Emissions Trading To Reduce Urban Ozone: The Chicago Area ERMS Program Richard F. Kosobud, Houston H. Stokes, and Carol D. Tallarico, Dept. of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago. Contents 1 Introduction 2 Summary of Results 3 Outline of the Study 4 How the ERMS Cap-and Trade Market Works 5 The Theory of Cap-and-Trade Market Incentives Applied to the Urban Scene Figure 1a Price determination and cost savings with a homogenous pollutant Figure 1b Price determination and cost savings with heterogeneous pollutants 6 Modeling Spatially Heterogeneous Pollutants 7 The Required Databases 8 Empirical Implementation of the Model 9 The Performance of the ERMS Cap-and-Trade Market Table 1 Prices, Trades, and Cost Savings for Varying VOM Reduction Rates Figure 2a Rates of Reduction, Cost Savings, and Trades Plotted Figure 2b Variance of Costs, Trades, and Cost Savings Plotted Table 2 Changes in Control Costs, Trades, and Cost Savings Table 3 Transactions Costs, Trades, and Cost Savings Table 4 Prices, Trades, and Cost Savings in an Auction Market Variant Figure 3a Individual Firm Trades Under Free Allocation Figure 3b Individual Firm Trades Under an Auction Market Table 5 Affects of Spatial Restrictions on Market Trading 10 Conclusion and Research Directions Appendix A. Implementation Procedures for the Model References 1 1. Introduction The government is confronted with difficult regulatory choices in controlling numerous air pollutants, ranging from volatile organic compounds to particulates and sulfur dioxide. Difficulties arise in devising control policies because these pollutants differ in the harms they cause and the costs of their control. Difficulties are compounded because air pollutants also differ by location of their emissions giving rise to varying exposures to sensitive populations. The regulator cannot rely on established estimates of marginal benefits and costs of reduction for optimal control of each and every emission, wherever it occurs, because these estimates are unavailable in the great majority of cases, or not permitted by legislation. These constraints are not likely to change in the foreseeable future. However, there is no escaping government responsibility for control of numerous air pollutants as the prevalent belief is that poor air quality comes as close as one can find to a pure public good with an army of polluters and a host of sufferers. One approach, at the policy level, is to establish a politically determined cap on pollutant emissions rather than attempt an estimate, based on limited or nonexistent data, of the benefit-cost level of emissions. In this approach emitters of pollutants are delegated the specific control decisions to be made under economic incentives while the government retains the right to set the cap, allocated tradable credits, and monitor the market. This study investigates this approach in the case of a pioneering application of a cap-andtrade market variant of emissions trading that has been designed as one of the measures to reduce urban ozone in the Chicago region. Our method of investigation is to model the cost-minimizing responses of stationary source emitters of volatile organic compounds or material (VOM) to market incentives given an aggregate cap on emissions in an effort to compare the cost-effectiveness of emissions trading as an alternative to traditional regulation. The region is a severe non-attainment area with respect to nationally established ozone standards, which means that Chicago’s air has found to be below these standards during prior summer seasons. The model is developed based upon existing rules of the cap-and-trade market, upon prior studies of actual marginal control costs for emitters, and upon actual allocations of tradable credits and historic emissions. The model then simulates or predicts transactions based upon the key assumption of cost minimizing behavior in an ideal market setting. Observed transactions to test the model are unlikely to become available for several years after the start-up date of the year 2000. Furthermore, the market may be operating below its potential for an even longer period for reasons to be explained shortly. Consequently, the objectives of this study are to: a. Estimate, within the model confines, the cost-effectiveness of emissions trading compared with traditional regulation in this innovative market incentive system; b. Prepare a model framework for future comparisons, or tests, with observed data; c. And, highlight critical areas deserving more research if the model’s predictions diverge from observed data. 2 Note it may not be a matter of judging the model right or wrong, but of evaluating reasons why the observed transactions differ from predicted. Such reasons could include learning behavior, concern about public acceptance of pollutant trading, transactions costs, and the like. A carefully prepared framework can advance later study of these issues. We also will indicate how this framework could be extended to consider issues of environmental justice. Research on emissions trading has burgeoned in recent years as applications of this incentive scheme have increased. Stavins (1995) has introduced transactions costs into the emissions trading framework; Montero (1997) has considered transactions costs and uncertainty with respect to regulatory approval of trades; and Mendelsohn (1986) has analyzed spatial emissions of sulfur dioxide in a trading setting. Tolley et al. (1993) have studied reasons for caution in applying emissions trading to urban ozone control. This study is the first we know of that develops a model to analyze a specific application of emissions trading to control of volatile organic compounds, a precursor of urban ozone control. We now proceed to a brief presentation of the results achieved, then to a brief description of the features of this innovative market incentive scheme, and next to an explanation of the specification of the model. This is followed by a description of the key databases, an account of the quantitative methods used to obtain empirical results, a more detailed explanation of the results, and finally a discussion of further research open up by this study. 2. Summary of Results We first assume emissions to become uniformly mixed concentrations over an unconstrained urban market area with resulting uniform harms to the population. In this case the model generates, with a cap-and-trade market in place, substantial cost savings that could be realized under unrestricted emissions trading compared with traditional or command-and-control (CAC) regulation. An advantage of our flexible model is that it enables us to carry out scenario experiments with alternate parameter values and emission targets to gauge the outcomes on the prices and quantities of trades, and on cost savings. Some of these scenarios would be very difficult, if not politically impossible, to carry out as trial runs. Our first finding is that the present program could achieve, in a well-functioning market, up to one million dollars in savings per year compared with CAC regulation. These savings free resources for alternative uses by government or the private sectors. Our model assumes cost-minimizing behavior on the part of emitters, flexibility of choice about control options, full information about control and trading opportunities, no uncertainty about trades and their public reception, and no transactions costs. The model results provide a benchmark for appraising actual market prices and transactions that may fall short of the potential if one or more of these assumptions fail to be appropriate. We then ask how changing the slopes of marginal cost control curves affect the results. Our motivation in this experiment is to explore how market incentives might stimulate innovations and reduce slopes, or how unforeseen events might hinder control measures and increase slopes. We find that changing all slopes by an equal percentage leads to 3 proportionate changes in the same direction of tradable credit prices and cost savings. This reduction in control cost slopes reduces tradable credit prices and reduces the variance among emitter costs compared with an increase in slopes that increases the prices and variance. In simple language, reducing costs of control and cost differences among emitters, advantageous as that is, reduces the gains from trade, whereas increasing costs and differences leads to greater savings. We introduce a simple form of transactions costs to estimate the impact on market variables. Higher transactions costs increase tradable credit prices, reduce trading, and reduce cost savings. Finally, to show the flexibility of the model, we reduce the policy cap on emissions, that is, reduce allowable emissions, and find that at the new equilibriums there is an increase in tradable credit prices, volumes traded, and cost savings. Environmental justice concerns have been raised about the spatial redistribution of emissions after trading. The issue is whether all neighborhoods have benefited by a market extending over the urban region. We have incorporated into the model sophisticated mapping software that can portray before and after spatial emission patterns. Differences in these spatial or neighborhood patterns could be an indicator or flag of possible spatial environmental equity concerns. The model can thus provide for a wide variety of mapping specifications as desired by the user including zip code, census tract, or neighborhood mappings of volatile organic compound or material (VOM) and HAP (hazardous air pollutants) emissions as affected by emissions trading. We shall report in later research on this complex matter after detailed reports by emitters on VOM and HAP emissions become available. It seems prudent in view of the general interest about neighborhood concerns to ask a question about the loss in cost savings if spatial market constraints are applied. We provide at this stage one kind of answer by arbitrarily limiting trading in certain areas and directions and assess the outcome in terms of the volume of trades, tradable credit prices, and control cost savings. 3. How the ERMS Cap-and-Trade Market Works Not only is emissions trading a new regulatory tool, but also the cap-and-trade variant was an untried approach to controlling urban ozone until the Illinois EPA (IEPA) launched the Emissions Market Reduction System, or ERMS, in 2000, for control of stationary source VOM emissions in the Chicago region. 3.1 How Government and Emitter Firms Share Key Decisions Under ERMS The target was set in the ERMS program for a further aggregate reduction of 12% of VOM emissions from stationary sources in the non-attainment area. It was estimated that this cap of 88% of historical emissions would contribute to the region’s attainment of national air quality standards that had not been reached by former reductions under CAC regulation. These stationary sources comprise about 20% of all seasonal VOM emissions in the region, transportation and smaller area sources under different regulatory control making up the rest. 4 The tradable credit was defined as a dated Allotment Trading Unit (ATU) good for 200 pounds of seasonal VOM emissions and transferable one-for-one anywhere in the region. The ATUs were not denominated in those HAPs that are a subset of VOMs nor identified or restricted by location. Thus, the decision was to have a unified regional or spatial market for VOM emissions. After devising a rule for allocation of ATUs to individual emitters, a rule requiring a properly dated ATU to be returned to the IEPA for every 200 pounds of emissions during the specific five month ozone season, and rules establishing record keeping, monitoring, and enforcement procedures, the IEPA turned over key implementation decisions to the regulated community. At the time of this study we had data on 179 major stationary sources that were each allocated free of charge 88% of their average 1994 to 1996 emissions (with some adjustments for unusual circumstances). These ATU allocations were made initially for the year 2000 ozone season. The allocations were to be renewed each year in the future generating an intertemporal stream of ATUs. Unlike traditional regulation that required specific control technologies or specified rates of emissions dependent upon technologies, the emitter firms were now free to compare reduction control options, and their costs, with trading in a market where ATU prices were revealed or negotiated. Emitters were expected to choose trading or control or a combination of the two in an effort to minimize control costs. Those emitters with the lowest control costs were expected to reduce more than 12% and sell ATUs to those emitters with higher costs until marginal control costs were equal to ATU prices across all emitters, thus achieving savings compared to traditional regulation. ATUs could be banked for one year only preventing a build-up of unused credits that could lead to seasonal spikes in emissions1. Stationary sources in this cap-and-trade market range over 23 SIC classifications including painting, plating, refining, manufacturing, publishing, and other industries. These industries vary by an order of magnitude in their seasonal emissions. They also vary widely in the control measures available to firms in different industries. Control measures could include changing the output level, the product, inputs into processes, or installing control equipment such as catalytic incinerators or other afterburners of various types (DePriest 2000). Such diversity in control options suggests a range of marginal control costs, which augurs well for cost savings from trading. However, such diversity of emitter industries scattered about the region also results in a multiplicity of different hydrocarbon and hazardous air pollutant emissions that constitute VOMs. 3.2 Addressing Non-uniform Mixing or Heterogeneity of VOM Pollutants in the Model Urban air is filled with an enormous variety of substances that move about and interact in ways not yet thoroughly understood. A few aspects bear on our study of spatial patterns. VOMs react with nitrogen oxides (NOx) and climate conditions to generate low-level ozone, which can impair lung function and contribute to other problems like the reduction in visibility. NOx moves about over larger areas than do most VOMs so that current 1 Additional details on the features of this cap-and-trade market with a comparison of the national sulfur dioxide version and the local Los Angeles cap-and-trade markets for sulfur dioxide and nitrogen oxides are available in Chapter 1 of Kosobud (2000). 5 policy efforts are directed toward larger regional control of NOx emissions while VOM controls are more directed toward local action like the cap-and-trade market subject of this study. Not only ozone but also aggregate and individual VOMs can have harmful impacts on human health and the environment. HAPs that are VOMs include benzene, toluene, the xylenes and other carcinogens. VOMs as they diffuse over space can also be transformed chemically into, generally, less harmful substances. Almost all of them tend to be fund rather than stock pollutants and dissipate over time so that control over the summer season seems appropriate. The regulatory agency understands this heterogeneity of pollutants by type and location, but made the implicit assumption that pollutants are sufficiently fixed in proportion from each emission source, and wafted approximately uniformly about the region so that the decision to create one market and one tradable credit, with attendant advantages, was defensible. The further implicit assumption was made that an aggregate emissions target or cap on stationary sources could represent their contribution toward meeting air quality standards. The objective was then to provide incentives for firms to minimize the costs while staying within the aggregate cap. The alternative was to define many spatially specific credits, and hence many markets, with possibly significant losses in market effectiveness. One aspect of our model was developed to help evaluate these assumptions by permitting a comparison of the performance of the unified market and a spatially subdivided market. It is important to note that existing traditional regulation of VOMs and HAPs remains in force underlying the emissions trading. That is, emitters cannot exceed existing traditional regulation levels; it is only the 12% reduction from those levels that is subject to trading opportunities. Therefore, it would appear that the worst that could happen is that neighborhoods would experience different percentage decreases in VOM and HAP emissions. The environmental equity issue would then be whether every neighborhood enjoys about the same percentage decrease. This conclusion must be modified for several contingencies. ATUs are allocated to the firm not the emission units or processes at the firm’s address. Those firms with more than one emission unit at one address may decrease one process and increase another with no change in VOMs, or required purchase of ATUs, but with a change in HAPs. Or a firm with a high proportion of HAPs per unit VOM emissions could buy ATUs from a firm with a low proportion. Therefore, HAP emissions could increase in a neighborhood. Similarly, new firms could enter the region or existing firms could decide on a major expansion. In each such case, the firm must acquire ATUs from the existing stockpile (no new ones are created for these firms), but neighborhoods in which they are located may experience a net increase in emissions over historical emissions while other neighborhoods enjoy a larger decrease. These cases and the general issues of environmental equity will require more data for their resolution, especially additional HAP emission reports from each participant emitter. The manner of collecting these data by individual ERMS participant remains to be worked out and may yet be several years away. The advantages of specifying and 6 testing the empirical base for such a model in preparation for this later study seem compelling to us. 7 4. The Theory of Cap-and-Trade Market Incentives 4.1 Overview of the Study’s Theoretical Framework We sketch just those theoretical aspects of cost minimizing behavior of emitter firms that guide our empirical work. Emitter firms with their allocated portfolio of dated ATUs are assumed to know their marginal control costs and those of others in the market. Knowing these costs, their endowments of ATUs, and the exogenous ATU price, the firm’s objective is to make joint cost-minimizing decisions about the degree of reduction of emissions by control measures and trading. The aggregate cap is a key decision of government policy. Our discussion in this section is based on the ERMS cap of 88%, but the theory holds for hypothetical alternate caps, say reducing the cap to lower levels like 76%. We illustrate the consequences of these changes in hypothetical scenarios in the results section. We shall assume in this first case, consistent with the ERMS program, that air pollutants are uniformly mixed over the region and ATUs trade one-for-one everywhere. We shall simplify this study by concentrating on the currently dated credits and leave for later work the issue of optimal intertemporal trading. 4.2 The Model Guiding Our Empirical Results Because of the fundamental rule that an ATU must be returned to the government for every 200 pounds of VOM emissions during the season by an emitter, the following identity holds: (1) hi qi ri ti i 1, ,179 emitters. h i refers to the historical or benchmark emissions of the ith firm, q i is the allocation of currently dated ATUs for the ith firm, ri is the reduction in emissions during the season for the ith firm, and t i is the number of ATUs bought (if negative) or sold (if positive) during the season for the ith firm. We shall consider ATUs that are banked for one year as a self-sale and include them in t i . ATUs may not be bought or borrowed from the future for current use. All variables are measured in 200-pound units of VOMs. Under traditional regulation, t i 0 and equation (1) reduces to ri hi qi where all values of the variables are determined by the government. Under emissions trading, equation (1) holds where ri and t i are now decision variables of the firm. We show later that the optimal value of one determines the optimal value of the other. 8 The emitter’s objective function under trading is to minimize reduction and trading costs knowing the control cost function, cr i (ri ) , which is increasing in r and differentiable, and the trading cost function, ct i (ti ) , or (2) Min cr i (ri ) ct i (ti ), (3) Subject to ri 0.0. Knowing that ct i (ti ) pti because p is the exogenous ATU price, and also knowing that ti / ri 1 because of (1), we can write the equilibrium conditions as (4) cr i (ri ) / ri p 0, (5) ri [cr i (ri ) / ri p] 0, (6) ri 0. The solution to (4), (5), and (6) yields the firm’s optimal reduction, ri* , and therefore the optimal trades, ti* . Note that ri* could be zero or equal to hi , and ti* could be positive or negative or zero. Marginal costs are equated to p for every firm deciding to reduce emissions, a requirement for minimum aggregate control costs. The optimal values for the firm’s reductions and trades may be used to obtain a measure, S, of the aggregate cost savings of trading compared with command-and-control (CAC). We may estimate S as the difference in aggregate control costs between regulatory regimes, or m m m i 1 i 1 i 1 (7) S ci (hi qi ) cr i (ri* ) ct i (ti* ) . The first term is aggregate control costs under CAC, the middle term is aggregate control costs under trading, and the last term is the sum of equilibrium purchases and sales of ATUs. Except in the unusual case of equal marginal control costs functions and equal historical emissions for all firms, S is expected to be positive; that is, emissions trading leads to cost savings. We also hypothesize that the greater the variance of control cost functions, the greater the aggregate cost savings. Demand and supply curves for ATUs may be derived from the marginal control cost schedules of firms. Since we know the marginal cost functions of the 179 emitter firms, we may simulate demand and supply trading in the market under the ERMS cap by trying out varying prices until sales equal purchases, or, equivalently, until the last term in (7) is zero. This approach may also be used to determine equilibrium ATU prices when model constraints, parameters, and emissions targets are changed. A geometric description of this procedure is provided in the next section. An implication of emissions trading theory in a competitive market is that any change in the allocation will not affect the ATU price and cost savings (Montgomery 1975). Under ERMS rules, the firm’s allocation, free of charge, is determined by the equation 9 qi (1 )hi where lambda is the fraction reduction (.12) of the firm’s historical emissions. One interesting alternative allocation could be determined by an auction of the same number of ATUs as were allocated free. We devise a Vickery- type auction as one way to test whether the price and aggregate savings are the same in the auction as they are in the free allocation. We find the ATU price, quantity of trades, and cost savings to be the same. The difference is that under the free allocation emitter firms receive a significant transfer of wealth whereas under the auction the government receives the wealth in the form of revenues. These results hold for the ERMS cap and also for hypothetically tightened caps. 4.3 The Geometry of Emissions Trading and CAC Regulation with a Homogeneous Air Pollutant In figure 1a we illustrate our method of estimating the equilibrium price of an ATU and calculating the cost savings from emissions trading in this case. The increasing and linear approximation to the marginal cost schedules of two emitter firms, i and j, are drawn under the assumption that 0 r, measured in 200 pound units, reflects the total possible reductions of both. For ease of visualization, we assume the government allocates r r0 ATUs to both for a 40% cap or an equivalent 60% emission reduction. Under CAC regulation each firm would reduce by 0 r0 with total control costs measured by the triangles 0 r0b 0r0 a . Allowing the firms to trade opens up new possibilities. Assume an independent auctioneer calling out trial prices and not allowing a transaction until the number desired to be bought equals the number desired to be sold. Assume initially only two firms. Given our schedules and cost minimizing behavior, a unique equilibrium price of 0 p1 exists. Emitter j sells r0 rj* ATUs and reduces by the amount 0 rj* . Emitter i buys an amount r0 ri* where r0ri* r0rj* , and reduces by 0ri* . Total control costs under trading are measured by the triangles 0ri*d 0rj*c and net savings compared with CAC regulation are ri* r0 b d r0 rj*c a , clearly a positive number measured by dfb fac . The argument generalizes to more than two firms and to integrals under nonlinear cost functions. A spatial inequity possibility emerges if emitter j is located in one neighborhood and emitter i in another. Both emitters have reduced emissions from the origin, but emitter j by more than i. To the extent that emissions have neighborhood rather than regional effects, they become spatially heterogeneous and a flag is raised concerning an environmental inequity. 10 p MCCi b d c MCCj f p1 a e ri* 0 r0 r rj* Figure 1a. Price determination and cost savings with a homogenous pollutant. p = $ per 200 pounds of VOM. r = reduction in 200 lb VOM units. In this figure the assumed firm cap is about 40% given by r0 r . p MSDi MCCi b d p1 c MCCj f a MSDj e rj 0 ri r0 rj ri r Figure 1b. Price determination and cost savings with heterogeneous pollutants. p = $ per 200 pounds of VOM. r = reduction in 200 lb VOM units. In this figure the assumed firm cap is about 40% given by r0 r . 5. Modeling Spatially Heterogeneous Pollutants: Issues and Choices 5.1 The Heterogeneity Issue Any attempt to track the contribution that one unit of emission from firm i at one location makes to pollutant concentrations at another location j, poses difficult problems for analysis (Tietenberg 1995). An estimate of the associated health impacts by location are even more difficult to make. Yet knowing that some VOMs are HAPs, and that speciated HAPs differ in toxicity, and that HAPs detoxify differently, motivates us to devise provisional yet tractable concepts of heterogeneity of pollutants. We have already indicated the simplification that the regulating community has made by treating pollutant emissions as homogeneous throughout the region when establishing a reduction target and defining ATUs as undifferentiated by location. 11 If the spatial distribution of all types of emissions changes little under trading and therefore all neighborhoods enjoy about the same emissions reduction, then the concern about environmental equity of trading may be eased. If, on the other hand, neighborhoods vary in the extent of particular reductions, this result raises a flag for further study of environmental inequity although no conclusive proof is obtained. We may look for these flags by tracking the local emissions, and changed emission spatial patterns after trading of aggregate VOMs and HAPs, and of speciated selected HAPs. A geometric description of some of the problems raised by heterogeneity of pollutants is provided in figure 1b, which may be usefully compared with figure 1a. 5.2 The Geometry of Emissions Trading Under Heterogeneous Pollutants In figure 1b we reproduce the schedules, price, and trading volume of figure 1a but we now assume that firm i emits hazardous VOMs that are HAPs and firm j emits nonhazardous VOMs. We illustrate that fact by assuming initially that we know the marginal social damage function for both types of emissions, and draw the function for firm i higher than for firm j. To maximize welfare we should require firm i to reduce by 0ri and firm j by 0ri thus equating benefits and costs rather than setting a common target level. Note that cost-minimizing behavior is assumed in this situation as in Figure 1a. If we incorrectly assume spatial homogeneity of pollutants, thinking that Figure 1a applies, we will reduce emissions from emitter i insufficiently, by ri ri , and emissions from firm j too much, by rj rj . If we knew the entire damage functions, the welfare loss could be calculated as the net areas under the damage curves. Even a glance indicates that these welfare losses could be important. Figure 1b highlights several problems. We do not have even a reasonable grasp of the spatial damage functions for HAPs, or for non-hazardous VOMs, singly or aggregated. In order to make progress in this area, it seems reasonable to both aggregate and distinguish speciated HAPs from other hydrocarbon VOMs because of their different capacities to harm. It also seems reasonable to test a hypothesis of a spatial emissions surrogate for the damage function; that is, changes in local or neighborhood emissions could have a bearing on the associated exposures and risks of the local or neighborhood population. This spatial dimension to heterogeneity could be changed by later research. We propose for later work a provisional definition of heterogeneous emissions that is relevant to the analysis of the ERMS program impacts on local areas. The first aspect of the definition treats aggregate and speciated HAP emissions differently from aggregate non-hazardous VOM emissions. The second aspect treats HAPs and non-HAP VOMs by location of emissions. A decline in aggregate or speciated HAPs observed in the region as a whole may occur at the same time that these pollutants increase in one or more neighborhoods. Hence, changes in emissions of varied types among neighborhoods after trading require separate analysis and a detailed database not yet available. With these distinctions in mind we could raise, or lower, flags of concern about environmental equity impacts of emissions trading. If all neighborhoods or zip codes enjoy the same reduction in VOM and HAP emissions because of trading, then no flags of concern appear to be flying. However, if one or more neighborhoods experience 12 different changes in aggregate VOM or HAP emissions, or a speciated HAP emission because of trading, then flags are set flying for a more detailed investigation. Figure 1b offers a way of illuminating this line of attack. Suppose firm i emits a greater proportion of HAPs per unit VOM than firm j. Suppose firm i is located in one neighborhood, firm j in another. Suppose that firm i, after trading (as in the figure), reduces emissions by less than firm j. We may conclude after this long list of suppositions that the flag of a possible environmental inequity in HAP reductions has been raised in firm i’s neighborhood. Whether these spatial patterns of HAP and other VOM emissions change after trading, raising or lowering possible flags of environmental equity in each case, are now empirical questions demanding data for empirical answers. We raise these environmental justice issues at this stage to indicate the kinds of data that will be needed to facilitate later research. 6. The Required Databases To measure the variables we have described requires detailed information on individual emitter locations, data on their marginal control costs, their ATU allocations and trades, and their VOM and HAP emissions before and after trading. Some of th4ese data are available for this study. We shall assume perfect and symmetric information in the regulated and regulating communities in order to focus on the issues of this study. Imperfect and asymmetric information are important topics for further research. 6.1 Location Street addresses of individual emitters are publicly available. If their emission or process units are at separate addresses, each address receives an allotment of ATUs. Zip codes offer an attractive local area designation because codes can be made more visible by different markings than the smaller census tract. Zip codes can be aggregated into larger neighborhoods, if desired. 6.2 Marginal Control Cost Schedules For this critical information we rely on a large study carried out by the IEPA that surveyed the numerous control measures for emission reduction available to participants in the market (IEPA, Technical Support Document, 1996). The survey estimated the costs at about the 12% emission reduction level for a number of emitters making use of engineering data and U.S. EPA estimates of the costs of Reasonably Available Control Technologies (RACT). These estimates were then extended to other emitters in the same SIC classification. Capital and operating costs were estimated in the study in present value terms. We are aware that questions of imperfect and asymmetric information may be most significant in this area. We temporarily set them aside for later work noting that a small survey of experts in this area does not reveal major problems in our cost estimates. 13 6.3 ATU Allocations and Trades Information on actual ATU allocations is available before the start of each season, but information on actual aggregate and individual trades and average ATU prices will become available only after the December 31 reconciliation periods when the IEPA will report on these variables. The model of this study makes use of actual ATU allocations but makes predictions before the end of the reconciliation date of the first year of trades and average ATU prices. The appropriate test of the model will be a comparison of the actual to the predicted trades and prices. However, several cautionary notes are in order. The model predicts the potential performance of the ERMS program to realize control cost savings. The predicted ATU trades and prices are for a fully functioning market. Because firms may exhibit learning behavior that restricts trades, or limit trading until they can gauge public acceptance of the program, the market may not be fully functioning in the first few years. Another feature of the market is the wide variation in size and industry of participants. It may take some time for all participants to learn about and take full advantage of the market’s opportunities. The sulfur dioxide program experienced such a lack of expected trading in its first few years. Therefore, the results of the model may be of value in providing a yardstick against which the actual performance of the market may be measured over time. And, of course, the model is used in this inquiry to simulate hypothetical scenarios including policy changes that cannot be tested by actual data from the current program, but do reveal properties of the cap-and-trade market. 6.4 VOM and HAP Emissions VOM emissions data available at the time of this study include the firm’s historical emissions and annual emissions since the 1994-1996 period. HAP emissions reported under Most Achievable Control Technology (MACT) and under Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) rules are accessible for prior years but these reports do not cover all HAPs, some of which are in the process of regulatory development. After the 2000 ozone season, participant firms will report their aggregate VOM emissions for the season and year, and the proposal is to participant firms report their aggregate and speciated HAP emissions after the year 2001 season. These reported emissions will take on more significance as the program evolves beyond the learning period. They will become essential information for later testing of the model’s predictions. 7. Empirical Implementation of the Model The underlying structural relationships of the model are the marginal control cost curves that were fitted for each firm by passing the curve through the origin and the 12% emission reduction cost value. These costs may be viewed as incremental to the control costs necessitated by prior traditional regulations that remain in effect. They are understood to be linear approximations to marginal costs over the relevant range. 14 Based on these structural relationships, the estimates of ATU equilibrium prices and of control costs under trading and under CAC regulation at equilibrium output levels were obtained by use of both a specially written optimization program that was built using the B34S® matrix programming language and an Excel® spread sheet program. Different approaches give us independent checks on the results. Basic to both approaches was the specification of the excess demand functions. These depend upon the desired targeted level of reduction, which was 12% in the case of ERMS. Summing the excess demand functions for all the firms and selecting the price that made this sum equal to zero determined the equilibrium price. In other words, at equilibrium the number of ATUs sold must equal the number of ATUs bought as demonstrated in figure 1a. Using Excel®, the price was manually moved until this sum was as close to zero as possible. Using the B34S® matrix command, the price was restricted to be greater than or equal to zero in the model specification and the optimization routine determined the solution of equilibrium price where the sum of excess demands were zero. An advantage of the optimization approach is that it allows the user to easily change constraints, parameters, and emissions targets or caps in the model and observe the results. Most important for our purposes is the inclusion of spatial constraints in the optimization model. For example, it is possible to restrict purchases of ATUs within a certain zip code, or group of them. The model enables us to gauge the effects of such proposed changes on both prices and the distribution of pollution. Mapping of these emission patterns provides a means of evaluating these changes in distribution and can be implemented by use of an advanced software routine. The optimization approach also enables us to highlight the flexibility of the model by changing the emissions reduction targets and reporting the consequences. A more explicit account of these implementation methodologies is given in Appendix A. 8 The Performance of the Cap-and-Trade Market With and Without Equity Constraints To recapitulate, the cap-and trade variant of emissions trading is often said to be costeffective, flexible, and non-confrontational. We are able to report detailed results on the first and second mentioned performance features. We consider first the situation where pollutants diffuse uniformly over the region independent of the location of emissions, the homogeneous case, and then we consider the situation where spatial constraints are placed on trading. 8.1 Emission Trading Results when Pollutants are Uniformly Mixed Over Space Establishing the cap or emissions reduction target may be viewed as the government acting as the citizen’s purchasing agent for air quality. The cap or target may change from time to time as new information comes to light or new citizen pressure comes to bear on air quality. Similarly the choice of a regulatory instrument may be viewed as the purchasing agent’s efforts to obtain the desired air quality in the most cost-effective way. Our model presents a methodology to evaluate the agent’s policy options and their consequences. 15 In table 1 we present the equilibrium ATU price, volume of ATU trades, the control costs under emissions trading compared with CAC regulation, and the cost savings to be realized by using market incentives for the present ERMS program reduction rate of 12% from the historical benchmark. We present additional results for hypothetically increased reduction rates on up to 36%, both as a test of the model and as a relevant exercise in view of the current policy debate on reducing acceptable urban ozone levels. The results are as expected from emissions trading theory. ATU prices increase as the cap tightens. Decentralizing control decisions in the cap-and trade market at the 12% ERMS reduction rate can bring about a million dollars in saving per year compared with CAC regulation. These savings increase to 9 million dollars as the emissions target rate of reduction increases to 36% implying that, as the number of ATUs allocated decrease and prices increase, the incentives to trade strengthen with the consequence of a more than proportionate increase in savings. Our approach enables us to report the number of ATUs traded at each reduction rate, as in the last column of Table 1. Recall that the reductions in emissions are obtained by issuing tradable credits to pollute in amounts below the benchmark or historical emission level. The benchmark emissions utilized in the ERMS program were equivalent to 109,211 ATUs; thus, to achieve the 12% reduction required that 96,106 ATUs be allocated for the year 2000 season.2 The amounts allocated decrease as the desired reduction rate increases so that 69,895 ATUs would have to be allocated to achieve a 36% decrease in emissions. The number of ATUs traded in the 12% scenario is 3,743, about 4% of those allocated in that case. The number of ATUs to be traded if the reduction rate were set to 36% increases to 11,229, a little over 16% of the total allocated in that scenario. These results confirm our expectations, based on rising marginal control cost schedules, that as reduction rates increase and ATUs allocations decrease, cost-saving trading opportunities increase even more rapidly. Figure 2a depicts the relationships between reduction rates and cost savings and ATUs traded. 2 In order to create a backstop to the market, the IEPA set aside 1% of these ATUs in an Alternative Compliance Market Account. As these credits are available at a price in the market, we believe that ignoring this set-aside will have negligible effects on our results. 16 Table 1 Estimates of ATU Equilibrium Price, Number of ATUs Traded, and Emissions Trading Cost Savings under ERMS for different VOM Emission Reduction Rates (year 2000 trading season) [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] VOM Reduction ATU Equilibrium Control Cost Control Cost Control Cost Number of Rate Price Under CAC Under ERMS Savings (3-4) ATUs Traded ($) (x $1000) (x $1000) (x $1000) 0.12 258 2,749 1,687 1,061 3,743 0.14 300 3,741 2,297 1,444 4,367 0.16 343 4,886 3,000 1,887 4,991 0.18 386 6,184 3,797 2,388 5,615 0.20 429 7,635 4,687 2,948 6,238 0.22 472 9,238 5,671 3,567 6,862 0.24 515 10,994 6,749 4,245 7,486 0.26 558 12,903 7,921 4,982 8,110 0.28 601 14,964 9,187 5,778 8,734 0.30 644 17,179 10,546 6,633 9,358 0.32 687 19,545 11,999 7,546 9,981 0.34 730 22,065 13,546 8,519 10,605 0.36 773 24,737 15,186 9,551 11,229 Note: There are 179 emitters included in the ERMS – UIC model. The number of ATUs allocated depends upon the VOM reduction policy goals. For the current 12% reduction, 96,106 ATUs were issued to these emitters for the ozone-trading season May through September 2000. Prices and cost estimates are in current (2000) dollars. Source of estimates: Simulations with the ERMS – UIC model. 17 Guided by another implication of emissions trading theory, we expect that the greater the spread in marginal control cost slopes among emitters, the greater the opportunities for savings and the higher the ATU price. To check these beliefs, we have changed the absolute spread among emitter slopes by varying percentages up and down with a consequent change in the variance among these slope coefficients. The confirming results are presented in Table 2 for the ERMS reduction rate of 12%. The equilibrium price increases as the absolute spread increases as do cost savings indicative of the increase in savings opportunities from trading. Figure 2b depicts the relationships between the variance and cost savings and ATU prices. Note as we increase or narrow the spread of all slopes by the same percentage, while holding the reduction rate constant, the number of ATUs that emitters find it advantageous to trade does not change even though the gains from each trade increase as the variance increases. Introducing transactions costs into the emissions trading section of the model is expected to decrease cost savings, increase ATU prices, and decrease the number of trades. In essence, they drive a wedge between sale and purchase price compared with the price in a frictionless or transaction cost-free market. These costs were introduced into the model in the case of the ERMS cap with both seller and buyer paying the same amount indicated in table 3. The results are as expected. Savings from trading and the number of trades decline appreciably in these extreme cases. The IEPA has attempted to reduce transactions costs by maintaining a free electronic bulletin board of offers and bids. These transactions costs to the emitter typically include search and negotiation expenditures, but they may also include anticipated emitter expenditures for legal and public relations assistance in the case of regulator challenges to trades, or public disapproval of trades. 18 N T RA D ED 11000 Cost savings (x $1000) and num ber of A T Us traded 10000 COST SA VE 9000 8000 7000 6000 5000 4000 3000 2000 .12 .14 .16 .18 .20 .22 .24 .26 .28 Rate of reduction of VOM em issions .30 .32 .34 .36 Figure 2a. The relationships between the rate of reduction of emissions and cost savings and number of ATUs traded. Note that the ERMS reduction rate of 12% results in cost savings of about $1,000,000. COST SA VE A T U Price and Cost Savings (x $1000) 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 A T UPRI CE 200 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 Variance of m arginal cost curv e slopes (000) 180 200 Figure 2b. The relationships between the variance of emitter marginal cost slopes and cost savings and ATU prices when the aggregate target rate of reduction is 12%. 19 Table 2 Effects of Changes in Control Costs on ATU Prices, Number of ATUs Traded, and Emission Trading Cost Savings (12% Reduction: Year 2000 trading season) [1] [2] Percent of Original ATU Equilibrium Slopes of Marginal Price in $ Control Cost Curves Variance ( ) (x $1000) 50 (23) 55 (28) 60 (34) 65 (39) 70 (46) 75 (52) 80 (60) 85 (67) 90 (76) 95 (84) 100 (93) 105 (103) 110 (113) 115 (123) 120 (134) 125 (146) 130 (158) 135 (170) 140 (183) 145 (196) 150 (210) 129 142 155 167 180 193 206 219 232 245 258 270 283 296 309 322 335 348 361 373 386 [3] Control Costs Under CAC [4] Control Costs Under ERMS [6] Number of ATUs Traded (x $1000) [5] Control Costs Savings (3-4) (x $1000) (x $1000) 1,374 1,512 1,649 1,787 1,924 2,061 2,199 2,336 2,474 2,611 2,749 2,886 3,023 3,161 3,298 3,436 3,573 3,711 3,848 3,985 4,123 844 928 1,012 1,097 1,181 1,266 1,350 1,434 1,519 1,603 1,687 1,772 1,856 1,940 2,025 2,109 2,194 2,278 2,362 2,447 2,531 531 584 637 690 743 796 849 902 955 1,008 1,061 1,114 1,167 1,220 1,273 1,327 1,380 1,433 1,486 1,539 1,592 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 3,743 Notes: The downward and upward shifts in the marginal control cost slopes maintain relative differences across emitters but do not change the advantages of trading, which is why the numbers of ATUs remains constant. Column 1 contains the percent by which original marginal cost curve slopes were shifted with the variance of all slopes in parentheses times $1,000. Note a 50% change means a decrease of 50% for each slope. The shifts change the gains from trading which is why the ATU price and control cost columns change. Source of Estimates: Simulations with the ERMS – UIC model. 20 Table 3 Effects of Transactions Cost Changes on ATU Equilibrium Price, Number of ATUs Traded, and Emissions Trading Cost Savings (12% Reduction: Year 2000 Trading Season) [1] Transaction Costs [2] Equilibrium Price [3] Control Costs Under CAC [4] Control Costs Under ERMS [6] Number of ATUs Traded (x $1000) [5] Control Cost Savings (3-4) (x $1000) ($) ($) (x $1000) No transaction costs 258 2,749 1,687 1,061 3,743 10 264 2,749 1,728 1,020 2,588 20 270 2,749 1,769 979 2,422 30 276 2,749 1,810 938 3,278 40 283 2,749 1,851 897 3,123 50 289 2,749 1,892 856 2,968 60 295 2,749 1,933 815 2,813 70 301 2,749 1,974 774 2,658 100 320 2,749 2,097 651 2,194 200 375 2,749 2,627 126 765 250 419 2,749 2,747 2 594 Notes: Transaction costs are considered to include a component for search, negotiation and bargaining expenditures required for trades. Broker fees may approximate part of these expenditures. Any extra expenditures by emitters for special reporting and management required by the ERMS program could also be included as well as anticipated expenditures for public relations or legal services. Source of Estimates: Simulations with the ERMS – UIC model. 21 A powerful implication of emissions trading theory is that changes in the allocation of ATUs among emitters ought not to affect prices or quantities, and hence savings, presuming that the market remains competitive and free of uncertainties and transactions costs. As discussed in the theory section, we simulate a Vickery-type auction in which the final equilibrium price balances the given supply with the demand schedules derivable from the marginal cost schedules. To dramatize this result, we show the auction results should the cap or reduction rate be changed. The results in Table 4 confirm the implications: the equilibrium ATU prices and cost savings are the same under both a government auction and a free allocation as a comparison of tables 1 and 4 discloses. What is different in these two markets is the transfer of wealth. Under the free allocation, the value of the ATU is transferred to the emitter; under the auction the revenues go to the government. We may estimate these transfers by multiplying the number of ATUs auctioned by the price. The wealth transfers amount to about 25 million dollars per year in the 12% scenario increasing to 54 million dollars in the 36% case. What also is different in these two markets is the individual firm purchases and sales of ATUs. We have arrayed emitter firms from low to high marginal costs in figure 3a and plotted their purchases and sales in the free-allocation and 12% reduction scenario. In figure 3b we array emitter firms in the same way but plot their purchases in the auction market again in the 12% scenario. In both markets, it will be recalled, emitters are equating their marginal costs to the ATU price. Total purchases for each emitter in the auction market are the algebraic sum of what they would have gotten under free allocations plus their purchases or minus their sales. Emitter control costs are the same in both markets but not their balance sheets. 22 Table 4 Estimates of ATU Equilibrium Price, Number of ATUs Traded, and Emissions Trading Cost Savings Under ERMS as an Auction Market. [1] VOM Reduction Rates [2] ATU Cap: Number of ATUs Auctioned [3] [4] [5] ATU Equilibrium Control Cost Under Control Cost for Price CAC VOM Reductions Under ERMS $ (x $1000) (x $1000) [6] Control Cost Savings (4-5) (x $1000) .12 .14 96,106 93,922 258 300 2,749 3,741 1,687 2,297 1,061 1,444 .16 .18 91,738 89,553 343 386 4,886 6,184 3,000 3,797 1,887 2,388 .20 .22 87,369 85,185 429 472 7,635 9,238 4,687 5,671 2,948 3,567 .24 .26 83,001 80,816 515 558 10,994 12,903 6,749 7,921 4,245 4,982 .28 .30 .32 .34 .36 78,632 76,448 74,264 72,080 69,895 601 644 687 730 773 14,964 17,179 19,545 22,065 24,737 9,187 10,546 11,999 13,546 15,186 5,778 6,633 7,546 8,519 9,551 Notes: The ATU cap for the auction is determined by multiplying the historical emissions of all emitters by 1 minus the desired rate of reduction of VOM emissions (or .88 in the case of the first row). Source of Estimates: Simulation with the ERMS-UIC model. 23 1000 Purchases (-) and sales (+) of A T U contracts 800 600 400 200 0 -200 -400 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 I ndi vidual em itter f irm s array ed f rom low to high M C curv e slopes 160 Figure 3a. Individual emitter purchases and sales of ATUs at a VOM reduction rate of .12, an ATU equilibrium price of $258, and a free allocation of ATUs. The ordinate values are ATU sales if positive and purchases if negative. The abscissa values are 179 individual emitters arrayed from lowest marginal control cost slope value on the left to the highest on the right. Purchases (-) and sales (+) of A T U contracts -1000 -2000 -3000 -4000 -5000 -6000 -7000 -8000 -9000 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 I ndi vidual em itter f irm s array ed f rom low to high M C curv e slopes 160 Figure 3b. Individual emitter purchases of ATUs at a reduction rate of .12 and ATU equilibrium price of $258 assuming the government auctions the ATUs. 24 8.2 Emission Trading Results When Pollutants are Not Uniformly Mixed Over Space Changes in VOM emissions in particular zip codes, and clusters of them due to trading, can be among our indicators of spatial equity concerns, as we have mentioned3. We launch our investigation into environmental equity concerns by first experimenting with constraints on trading in certain zip codes that are selected at random and not for their welfare significance. We begin in this way to bring out two important consequences of spatial restrictions. First, restricting the emitters from buying ATUs in certain neighborhoods, frequently mentioned as the way to reduce importing emissions into these areas, has the immediate effect of reducing the demand for ATUs. This translates into lower equilibrium prices, fewer trades, and decreased cost savings. These effects must be balanced against the welfare gains of these spatial restrictions. There is a second, more subtle, consequence of spatial constraints. Restrictions in one neighborhood mean increased emissions in others. Total emissions remain capped, of course, but the decline in ATU price caused by spatial constraints leads other emitters to reduce emissions less by control measures and buy more ATUs, hence emit more. Only a careful spatial analysis can reveal the changing emission patterns that result. The first consequence can be explored in the abstract by starting with the 98 zip codes in which emitters are located and randomly eliminating first about 10% of the codes, then 20% on up to 40%. The results in table 5 reveal that ATU prices, trades, and cost savings decrease as expected. Spatial restrictions on the market’s workings can have significant effects that must be kept in mind when evaluating the environmental equity benefits of such restrictions. The results of Table 5 are based on one random pattern of zip code elimination. 3 Several simple spatial restrictions have characterized existing trading programs to date in an effort to allay equity concerns. The Los Angeles Regional Clean Air Incentive Market (RECLAIM) program prohibits sales of SOx and NOx credits from the inland area to the coastal area because of the prevailing winds (Lents 2000). In the national SO2 control program, the state of New York has recently prohibited electric utilities from selling credits to the west of the state due to concern about prevailing winds and acid rain deposition (Ellerman et al. 2000). 25 Table 5 Effects of ERMS Sub-area Restrictions on ATU Equilibrium Prices, Number of ATUs Traded, and Emission Trading Cost Savings (12% Reduction: Year 2000 trading season) [1] [2] Restrictions on ATU ATU Equilibrium Purchases in Selected Price ZIP Codes [3] Control Costs Under CAC [4] Control Costs Under ERMS [6] Number of ATUs Traded (x $1000) [5] Control Cost Savings (3-4) (x $1000) (x $1000) No special restrictions (12 % reduction) 258 2,749 1,687 1,061 3,743 Restrictions on purchases in 10 zip Codes 238 2,749 1,964 784 2,942 Restrictions on Purchases in 20 zip Codes (including first 10) 230 2,749 2,047 702 2,597 Restrictions on Purchases in 30 zip Codes (including above 20) 213 2,749 2,242 507 1,917 Restrictions on Purchases in 40 zip codes (including above 30) 208 2,749 2,289 460 1,709 Notes: There are 98 zip codes in the non-attainment area in which emitters are located. Codes were chosen for restrictions on buying ATUs in a random manner. Emitters not allowed to buy ATUs must meet the requirement of covering their seasonal emissions with ATUs allocated but not sold. All dollar values are in current (2000) prices. Sources of Estimates: Simulations with the ERMS – UIC model. 26 9 Conclusions and Research Directions Emissions trading compared with traditional control compels us to take a fresh look at and ask different questions about the workings and impacts of environmental regulation. The government makes new key policy decisions about the cap and devises general market rules and appraisal procedures subject to the scrutiny and comment of the regulated community and public interest groups. The regulated community in turn makes new decisions about the choice of control options, the search for new options, and the management of the ATU portfolio. Our model provides one means for taking this fresh look. It can help reveal the potential of emissions trading under a variety of assumptions about the parameters of relationships and changes in emission targets or goals. The model can become a guide to the workings of the ERMS program before the learning and break-in period is complete. As recorded data become available, the model can be tested and adjusted for future research. Our first results indicate that the present ERMS program can bring about significant cost savings, up to one million dollars per period, compared with CAC regulation. This result can be achieved with trading of about 4% of all ATUs allocated. An equilibrium price of $258 is generated by the model’s trading simulation. The actual observed price may be lower due to the fact that marginal cost functions were estimated on the basis of a 1996 study and participants may have introduced new cheaper control actions since then—just what market incentives are suppose to encourage them to do. Actual observed prices and trades also may be lower than the model predictions due to learning behavior or concern about public acceptance of emissions trading. Careful further research is required here. The model enables us to simulate emitter decisions when changes in marginal control cost (slopes) are introduced. Decreasing the spread of these slopes decreases ATU prices, trades, and savings, as trades become financially less attractive. Increasing them does the opposite. If emitters confront transactions costs in the market, the model enables us to demonstrate that the higher these costs the lower the ATU price, the fewer the trades, and the lower the cost savings. Study of participant perceived transactions costs is also a serious research priority. The model enables us to simulate government changes in policy objectives such as tightening the cap. Allocating fewer aggregate ATUs in this case causes higher prices, more trades, and greater cost savings compared with traditional regulation. If the government chose to change the free allocation of ATUs, the model enables us to show that, in a competitive market, there would be no change in ATU equilibrium price or cost savings, but there would be a change in the transfer of wealth. We prove this by having the government auction ATUs and solving for ATU price and quantity traded. The model can show its versatility by providing the input data for software mapping of emissions patterns that can help evaluate issues of environmental equity. In anticipation of future research based on detailed emitter data, we illustrate the reduction of market performance when arbitrary spatial restrictions are implemented. 27 Appendix A: Implementation Methodology Specification of the Excess Demand Function in the Case of an ERMS 12% Emission Reduction Goal. The key variables in our dataset of 179 firms are: cri (ri ) = the marginal cost of reduction of emission reduction for firm i. 0 = the reduction goal of 12%. The cap then becomes 88% of historic emissions. hi and qi as given by prior recorded emissions and government policy where qi (1 0 )hi . In words, if the firm reported historic emissions of 100 units of VOM emissions as an average during 1994-1996, the firm was then allocated 88 ATUs for the ozone season. The next task is to estimate the marginal control cost based upon reported values (IEPA Technical Support Document 1996) at a 12% reduction. One assumption would have been to assume constant marginal costs. We rejected this approach as not realistic in favor of the increasing marginal cost case. The question then becomes, are the costs increasing at an increasing rate, at a constant rate or a decreasing rate? In our preliminary model we assumed the constant increase rate case where the cost curve was fitted to the 12% reduction value and the origin. As more detailed data on costs becomes available, other cost functions can be employed in the model. These estimated marginal cost curves underlie our excess demand and enable us to generate equilibrium prices, quantities of ATUs traded, and control costs under both CAC and ERMS regulation. We show how we derive these values in the next section where we illustrate the flexibility of the model by explaining the implications of varying emission caps or emission reductions. Specification of the Excess Demand Functions in the Case of Varying Reduction Goals. Assume 0 base reduction rate (.12 ) and j the reduction rate mandated in period j then (A1) cr i (ri , j ) cr i (ri , 0 )[ j / 0]. where we introduce j to indicate that we are comparing the cost value of a different cap point along the curve, although the slope remains the same. In words, if the marginal costs of reducing emissions was $200 assuming the base reduction was 12% ( cr i (ri ,.12) $200 ) and the reduction rate was mandated to increase to 16%, then marginal costs will rise to $266.67 [cr i (ri ,.16) $200*(.16 / .12) $266.67] . The decision for a firm to sell or buy is limited by various constraints. Clearly the firm cannot sell more than it has been allocated. Nor will it buy more than it needs to reduce. Define ri ( ) as the amount of emissions that firm i needs to reduce given any . As 28 explained in section 5, the relation ri hi qi holds if there is no trading under traditional regulation. When trading is permitted ri hi qi ti . Define ti ( , p) the amount firm i sells (if positive) or buys (if negative) given the required reduction and the market price of an ATU p . We will show later that the price of an ATU, p , is an increasing function of , or the required reduction percentage. Equations (A2) and (A3) explain how we calculated the optimal trading for the firm; that is, how we determined ti ( , P) given the allocation of ATUs and the marginal control cost. (A2) For p cr i (ri , ) ti ( , p) min(( p cr i (ri , )(ri ( ) / cri (ri , )), qi ( )). (A3) For p cr i (ri , ) ti ( , p) max(( p cr i (ri , )(ri ( ) / cri (ri , )), hi qi ( )). Note that (A2) limits the maximum sales to the amount the firm has been allocated qi ( ) while (A3) limits the amount bought to what they need or their historic emissions minus the ATUs they have been given. The optimization problem is to find p such that 179 t ( , p) 0 for a i 1 i j j value. Given p1 is the equilibrium price, our empirical work shows that, everything else equal, p1 / 0 or the greater the required rate of reduction, the higher the price of the ATU. The higher price results in more ATUs traded due to the increased incentive to acquire ATUs as marginal control costs mount. It also revealed that cost savings of trading increase compared to CAC regulation. More specialized cases can easily be solved if for an individual firm i we place a cap on the amount it can buy (ti ( , p) ) or in fact restrict the firm to only selling ATUs (ti ( , p) 0.0 .4 In summary, our model allows much more specialized excess demand functions whose implications are a task for future research. Solving for a Government Auction of ATUs The above analysis assumes that each firm was given an allocation of ATUs, qi ( ) and that some firms would buy ATUs and some firms would sell ATUs depending on their individual cost functions. In the assumed auction case, we do not allocate any ATUs to firms. Instead each firm must either reduce all emissions or buy ATUs from the government to cover emissions at a Vickery-type auction where the single price clears the market. As in the free allocation case, the market clears when all ATUs offered by the government are sold and excess demands equal zero. Our approach to estimating prices, quantities traded and costs are the same in both auction and free allocation scenarios. It will be noted that both scenarios yield the same prices, same number of ATUs traded, and same cost savings, although the transfer of wealth is different. This turns out to be an application of the Coase theorem (Coase 1960). 4 Note that the cap is inserted as a negative number. 29 In all cases command and control costs have been calculated as ri ( ) cr i (ri , ) / 2 and trading costs as (ri* ( ) ti ( , p)) 2 (cr i (ri , ) / 2ri* ( )) in keeping with figure 1a and 1b in section 5. The gain from trading for firm i becomes (A4) (cr i (ri , )ri ( )) / 2 (( ri* ( ) ti ( , p)) 2 (cr i ( ri , ) / 2 ri* ( ))). The percent reduction of the firm becomes (ri* ( ) ti (, p)) / hi which suggests that the more a firm sells (buys) ATUs the more (less) it reduces its emissions. Concluding Comments on the Model Because we have been using a general nonlinear optimizer to solve our model, it is possible to add other parameters to the model and place complex nonlinear constraints on the solution.5 What would be the nature of these constraints is left to further research. Our model has been designed to highlight both the price and spatial effects of such changes. 5 The B34S (Stokes 1997) contains a nonlinear programming with nonlinear constraints function. This was not needed in this preliminary analysis since the only constrained placed on the solution that p must be greater than or equal to zero. 30 References Coase, R. H. 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3, 1-44. DePriest, William. 2000. “Development and maturing of environmental control technologies in the power industry”. In Kosobud, editor, op cit. 168-185. Ellerman, A. Denny et al. 2000. Markets for clean air: the U. S. Acid Rain Program. Cambridge, U. K. Cambridge University Press. Illinois Environmental Protection Agency. 1996. Technical Support Document for VOM Emissions Reduction Market System. Springfield, IL. Bureau of Air, IEPA. (October). Kosobud, Richard F. editor. 2000. Emissions trading: environmental policies new approach. New York. John Wiley & Sons. Lents, James M. 2000. The RECLAIM Program after three years. In Kosobud, editor, op cit. 219-240. Mendelsohn, R. 1986. Regulating heterogeneous emissions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 13, 301-312. Montero, J-P. 1997. Marketable pollution permits with uncertainty and transactions costs. Resource and Energy Economics 20, 27-50. Montgomery, W. D. 1975. Markets for licenses and efficient pollution control programs. Journal of Economic Theory 5, 395-418. Stavins, R. N. 1995. Transactions costs and tradeable permits. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 29, 137-148. Stokes, H. H. Specifying and Diagnostically Testing Econometric Models. Westport CT: Quorum Books 1997 Tietenberg, T. H. 1995. Emissions trading: an exercise in reforming pollution policy. Washington, DC. Resources for the Future. Tolley, George, Jeffrey Wentz, Steven Hilton, and Brian Edwards. 1993. “The Urban Ozone Abatement Problem.” In Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Cost-Effective Control of Urban Smog. Chicago, Illinois. 31