CHAPTER 10 OPTIMUM OUTPUT OF A PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRM 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 1. Introduction Optimum Output Q—Total Revenue-Total Cost Approach 2.1. The Revenue Side 2.1.1. Total Revenue of a Firm Under Perfect Competition 2.1.2. Marginal Revenue of a Perfectly Competitive Firm 2.2. The Cost Side 2.3. The Optimum Q Optimum Q—Marginal Revenue-Marginal Cost Approach 3.1. Using the Average Cost Curves to Determine the Firm’s Profit 3.1.1. Case I: The Firm is Making an Economic Profit 3.1.1.1. Economic Profit Revisited 3.1.2. Case II: The Firm is Breaking Even or Making a Normal Profit 3.1.2.1. What is a Normal Profit? 3.1.3. Case III: Negative Economic Profit (Economic Loss) 3.1.3.1. Should the Firm Shut Down when Incurring an Economic Loss? 3.1.4. Case IV: Economic Loss—Shut-Down Case Marginal Cost—the Firm’s Short-Run Supply Curve Industry (Market) Supply and Market Demand 5.1. Market Equilibrium Price and Quantity 5.2. Economic Profits will Attract More Resources to the Industry 5.3. Entry of New Firms and Disappearance of Economic Profit Long-Run Industry Supply—How Resources Are Allocated Under Perfect Competition 6.1. Long-Run Industry Supply—Constant Cost Industry 6.2. Long-Run Industry Supply—Increasing Cost Industry Efficiency of Perfect Competition Introduction The firm’s function in the market place is to supply goods and services, and the only incentive for the firm to continue production is making a profit. The firm’s profit is the difference between its receipts from selling the products (total revenue) and the cost of producing them (total cost). The firm, in fact, is not just interested in making a profit. The rational-behavior assumption requires that the firm maximize its profits. The firm’s total revenue and total cost are both a function of the level of output Q, the quantity it produces and sells in the marketplace. To maximize profits, therefore, the firm must determine the optimum or profit-maximizing (and in some cases, loss minimizing) level of output. The firm’s optimum output level can be determined in two ways: (1) the Total Revenue-Total Cost approach; and (2) Marginal Revenue-Marginal Cost approach. The two should result in the same optimum Q. As by now you should recognize, the marginal approach is the preferred one. That is the one which will be used in subsequent analyses of the behavior of the firm. 2. Optimum Output Q—Total Revenue-Total Cost Approach 2.1. The Revenue Side The firm is interested in maximizing its profits. Profit is defined as the difference between total revenue and total cost: π = TR − TC. The firm’s total revenue is simply the product of price times the quantity produced and sold. 1 TR = P × Q 2.1.1. Total Revenue of a Firm Under Perfect Competition What is perfect competition? When discussing the firm’s revenue, it is very important to recognize a central assumption about the nature of the firm, the context in which the firm operates. The firm discussed in this chapter is a representative firm in a perfectly competitive industry. Economists use a specific set of criteria to provide a precise definition of “perfect competition”, or a “perfectly competitive industry”. These criteria are: In a perfectly competitive industry, There are large number of firms. And, because there are many firms, each firm's output is a very small fraction of the total output of the whole industry. All firms produce a homogeneous or standardized product. One firm's product cannot be distinguished from another's. Farmer Smith’s wheat is the same as farmer Jones’ wheat. All firms are price takers. Each firm must abide by the price dictated by the market. A representative firm cannot raise its price simply because no one will buy from it. There are other suppliers readily available who sell the product at the going lower price. And it would not lower its price below the market price because it can sell all it produces at the going higher market price—unless, of course, the owner of the firm is nuts. This is why a perfectly competitive firm is said to be a "price taker". There are no barriers to entry of new firms to the industry. If there are profit opportunities in the industry, new firms will enter the industry to take advantage of the higher (economic) profit. Also firms can freely exit the industry, if there are better opportunities to use the resources somewhere else, that is, if the opportunity cost of remaining in the industry becomes too high. Because the firm in a perfectly competitive industry is a price taker, to increase its revenue, it is free only to change the quantity variable Q in the total revenue function TR = P∙Q . Price P is therefore a parameter dictated to the firm by the market; it cannot adjust it at will. 2.1.2. Marginal Revenue of a Perfectly Competitive Firm Marginal revenue (MR) is the revenue earned from each additional unit of output sold. Note that for a competitive firm, who must "take" the price dictated by the market, and can sell any number of units at that price, marginal revenue is always equal to price. This important feature of marginal revenue for a perfectly competitive firm can be shown by the fact that MR is the derivative of the linear TR function with respect to quantity. TR = PQ MR = dTR =P dQ Let, for example, P = $50. Then the derivative of TR = 50Q with respect to Q is MR = 50. Also note that, since TR = PQ is a linear function, the derivative of TR, MR, is also the slope of the TR function. MR = dTR TR = dQ Q Table 10-1 shows the firm’s total revenue and marginal revenue for various levels of output 2 Q P TR 0 $50 $0 1 50 50 2 50 100 3 50 150 4 50 200 5 50 250 6 50 300 Table 10-1. Marginal revenue schedule of a perfectly competitive firm Because a perfectly competitive firm is a price taker, and each additional unit is sold at the going market price, marginal revenue is always equal to the price. MR $50 50 50 50 50 50 Figure 10-1 shows the graph of the TR and MR curves. 350 TR = PQ Marginal Revenue (dollars) Total Revenue (dollars) 300 250 200 ∆TR = 50 150 ∆Q = 1 100 Slope = ∆TR ⁄ ∆Q = 50 = P 50 50 MR = P 0 0 1 2 3 Q 4 5 6 0 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Q Figure 10-1. Total Revenue Curve and Marginal Revenue Curve of a Perfectly Competitive Firm Since a perfectly competitive firm can sell its output only at the going market price, each additional unit would earn a marginal revenue which is equal to price. The MR curve is the constant slope of the linear TR curve. Note that the TR curve is a linear curve rising with the number of units produced and sold. Marginal revenue, however, is a horizontal line because the price for each additional unit (revenue received for each additional unit) sold remains at the given market price level of $50. We will use both the TR and MR curves in determining how a representative competitive firm maximizes its profit. As mentioned, profit is the difference between TR and TC. We looked at TR. Now consider the firm's TC schedule or TC curve. 3 2.2. The Cost Side In the previous chapter we learned that the firm's total cost (TC) is the sum of its total fixed cost (TFC) and total variable cost (TVC). TC = TFC + TVC All cost schedules are related to (are functions of) the output level Q. Consider Bob’s perfectly competitive firm in the schmoo industry with the following cubic total variable cost function: TVC = 50Q − 12Q² + Q³ Let TFC = $100. Then, TC = TFC + TVC = 100 + 50Q − 12Q² + Q³ Using the above cost function, Table 10-2 shows the cost figures for different levels of output. Also, assuming the market price of schmoo of P = $50, the TR column in Table 10-2 shows Bob’s total revenue. Q 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 2.3. TVC $0 39 60 69 72 75 84 105 144 207 300 429 TC $100 139 160 169 172 175 184 205 244 307 400 529 TR = 50Q $0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 550 π = TR − TC -$100 -89 -60 -19 28 75 116 145 156 143 100 21 Table 10-2. Total variable cost, total cost, total revenue, and economic profit The figures in the TVC column are obtained using the cubic function TVC = 50Q − 12Q² + Q³ The TC column provides the total cost data. It is obtained by adding the fixed cost of $100 to TVC at each output level. Total revenue is TR = 50Q, where P = $50 is dictated by the market to the firm. The difference between TR and TC shown as π = TR – TC is the profit equation. The Optimum Q The firm maximizes profit by comparing TR to TC. The output level at which the difference between TR and TC is at its maximum is the optimum output level. In Table 10-2 the highlighted optimum output level is Q = 8, at which profit is maximized at π = 400 − 244 = 156. Using simple calculus we can determine the optimum output from the profit equation or function π = TR – TC. Given the total cost and total revenue functions above, first determine the profit function. TC = 100 + 50Q − 12Q² + Q³ TR = 50Q π = TR − TC π = 50Q – (100 + 50Q – 12Q² + Q³) π = −100 + 12Q² − Q³ To maximize the profit function, set the first derivative of the profit function with respect to Q equal to zero. dπ = 24Q − 3Q² dQ 4 24Q − 3Q² = 0 Q(24 – 3Q) = 0 24 – 3Q = 0 Q=8 You may also use the quadratic formula to find the value for Q from 3Q² − 24Q = 0. Q= 24 242 4 3 0 =8 23 The maximum profit is then: π = 50(8) − 100 − 50(8) + 12(8)² − (8)³ = 156 Figure 10-2 shows that the vertical difference between TR and TC is the largest at Q = 8. 600 Figure 10-2. Optimum Quantity Total Cost and Total Revenue (dollars) 550 TR TC 500 450 400 400 350 Optimum quantity is the output level at which profit , π = TR − TC, is maximized. Profit is maximized where the vertical gap between TR and TC is the largest. Mathematically this occurs where the slope of the line tangent to the TC curve is parallel to the TR line. 300 250 244 200 150 100 50 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Q 3. Optimum Q—Marginal Revenue-Marginal Cost Approach The more prevalent method to find the theoretical profit maximizing level of output of a firm in economics is to use the marginal revenue-marginal cost approach. Figure 10-2 already provides the background for the MR-MC approach. In Figure 10-2 note that the gap between MR and MC is maximum when the slope of the linear MR function is equal to the slope of the line tangent to the TC curve—that is, when the TR line is parallel to the tangent line. Mathematically speaking, the slope of a continuous function at any given point is the first derivative of the function at that point. Since TR is a linear function, the slope of TR is constant at any point along the straight line. The slope of the TC function, represented by the slope of line tangent to the TC function, however, varies along the curve. We learned that the slope of the TR function is the marginal revenue, and the slope of the line tangent to the TC curve is the marginal cost (the derivative of the TC function). In order for the slopes of the two functions to be the same, then marginal revenue must equal to marginal cost. We have already learned that in the marginalist approach to optimization marginal cost must equal marginal benefit for the optimum choice. The choice decision here is: what quantity is the optimum quantity? The firm 5 must determine if any additional output would add to the total profit or reduce it. The firm must weigh the revenue against the cost arising from the additional output, that is, the firm must compare the marginal revenue against marginal cost. If MR from the additional output exceeds the MC, then the firm will increase output. The optimum is Q achieved when MR = MC. As explained above, for a perfectly competitive firm, marginal revenue is always equal to the price: MR = P Thus, the optimality condition for a perfectly competitive firm can be stated as: P = MC Knowing this, now we can show how the MR-MC approach can be used to determine the firm’s optimal output. Table 10-3 compares the total revenue-total cost approach to the marginal revenue-marginal cost approach. MC Q 0 TC $100 TR $0 π = TR − TC -$100 dTC ⁄ dQ $50 1 139 50 -89 29 ∆TC ⁄ ∆Q MR = P $50 $39 50 21 2 160 100 -60 14 3 169 150 -19 5 50 9 50 3 4 172 200 28 2 50 3 5 175 250 75 5 6 184 300 116 14 50 9 50 21 7 205 350 145 29 50 39 8 244 400 156 50 50 63 9 307 450 143 77 50 93 10 400 500 100 110 50 Table 10-3. The optimum output of a perfectly competitive firm The optimum Q is that which maximizes the firm’s profit. If (theoretically) output is measured in very small or fractional scale, then we can use the first derivative of the TC as the MC function. Then the optimum Q is achieved when MC is exactly equal to MR or price. If output is increased in discrete scale, then MC is measured as ∆TC ⁄ ∆Q. In that case the optimum Q is achieved when the positive difference between MR and MC is the smallest. As the table shows, both approaches provide an identical optimum Q = 8 units. Note again that when the gap between TR and TC is at its maximum (maximum profit), the positive difference between MR and MC is at its minimum. When the firm is producing less than 8 units, it would make sense to increase output because the price received (MR) exceeds the cost (MC) of the producing the additional unit. This holds until the output level Q = 8 is 6 reached. At this point the total profit is $156, the maximum value in the profit column. Any further increase in Q will entail a marginal cost which is greater than marginal revenue. The profit level will then fall from the maximum of $156. If output could be measured on a small, fractional scale, that is, if Q were divisible into very small units, then the ultimate optimality condition, MR = MC can be achieved. The MR = MC optimum condition can be determined algebraically and shown graphically. We know MR and MC are each the first derivative of, respectively, TR and TC functions. We can therefore find these derivatives, set them equal, and solve for Q. TR = 50Q TC = 100 + 50Q − 12Q2 + Q3 dTR = 50 dQ dTC MC = = 50 − 24Q + 3Q2 dQ MR = MR = MC 50 = 50 − 24Q + 3Q2 3Q2 − 24Q = 0 Using the quadratic formula, the optimum Q is: Q= 24 24 2 4 3 0 =8 23 Figure 10-3 shows that both TR-TC and MR-MC yield the same optimum, profit maximizing, level of output. 7 600 Total Cost and Total Revenue (dollars) 550 TR TC 500 Figure 10-3. Optimum quantity--TR/TC versus MR/MC In the lower panel, the optimum output level is where MR = MC. The same optimum output level in the upper panel provides that the gap between TR and TC is the largest. 450 400 400 350 300 250 244 200 150 100 50 0 Marginal cost and marginal revenue (dollars) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Q 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 MC MR 0 3.1. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Q Using the Average Cost Curves to Determine the Firm’s Profit To use the MR-MC approach we need to include the other components of the model that are needed to compute the firm’s profit or, as it may happen, losses. These components are the Average Total Cost (ATC) and the Average Variable Cost (AVC). If the price at which each unit is sold (average revenue) is greater than ATC, then the firm would be earning an economic profit. If it is lower than ATC, then the firm is incurring an economic loss. Furthermore, as will be shown below, when the firm is incurring an economic loss, AVC will determine whether the firm should continue operating even with a loss, or if it should shut down immediately. Sounds complicated? Don’t worry, it will all be clear. 8 3.1.1. Case I: The Firm is Making an Economic Profit Looking at the firm’s revenue/cost situation from the average, rather than total, perspective, the firm’s operations are profitable if the price exceeds average total cost of producing the optimum quantity. In table 10-4, the optimum quantity, where MC = P = $50, is Q = 8. At that output level ATC = $30.50. Therefore the firm is making a profit of $50 − $30.50 = $19.50 per unit. The total profit is the $19.50 × 8 = $156. Q 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 TC $100 139 160 169 172 175 184 205 244 307 400 ATC MC $50 29 14 5 2 5 14 29 50 77 110 $139.00 80.00 56.33 43.00 35.00 30.67 29.29 30.50 34.11 40.00 P $50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 Table 10-4. Comparing ATC to price—economic profit per unit At the optimum quantity of Q = 8, the firm’s ATC is $30.50, compared to the price $50. The firm is making a profit of $19.50 per unit, for a total profit of: $19.50 × 8 = $156 Figure 10-4 shows ATC, and MC curves on the cost side, and the horizontal MR = P curve on the revenue side. As the diagram shows, the firm’s optimum output is Q = 8 units. This output is determined by the intersection of the MR = P curve with MC. The firm sells each unit of output for $50. Therefore, its revenue per unit (or average revenue) is $50, At Q = 8, ATC is $30.50 (see Table 10-4). The difference between ATC and price is the firm’s profit per unit or average profit: $50 − $30.5 = $19.2. Total profit, π = $19.5 × 8 = $156, is shown as the area of the rectangle ABCD. Marginal Cost and Marginal Revenue (dollars) 160 150 140 MC 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 A 40 30 D MR = P B ATC C 20 10 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Q 9 Figure 10-4. The firm earns an economic profit if P > ATC At the optimum quantity of Q = 8, the price the firm receives (point B) exceeds the ATC (point C). Profit per unit is BC = P − ATC. Total profit is the area of the rectangle ABCD, 3.1.1.1. Economic Profit Revisited In Figure 10-4, when the MR = P line intersects the MC curve at a point above the minimum ATC, the firm is making an economic profit. Why the term “economic” profit? The meaning of economic profit is that the return to the resources allocated for the production of the good in question is above the return on any other alternative allocation. You may interpret economic profit in the following way as well: The opportunity cost of allocating the firm’s resources to the good in question is the return forgone from the allocation to the next best alternative good. Economic profit, therefore, means that the return on the existing allocation exceeds its opportunity cost. 3.1.2. Case II: The Firm is Breaking Even or Making a Normal Profit Marginal Cost and Marginal Revenue (dollars) When the price is equal to the minimum average total cost, then MC intersect MR = P at ATCMIN. In this situation the firm is making zero economic profit. The firm is said to be breaking even. Figure 10-5 represents the breakeven optimum output. The optimum output is Q = 7, where P = MC = ATCMIN = $29.3. When the optimum output is at the break-even point, the firm is said to be making a normal profit. 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 MC Figure 10-5. The break-even case—the firm earns zero economic profit, but earns normal profit At the optimum quantity of Q = 7, the price the firm receives is equal to ATC. The economic profit is, therefore, zero. However, the firm is earning a normal profit. Normal profit means a fair return on the economic activity; a return no greater than that could be earned in the next best alternative. ATC MR = P 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Q 3.1.2.1. What is a Normal Profit? When the return on the existing allocation is equal to its opportunity cost, that is, when it is equal to the return on the next best alternative allocation, the firm is making a normal profit. This is the return on investment that should keep the owner of the firm satisfied. This means that the owners of the firm could do no better; they are earning a fair return on their activity. 10 3.1.3. Case III: Negative Economic Profit (Economic Loss) MC, MR, ATC, AVC (dollars) When price is below the minimum ATC, the firm is not covering all of its costs. Therefore, the firm is incurring an economic loss, meaning that the return on the activity is less than the return on the next best alternative. Or, the return on the allocation of resources on the current activity is less than its opportunity cost. Figure 10-6 shows the economic loss case. 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 MC ATC AVC MR = P 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Figure 10-6. The economic loss case. At the optimum quantity of Q = 6.4, the price the firm receives is less than ATC. The firm is incurring an economic loss. However, the firm should continue to operate because it is covering part of its fixed costs or long-term unavoidable obligations. Consider the TR and TC in the diagram: TR = $20 × 6.4 = $128 TC = $30 × 6.4 = $192 π = TR − TC = −$64 If the firm shuts down, it still would have to cover its fixed costs of $100. So by shutting down it would incur a loss of $100, rather than $64 if it continues to operate. 10 11 12 Q An interesting and a very important question arises when the firm is incurring an economic loss: 3.1.3.1. Should the Firm Shut Down when Incurring an Economic Loss? Since the return on the activity is less than the opportunity cost of the activity, should the firm shut down and allocate its resources to an alternative which has a higher return? The answer in this case is no. It should continue the operation in the short run. Why? The answer to this question lies in the firm’s fixed cost. The firm’s total fixed cost, as we already know is $100. If the firm shuts down it will still have to cover its contractual obligations. If it continues to operate, not only it will cover its variable (or operating) costs, but it will also recover part of the fixed cost, thus minimizing its losses. In Figure 10-6, the price is P = $20, at which the optimum quantity is Q = 6.4 units (fractional units are permitted in this example). The firm’s total revenue is $20 × 6.4 = $128. Given the ATC of $30, the total cost is $30 × 6.4 = $192. The economic loss is $128 − $192 = −$64. Since the loss is less than the fixed cost, the firm is covering a portion of its fixed cost contractual obligations ($100 − $64 = $36). If the firm shuts down it will not be able to recover this portion of the fixed costs. So its loss would be much greater. When price is below the ATCMIN but above the AVCMIN, the firm is making an operating profit. As long as the firm covers all of its variable costs (is making an operating profit) and recovers any part of its fixed costs, it should continue to operate until the fixed costs are completely covered, and then shut down and exit the industry. 11 3.1.4. Case IV: Economic Loss—Shut-Down Case When price falls so low that it is below the minimum average variable cost (AVCMIN), then the firm is unable to fully pay for its variable inputs and, therefore, should shut down immediately. In Figure 10-7 the price of P = $10 is below the firm’s minimum average variable cost. The economic loss is computed as follows: TR = $10 × 5.6 = $56 TC = $32 × 5.6 = $179.2 π = TR − TC = −$123.2 MC, MR, ATC, AVC (dollars) If the firm continues to operate, its total loss will be −$123.2. If it shuts down immediately, its total loss would be limited to its total fixed cost of $100. 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 MC ATC AVC Figure 10-7. The shut-down case. When the price is below the AVC, the firm should shut down. If the firm shuts down, its economic loss would be limited to the total fixed cost—Here TFC = $100. If it does not shut down, not only the firm does not cover any of its fixed costs, but also is unable to cover all of its operating (variable) costs. In the diagram: TR = $10 × 5.6 = $56 TC = $32 × 5.6 = $179.2 π = TR − TC = −$123.2 MR = P 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Q 4. Marginal Cost—the Firm’s Short-Run Supply Curve As was repeatedly shown above, the firm determines the optimum level of output where the price line intersects MC. Recall, from Chapter 3, that the supply curve was defined as various quantities of a good a firm is willing and able to produce at different prices, ceteris paribus. Now you can see that the amount the firm is willing and able to produce (the amount which would maximize profits or minimize losses) at different prices is determined by the firm’s marginal cost curve. Thus, the firm’s short-run supply curve is the same as its MC curve. As shown in Figure 10-8, when looking at the MC curve as the firm’s supply curve, you should note that only the part of the MC curve that lies above the minimum AVC constitutes the firm’s supply curve. It was just explained that when the price is less than the minimum AVC the firm should produce nothing and shut down. 12 MC, MR, ATC, AVC (dollars) 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 MC = S P₂ Figure 10-8. The firm's supply curve is its marginal cost curve. The firm's supply curve is the MC curve above the minimum AVC. Once the price falls below P₀, the shut-down point, losses exceed fixed costs and the firm shuts down. If the price is P₁ = $50, the quantity supplied is 8. If the price rises to P₂, quantity supplied will increase to 10. P₁ AVC P₀ 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Q 5. Industry (Market) Supply and Market Demand 5.1. Market Equilibrium Price and Quantity In Figure 10-9 the industry supply is shown as the horizontal sum of the MC curves of all the firms operating this perfectly competitive industry. The industry (or market) supply together with the market demand determine the market equilibrium price and quantity. The market equilibrium is the signal received by individual firms, according to which each firm determines the optimum quantity it should produce. The independent decisions of all the firms, along with the independent decisions of the buyers on the demand side, generates the equilibrium price. This price is the benchmark which determines the optimum output of each firm. The essence of perfect competition is that each individual firm has no influence on the price by itself. All firms are price takers. 5.2. Economic Profits will Attract More Resources to the Industry In Figure 10-9, the equilibrium price is above the ATCMIN. The representative firm is therefore making an economic profit, shown as the shaded rectangle. Will this economic profit last for long? The answer is no. The representative firm earns an economic profit only in the short-run. Here is where another one of the features of a perfectly competitive industry comes into play. There are no barriers for the outside firms to enter this industry. High economic profits will soon attract resources from elsewhere. What is the result? The answer is what comes next. 13 160 $ 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Firm MC $ Economic profit ATC AVC 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11Q 12 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Industry S D 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 Q8000 Figure 10-9. Industry supply is the horizontal sum of the MC curves of all the firms in this industry. With the industry supply of S and the market demand of D, the equilibrium market quantity is 3,600 and the equilibrium price is $80. At this price the representative firm is making and economic profit. 5.3. Entry of New Firms and Disappearance of Economic Profit When the representative firm is making an economic profit, the return on the resources in the industry is higher than the return on the resources is in the alternative industries. If resources are free to move, they always go where the profit is higher. If the profits are higher in the schmoo industry than in the gizmo industry, then resources will flow from gizmo to schmoo industry. As shown in Figure 10-10, the flow of resources into the schmoo industry will shift the schmoo industry supply to the right, thus reducing the price of schmoos. The fall in prices will gradually squeeze the economic profit out until all economic profits are eliminated and only normal profits remain. Thus, the return on resources in the schmoo industry fall to the same level as that in the gizmo industry. 14 160 $ 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Firm MC $ ATC AVC 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11Q 12 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Industry S₀ S₁ D 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 Q8000 Figure 10-10. Long run industry equilibrium--zero economic profit for the representative firm. Referring back to Figure 10-9, at the equilibrium price of $80 the representative firm is making an economic profit. This will attract new firms to the industry. The industry supply will shift to the right, bringing the equilibrium price down to where it is equal to the ATC MIN of the representative firm. Once the zero economic profit equilibrium price is reached entry of new firms will stop. The representative firm will make a normal profit. 6. Long-Run Industry Supply—How Resources Are Allocated Under Perfect Competition The theoretical appeal of the perfectly competitive model rests on the notion of “efficiency of perfect competition”. To get to this, first let’s consider how firms in the perfectly competitive schmoo industry respond to market signals, and how the firms’ response leads to allocation of resource from one industry to another. This signal is nothing other than the change in the price of schmoo. In Figure 10-11 Panel (a), Bob’s perfectly competitive firm is responding to the price of $55 determined in the schmoo market in Panel (b) by the intersection of D₀ and S₀ at point A. At the price of $55, given Bob’s MC schedule, he will produce 8.2 units of schmoos per period. Since the market price is equal to Bob’s minimum ATC, he is making a normal (zero economic) profit. At this stage the market is in a stable equilibrium and the representative firm is breaking even. Now suppose schmoos become popular among consumers, causing the demand to increase, shift to the right, from D₀ to D₁. Given the industry supply, which is the sum of existing firm’s short-run marginal cost curves, the increase in demand will push the price schmoos up to $100, the intersection S₀ and D₁ at point B. Bob and other existing firms in the schmoo industry will enjoy a high economic profit, because price is significantly higher than the ATC. However, the market equilibrium at point B is not permanent. Firms outside the schmoo industry will be attracted to the high economic profits in the schmoo industry. Since there are no barriers to entry, there will then be a steady inflow of new firms to the schmoo industry. In Panel (b), the inflow of new firms to the schmoo industry will shift the industry supply from S₀ steadily forward to its final location of S₁. The intersection of S₁ and D₁ at point C will now result in a new equilibrium price and quantity. Note that the new equilibrium price at point C is the same as that at point A. The market equilibrium quantity has increased to about 8,200. In Panel (c), Bob’s (the representative firm) output shrinks back to the original level of 8.2 units as the price falls from $100 back to the original break-even equilibrium level of $55. 15 Panel (a) Bob's Firm 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Panel (b) Industry MC 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 ATC 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 7 8 9 10 11 1 S₁ S₀ 2 B A C LRIS D₁ D₀ 0 2000 4000 6000 8000 10000 Panel (c) Bob's Firm 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 MC ATC 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Figure 10-11. Long Run Industry Supply--Constant Cost Industry. Panel (b) shows the supply and demand in the schmoo industry. With D₀ and S₀, the equilibrium price is $55 and the market equilibrium quantity is 4,800. At this price, in Panel (a) Bob, the representative firm, is breaking even. With demand increasing to D₁, the equilibrium price rises to $100. At this price, Bob and all the existing firms will increase their output from 8.2 to 9.7. Now Bob is making an economic profit. The economic profit will attract new firms to the schmoo industry pushing the supply to the right. In Panel (b) supply shi fts from S₀ to S₁. At the intersection of D₁ and S₁, the new equilibrium price is back to $55. The market equilibrium is 8,200. In Panel (c), the falling price forces Bob to cut his production back to 8.2 units. The long run industry supply (LRIS) is obtain by connecting points A and C in Panel (b). LRIS is perfectly elastic. This indicates that the industry is a constant cost industry. The entry of new firms has not caused the price of factor inputs to rise, keeping the cost curves of the representative firm the same as before. 6.1. Long-Run Industry Supply—Constant Cost Industry Going back to Panel (b) in Figure 10-11, the industry’s original equilibrium at point A was disturbed by an increase in demand from D₀ to D₁. The high new equilibrium price at the intersection of D₁ and S₀ (point B) signaled outside firms to enter the schmoo industry pushing the supply rightward to S₁. Thus, a new lower equilibrium price is established at the intersection of S₁ and D₁ (point C). The line connecting point A and C depicts the long-run industry supply (LRIS) curve. Here the long run industry supply curve is perfectly elastic. When the LRIS is horizontal, the industry is called a constant cost industry. What does this mean? A constant cost industry is a situation where as new firms enter the industry in response to a higher return, they bring all the required resources or factor inputs with them. The existing firms, therefore, do not encounter a rise in the price of factor inputs. Their costs thus remain unchanged or constant. 6.2. Long-Run Industry Supply—Increasing Cost Industry In some cases, as new firms enter the industry to take advantage of high profits, the new entrants must compete with the existing firms for some factor inputs, thus bidding up the price of that input. For example, as the demand for wine increases, pushing up the price of wine, more wineries will open up. However, the supply of land suitable for vineyards may be limited. The price of vineyards thus will be bid up. Rent on land, as an implicit or explicit cost of production, will rise, pushing up the production cost schedules for both the new and existing wineries. In Figure 10-12, in Panel (b), the rise in demand for schmoos from D₀ to D₁ has pushed the price up to from $55 to $100. New firms enter, pushing the industry supply to the right. However, unlike the constant-cost industry case, the supply does shift far enough to lower the new equilibrium price back to $55. Instead, the new equilibrium (point C) is established at price of $80. The reason for the comparatively higher price at point C can be observed from the behavior of the individual firm’s cost curves in Panel (c). As the entry of new firms bid up the price of factor inputs, the representative firm’s cost curves shift upward. The break-even price where the economic profit is zero is achieved at a higher minimum ATC. 16 The long-run industry supply curve, obtain by connecting points A and C in Panel (b) is no longer perfectly elastic; it slopes upward. MC 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 ATC 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 S₀ S₁ 2 1 LRIS B C A D₁ D₀ 0 2000 4000 6000 8000 10000 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 MC₁ MC ATC₁ ATC 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Figure 10-12. Long Run Industry Supply--Increasing Cost Industry. Panel (b) shows the supply and demand in the schmoo industry. With D₀ and S₀, the equilibrium price is $55 and the market equilibrium quantity is 4,800. At this price, in Panel (a) Bob, the representative firm, is breaking even. With demand increasing to D₁, the equilibrium price rises to $100. At this price, Bob and all the existing firms will incr ease their output from 8.2 to 9.7. Now Bob is making an economic profit. The economic profit will attract new firms to the schmoo industry pushing the supply to the right. In Panel (b) supply shi fts from S₀ to S₁. At the intersection of D₁ and S₁, the new equilibrium price is about $80. The market equilibrium is about 7, 000. In Panel (c), Bob's cost curves have shifted higher because the entry of new firms into the industry has bid the price of factor inputs up. Bob's new break-even output is slightly higher than the previous break-even output. The long run industry supply (LRIS) is obtain by connecting points A and C in Panel (b). LRIS is upward sloping. This indicates that the industry is and increasing cost industry. The entry of new firms has bid the price of factor inputs up, raising the cost curves of the representative firm. 7. Efficiency of Perfect Competition In the discussion of the long-run industry supply we observed how under perfect competition the free movement of firms leads to the allocation of resources in different industries. Note that the initial equilibrium in the schmoo industry [point A in Panel (a) of Figure 10-11 or Figure 10-12] was disturbed by change in demand. This change in demand reflects the consumers’ preference. The producers respond to this change in consumer preference by allocating more resources to the production of schmoo. The schmoo industry or market finally settles at a new equilibrium point C. Let us observe some important features of the industry at this point. P = MC. In a perfectly competitive market, the equilibrium price equals marginal cost. We learned that the industry supply S₁ is the combination of the marginal cost curves of all the firms in that industry. At the intersection of D₁ and S₁ the price consumers are paying for schmoos is equal to the marginal cost of producing that quantity of schmoos. This indicates that the right (optimal) amount of schmoos is being produced. Note that the price consumers are willing to pay reflects the value they place or benefit they receive from consuming the marginal unit (MB). If an amount lower than the equilibrium quantity of schmoos is produced, marginal benefit would exceed marginal cost. Total benefit to consumers would increase if more was produced. If price is less than marginal cost, then marginal cost exceeds the marginal benefit. Total benefit would increase by producing less. Thus, the optimum quantity is that at which MB = P = MC. P = ATCMIN. The quantity produced in the perfectly competitive market is not only optimal, but also is produced at the lowest per unit cost possible, given the existing technology. The efficiency criterion P = MC is also indicative of the fact that under perfect competition total surplus, consumer surplus plus producer surplus, is maximized. All willing buyers and willing sellers have the opportunity for transaction. No mutually beneficial transactions remain unfulfilled. And, one last point about the efficiency of perfect competition: there is no deadweight loss of consumer and producer surplus. 17