth by at least a factor of more than 11. [Source: chap2_tab_nogrowth.xlsx] 6 Another example is the group of models used in the EMF-22 model comparison study (see Weyant, ???). These average of the assumed growth rates of GDP per capita over the period 2000-2100 was 1.74 percent per year. The lowest growth rate of any model for any region was 0.74 percent per year (for the U.S. by the MESSAGE model). For low-income countries, the average growth rate was assumed to be 2.3 percent per year. [Source: EMFpop gdp growth.xls] One analyst who does take this path is Herman Daly, author of The Steady State Economy. 7 8 Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Survive, Viking Press, New York, 2005 This list is primarily drawn from IPCC, Impacts 2007, with particular attention to the Summary for Policymakers and the chapter on ecosystems. The emphasis here is slightly different, however, because some of the major issues identified in that report are ones that are in fact heavily managed and seem less likely to be of long-run concern. For example, much of the work on impacts concerns agriculture, which, as noted elsewhere in this part, is increasingly managed and a declining share of economic and human activities. Similarly, the emphasis on health consequences has a very static view of the health-care system; see the discussion of health effects later in this part. Several reports also emphasize the harmful impacts of migration, whereas migration is an important safety valve to relieve regions that are harmed by income or environmental shocks. 9 I-53 [manage v unmanage.xlsx] See IPCC, Science, p. 812, Figure 10.31. The range of estimates of thermal expansion for scenario A1B is 14 to 38 cm by 2100. I suspect that a substantial part of the difference is due to differences in the temperature trajectories. 10 11 Human tide: the real migration crisis, A Christian Aid report, May 2007. Center for Naval Analyses, National Security and the Threat of Climate Change, Alexandria, VA: The CNA Corporation, 2007, available online at http://www.cna.org/nationalsecurity/climate/ (hereafter the “CNA Report”). 12 The underlying data are provided by the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis at www.bea.gov, in the industry tables at http://www.bea.gov/industry/gpotables/gpo_action.cfm. The only major decision is how to partition real estate between moderately and lightly vulnerable sectors. We assume that low-lying real estate is susceptible to storms and flooding. From our GEcon data, we estimate that 3 percent of U.S. output and population lies below 10 meters of elevation, so that is our estimate of the moderately affected share of real estate. [Source: gdp by sector.xlsx] 13 Data are from the World Bank, World Development Indicators at http://www.worldbank.org. [Source: share_ag_diff_countries.xlsx] 14 The underlying data are from the American Time Use Survey conducted by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, available at atus.bls.gov. Two areas required some supplementation. The time at work is taken from the hours engaged, from the Bureau of Economic Analysis, and uses the same industrial breakdown as in Table 1. For sports and recreation, we draw upon a Australian survey that shows participation for detailed sports, available at http://www.ausport.gov.au/__data/assets/pdf_file/0004/304384/ERASS_Report_200 8.pdf . [Source: timeuse.xlsx] 15 16 The comparison of RICE and IPCC scenarios is contained in temperature history.xlsx. These estimates are drawn from IPCC, Science 2007, Chapters 5 and 10. The estimate for the 21st century is for SRES scenario A1, Table 10.7, ibid., p. 820. Similar results are found for scenario B2. The range of models is from 0.12 to 0.32 meters over the century. 17 This is the striking title of a report by a committee of the National Academy of Sciences, Abrupt Climate Change: Inevitable Surprises, Washington, D.C., National Academy Press, 2002. 18 I-54 A description of the SLR module of the Yale-RICE model is available at http://nordhaus.econ.yale.edu/RICEmodels.htm. 19 See particularly James Hansen et al., “Target Atmospheric CO2: Where Should Humanity Aim?” The Open Atmospheric Science Journal, 2008, pp. 217- 231. 20 21 ?? A reference is missing here?? [Source: elev_gecon31_120109.wf1 for the data; program is cum_pop_gcp.prg; figure is fig_cum_alt] 22 For more information on the G-Econ data set, see gecon.yale.edu . [Source: slr_area_pop.xlsx for the tabulation; elev_gecon31_120109.wf1 for the data; programs are elev_sort.prg and country_id_dums_v3.prg] 23 This important point was uncovered in a series of pioneering studies by Gary Yohe and colleagues. See for example Gary Yohe, et al., “The economic cost of greenhouseinduced sea-level rise for developed property in the United States,” Climatic Change, 1996, pp. 1573-1480. 24 The study of ocean carbonization is a very new field. It was discovered almost by accident by Ken Caldeira about a decade ago. For those interested in the chemistry, here are the reactions: The net effect of increased CO2 is to lower the carbonate-ion (CO3 2-) concentration, and lower the saturation state of calcium carbonate (CaCO3) minerals. One of the first studies was Ken Caldeira and Michael E. Wickett, “Oceanography: Anthropogenic carbon and ocean pH,” Nature, 425, 25 September 2003, p. 365. 25 The material here draws upon my study, “The Economics of Hurricanes and Implications of Global Warming,” Climate Change Economics, vol. 1., no. 1, 2010. The important scientific studies are Kerry A. Emanuel, “The Dependence of Hurricane Intensity on Climate,” Nature, 326, April 8, 1987, pp. 483 – 485 and Thomas R. Knutson and Robert E. Tuleya, “Impact Of CO2-Induced Warming On Simulated Hurricane Intensity And Precipitation: Sensitivity To The Choice Of Climate Model And Convective Parameterization,” Journal of Climate, Vol. 17, No. 18, September 15, 2004, p. 3477-95. Similar results, including estimates for other countries, are in ???. 26 One of the earliest studies was Richard A. Feely, et al., “Impact of Anthropogenic CO2 on the CaCO3 System in the Oceans,” Science, 305, 2004, pp. 362-366. A recent nontechnical survey of the issue is in Scott C. Doney et al., “Ocean Acidification: The Other CO2 Problem,” Annual Review of Marine Science, 2009, pp. 169–92. 27 I-55 Estimates of vulnerable capital are from Nordhaus, “The Economic Impacts of Hurricanes,” op. cit. The estimates of capital stock are from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis and are available at http://www.bea.gov/national/index.htm#fixed. Depreciation rates are discussed in Barbara M. Fraumeni, “The Measurement of Depreciation in the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts,” Survey of Current Business, July 1997, pp. 7-23 available at www.bea.gov/scb/pdf/NATIONAL/NIPAREL/1997/0797fr.pdf. The methodology of replacement estimates is also used by Yohe et al., op. cit. 28 Arthur Schopenhauer, On the Basis of Morality, translation, E.F.J. Payne, Providence, RI, USA, Berghahn Books, 1955. 29 See Chris D. Thomas et al., “Extinction risk from climate change,” Nature, 8 January 2004, pp. 145-148. 30 An exemplary study that shows the methodology is Kent E. Carpenter, et al., “OneThird of Reef-Building Corals Face Elevated Extinction Risk from Climate Change and Local Impacts,” Science, 321, 2008, 560-563. 31 This is one of those statements that is widely quoted but seems to emerge from nowhere. I have seen it widely used but cannot find the original source. Many of the cites are to www.raintree.com. A query to that site produced no answer. 32 See Chris D. Thomas et al., “Extinction risk from climate change,” Nature, 8 January 2004, pp. 145-148. 33 Guy Hutton, David Schellenberg, Fabrizio Tediosi, Eusebio Macete, Elizeus Kahigwa, Betuel Sigauque, Xavier Mas, Marta Trapero, Marcel Tanner, Antoni Trilla, Pedro Alonso, and Clara Menendez “Cost-effectiveness of malaria intermittent preventive treatment in infants (IPTi) in Mozambique and the United Republic of Tanzania,” Bulletin of the World Health Organization (BLT), Volume 87, Number 2, February 2009, 123-129. Data at malaria DALY.xlsx. 34 The sources are Christopher J. L. Murray and Alan D. Lopez, Global Health Statistics, Harvard School of Public Health, and World Health Organization, 1996; data on DALYs are published by the World Health Organization and can be found at http://www.who.int/healthinfo/global_burden_disease/estimates_regional/en/index .html. A detailed discussion of the methodology is contained in Anthony J. McMichael, et al., Climate Change and Human Health: Risks and Responses, World Health Organization, Geneva, 2003. 35 I-56 The estimates were prepared as follows. We took the relative risk estimates from McMichael, et al., op. cit., for each of the major sources for 2030 and applied them to the baseline mortality risk from the WHO data cited op. cit. for 2004. We have used the temperature estimates from the RICE-Yale baseline, which reach the same temperature level in 2050 as the climate assumptions in McMichael et al., so we have labeled these as “2050 impacts.” There will be some inconsistency because that study used different assumptions about GDP growth. For each of the three diseases, we took the upper response for the “unmitigated emissions” scenario. [Source: health_impacts_v2.xlsx, sheet “Future impacts”] 36 The data on life expectancy are from the World Bank. [Source: le and pcy and temp.wf1] 37 IPCC, Impacts 2007, p. 409. This is one of many statements, some of which are inconsistent. 38 Center for Naval Analyses, National Security and the Threat of Climate Change, Alexandria, VA: The CNA Corporation, 2007, available online at http://www.cna.org/nationalsecurity/climate/ (hereafter the “CNA Report”). 39 The White House, National Security Strategy, May 2010, unclassified, available at www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/rss.../national_security_strategy.pdf. 40 These examples are drawn from the CNA report, op. cit., particularly the chapter on Direct Impacts on Military Systems, Infrastructure, and Operations. 41 This is from the thoughtful analysis by Rymn J. Parsons, “Taking up the Security Challenge of Climate Change, Strategic Studies Institute, U.S. Army War Institute, August 2009, available at www.strategicstudiesinstitute.army.mil/pdffiles/PUB932.pdf. 42 Halvard Buhaug, Nils Petter Gleditsch, and Ole Magnus Theisen, “Implications of Climate Change for Armed Conflict,” paper commissioned by the World Bank Group for the “Social Dimensions of Climate Change” workshop, The World Bank, Washington DC, 5–6 March 2008. This quotation is slightly edited for brevity. 43 See Nordhaus, Oneal, and Russett at ??. I modified the equation estimated in this study by adding dummy variables “ifdepa2” and “ifdepb2.” These variables takes a value of zero in normal times and a value of 1 if real GDP growth in the prior two years was less than -5 percent per year in each year. The specification contains growth rates 44 I-57 for each of the two countries of conflict and has 185,015 dyadic observations. The coefficient in a linear regression of the probability of conflict on various determinants had coefficients of -0.00095 ( + 0.0011) and -0.00028 ( + 0.00067) on the recession dummy variables. These coefficients are very small and statistically insignificant. On the face, they state that a sharp economic downturn in either country lowers the probability of military conflict by about 0.1 percent per year, but this is very poorly determined. The estimates are similar for different definitions of economic downturns for either 2 or 3 years and for downturns of greater than 1 to 20 percent per year. [Data set is panel3a.wf1; program is econ_distress_war.prg] Stern Review of the Economics of Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, p. 84 – 86.. 45 One of the best detailed studies of adaptation in agriculture is Norman Rosenberg, “Adaptation of agriculture to climate change,“ Climatic Change, Volume 21, Number 4, August, 1992, pp. 385-405. 46 This figure and discussion are drawn from Robert Mendelsohn, William D. Nordhaus and Daigee Shaw, “Measuring the Impact of Global Warming on Agriculture,” American Economics Review, 1996. 47 48 The plot is from IPCC, Impacts: 2007, p. 286. The reasoning is the follows. World wheat production in 2008 was 680 million metric tons, of which about 10 million tons was from Kansas. A 10 percent decline of Kansas production with a supply elasticity of 0.2 is estimated to raise prices by about ½ percent. This would raise the prices of products with wheat by less than 0.1 percent. 49 The figure shows the ratio of the price index of farm output to the price of all GDP. Data are from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, Table 1.12. [Source: q011109.wf1; Figure: fig_real_farm_p] 50 See IPCC, Impacts: 2007, p. 297. At 3 °C, 2 models showed an increase in food prices of around 15 percent, 2 models showed a decrease of around 10 percent, and 1 model showed no change. 51 The study is Richard Tol, “The Economic Impact of Climate Change,” Working Paper No. 255, Economic and Social Research Institute, Dublin, Ireland, September 2008. [source: impacts_survey.xlsx] 52 The question of risk aversion is more complicated than it would appear at first glance. The modern theory of risk holds that we will pay a risk premium to avoid losses of 53 I-58 income or consumption that occur when we are likely to be poor. This is why we buy fire insurance on our house. If our house burns down, we are not only out of a house but have lost a substantial fraction of our wealth. On the other hand, it would not be sensible to buy insurance to cover the risk that we win the lottery, which is a risk that would leave us rich. In the case of climate change, we need to consider whether the cases where we have higher damages are also associated with higher incomes. Since on the whole this is likely to be the case (see Table II-1), buying insurance against higher warming may be like buying insurance against winning the lottery. Here is an interesting definition, “Technically, an abrupt climate change occurs when the climate system is forced to cross some threshold, triggering a transition to a new state at a rate determined by the climate system itself and faster than the cause.” See National Academy of Sciences, Abrupt Climate Change: Inevitable Surprises, Washington, D.C., National Academy Press, 2002, p. 14. I am particularly grateful to Richard Alley for explaining many of these phenomena to me. 54 The statement is a slightly alteration of the original drawn from the transcript of Dornbusch’s Munich lectures, published posthumously. See Rudi Dornbusch and Stanley Fischer, “International Financial Crises” CESIFO Working Paper No. 926, Category 6: Monetary Policy And International Finance, March 2003. 55 The Dornbusch quip is actually a very deep point about catastrophic structures. We can often predict that a situation is dangerous, but we cannot predict the timing of the crash. This is why we often tip over a canoe. If the canoe’s exact tipping point were easily predictable, then we would avoid it. Note that financial crises and abrupt events are different from high tides in their intrinsic unpredictability. People often proclaim that they predicted the crisis of 2007-2009, but if you look carefully you find that they were regularly predicting crashes that did not occur. This point is captured in Paul Samuelson’s remark that the stock market predicted 9 of the last 5 recessions. 56 A useful summary of evidence is contained in Jonathan T. Overpeck, Bette L. OttoBliesner, Gifford H. Miller, Daniel R. Muhs, Richard B. Alley, and Jeffrey T. Kiehl, “Paleoclimatic Evidence for Future Ice-Sheet Instability and Rapid Sea-Level Rise,” Science, 311, 1747, 2006, pp. 1747-1750. 57 58 See the detailed analysis in IPCC, Science: 2007, particularly in section 10.3.4. 59 See IPCC, Science: 2007, Table 7.4, p. 535 and the surrounding discussion. This argument is presented in James Hansen et. al., “Target atmospheric CO2: Where should humanity aim?” Open Atmospheric Science Journal, 2008, vol. 2, pp. 217-231. 60 I-59 These data refer to India and China. According to the Penn World Table 6.3, the growth of Indian per capita real income was a factor of 4.8 from 1950 to 2007, while the growth of Chinese per capita income was a factor between 14 and 23 depending upon the measures used. Source: pcy india china.xlsx 61 I-60