Momentum and Market States: A Regime Switching Approach Thesis Proposal By Jia Xu Department of Finance and Accounting Business School National University of Singapore This version: Feb 2004 1 Abstract By using an alternative measure of market state, I will re-examine the relationship between market state and momentum as well as long-run reversal profits. The measure classifies excess market returns into two regimes using a Markov-switching model. There are at least two advantages to this approach. First, this measure of market states is more natural as we let the data to classify market states. Second, in this study we can account for the possibility of regime switches, the market state prior to as well as during the holding period. I will investigate the effects of both the prior and the contemporaneous market state on the momentum and long-run reversal profits. I. Introduction 1.1 Objectives and Potential Contribution of the Study Since DeBondt and Thaler (1985) and Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), extensive research has been done on the short-run momentum and long-run reversal. The anomalies have been found in both US and non-US markets. Attempts using risk-based models to account for these anomalies have largely been unsuccessful. Several behavioral theories were developed to jointly explain both the momentum and contrarian phenomena. Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (DHS, 1998) and Hong and Stein (HS, 1999) each constructed a behavioral model to explain these anomalies. Particularly, they link the investor overreaction to new information with momentum profits. Moreover, the degree 2 of overreaction is believed to be higher following market gains as well as the decreasing investor risk aversion. Following these models, Cooper et al (2003) has tested the overreaction theories of shortrun momentum and long-run reversal in the cross section of stock returns. They find that the momentum and long-run reversal profits depend on the state of the market prior to the beginning of the momentum holding periods. They call attention for later research to take regime switches into account. Given the critical effects of market states, it is natural to pay attention to the criterion for identifying them. In Cooper et al (2003), they define the two market states based on whether the lagged market returns are positive (UP market) or negative (DOWN market). The lags they used are one-year, two-year and three-year. However, in this study, I propose an alternative measure of market states, which classifies excess market returns into two regimes using a Markov-switching model. There are at least two advantages to my approach. First, this measure of market states is more natural as we let the data to classify market states. Second, in this study we can account for the possibility of regime switches, the market state prior to as well as during the holding period. Some empirical exploration can be conducted. This study may have two potential contributions: Firstly, based on the two market states I identify, I will re-examine the relationship between market states and the momentum and long-run reversal profits. Besides, in Cooper et al (2003), there is an open question that 3 there seems no initial momentum before the long-run reversal following the DOWN states. In my paper, it would be interesting to see if the phenomenon persists. Secondly, since momentum profits can also be influenced by the market state during the holding periods, the study will investigate the effects of both the prior and the contemporaneous market state on the momentum and long-run reversal profits. I would test which effect is more important to momentum and long-run reversal profits. The results may lead to some interesting discussions about behavioral models. 1.2 Organization of the thesis The thesis proposal is organized as the following: Section II reviews the literature on momentum and contrarian studies, behavioral models and market states, and regime switching models and its application. Section III details the research design, methodology and data. Section IV discusses further study beyond this thesis. II. Literature Review 2.1.1 Momentum Studies The momentum effect, first elaborated by Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), is still a major puzzle in finance literature up to today. They show that a simple strategy, buy high sell low, based on previous 3 to 12 months stock returns will generate about 12% return for the following year. It has drawn great attention thereafter. Among a lot other research, 4 Jegadeesh and Titman (2001) give further evidence on the momentum effect, which cannot be explained by data mining. Forner and Marhuenda (2003) confirmed that momentum is significant. Rouwenhost (1998) and Chan, Hameed and Tong (2000) tested and confirmed the momentum anomaly in the international equity market. Current asset pricing models have difficulty in explaining momentum. Some studies find that it is not primarily driven by market risk. In Fama and French (1996), they show that their unconditional three-factor model cannot explain the momentum. And Grundy and Martin (2001) confirmed the result later on. Chordia and Shivakumar (2002) try to use a conditional asset pricing model with lagged macroeconomic risk factors to forecast momentum profits. But Griffin et al (2003) show that Chordia-Shivakumar model cannot be applied internationally. Moreover, Cooper et al (2003) also find that macroeconomic factors cannot explain momentum profits after simple methodological adjustments to take account of microstructure concerns. 2.1.2 Contrarian Studies DeBondt and Thaler (1985) suggest that over long period of time there are reverse changes in stock returns: specifically, the stocks that have lowest returns (the losers) during the previous three to five years (the formation period) will do better during the following three to five years (the test period) than those that previously had the highest returns (the winners). Based on the findings of Kahnem and Tversky (1982) in the field of cognitive psychology, DeBondt and Thaler (1985) interpret their results as irrational behavior on the part of investors. This will lead to excessive optimism toward good news 5 and excessive pessimism over bad news. Such a situation can cause the stock price temporarily stray from its fundamental value. This potential violation of the Efficient Market Hypothesis is called as the overreaction effect. It remains one of the most controversial topics in finance field. Forner and Marhuenda (2003) showed contrarian is significant and not from data mining. Supporting evidence has also come from MacDonald and Power (1991) and Campbell and Limmack (1997) in the UK, Mai (1995) from the French Market, Da Costa (1994) in Brazil and Alonso and Rubio (1990) in Spain. Besides, a lot research has also found similar phenomena in financial markets that are not based on stocks. Not surprisingly, existing asset pricing models cannot fully explain the contrarian profits, neither. 2.2 Behavioral Models and Market States Facing the challenges the above study has raised against rational asset pricing models, quite a few behavioral models have been developed to explain the anomalies. De Long et al. (1991) develops a model to examine the profits of traders who underestimate risk. Hirshleifer, Subrahmanyam, Titman (1994) tries to see how traders who overestimate the probability that they get information before others will increase stock selection herding. But the above models are not unified. The following are some of the integrated models. Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (DHS, 1998) develop a theory of security market under- and overreaction on the bases of two psychological biases: investor overconfidence about the precision of private information and variation in confidence arising from biased self-attribution. A typical investor in the context is who overestimate 6 the precision of his private information rather than the public information and whose confidence will change asymmetrically to confirming versus disconfirming pieces of news. Thus, the arrival of confirming news tends to raise the overconfidence of the investor, which may trigger further overreaction. Such continuing overreaction will cause momentum in security prices. But, in the long run, with further public information arriving, the momentum is eventually reversed towards fundamental values. Thus, the model may account for both short-run momentum and long-run reversal. Hong and Stein (1999) provide another unified account for under- and overreaction. In their models, under the assumption of the gradual diffusing news about fundamentals, there are two different groups of investors: “newswatchers” and “momentum traders”. The authors emphasize on the interaction of heterogeneous investors. The newswatchers base their decisions only on their private information. While the momentum traders, on the contrary, only condition on the past price changes. They show that the newswatchers tend to underreact to the private information at the beginning. And the momentum traders try to exploit the underreaction and, thus, create an excessive momentum profit which inevitably leads to overreaction. Good theories must be potentially rejectable by empirical tests. By extending the above theories (mainly DHS (1998) and HS (1999)) to the relationship between market states and momentum, Cooper et al (2003) tests the short-run momentum and long-run reversal in the cross section of stock returns conditioned on UP and DOWN markets. They find the results are, in general, consistent with the overreaction theories: the monthly 7 momentum profit does depend on the market state, and that the up-market momentum will reverse in the long run. But Cooper et al (2003) leaves an open question: they find significant long-run reversal in the DOWN states without any initial momentum. They note that, “[t]his finding indicates that long-run reversal is not solely due to the corrections of prior momentum.” Does this suggest the limits of overreaction theories? Or “there may be other factors causing longrun reversal in general”, as the authors mentioned? In my suspicion, it may simply because of measurement error. By using another way of measuring and identifying the market states, this study will examine whether the puzzle is still there. 2.3 Regime-switching Model and Market State In Cooper et al (2003), they define two market states: “‘UP’ is when the lagged threeyear market return is non-negative, and ‘DOWN’ is when the three-year lagged market return is negative.” Although their results are robust using one- or two- year lagged market states and risk-adjustments, the definition of market states is still rather subjective. Why not use six months as the window? Why not set the cutting return to be 0.5% instead of 0%? ... Questions as these are unavoidable. Besides, defining market states according to the sign of index returns may misclassify the true state of the market. Suppose the index return over a given lag period, say 36 months is positive. Thus, the market is considered to follow an UP state according to Coopers et. al (2003). However, if the market is volatile, it is possible to have many down states 8 within the 36-month period. It is very likely that the holding period is actually following a recent down market, instead of UP market. Consequently, it may be quite misleading to classify that period as a bullish period. Conversely, a DOWN market according to their classification may actually consist of many up states. Again, if this is true, then it is misleading to consider that period as a down period. Here, I provide a more inclusive definition of UP and DOWN market states by fitting a Markov switching model to excess returns (over Treasury bills) on the market index. From the literature in statistics, economics and finance, regime-switching models have their advantages in identifying the market states. Often, we define model instability as a switch in a regression equation from one regime to another. However, in many cases, we may have little information on the dates at which parameters change, and thus need to make inferences about the turning points as well as the significance of parameter shifts. In statistics and econometrics, a lot research has been done on switching models. In the sixties and seventies, many models have been developed to deal with the issue, for example, Quandt (1958, 1960, 1972), Farley and Hinich (1970), H. Kim and Siegmund (1989) and I.-M. Kim and Maddala (1991). An interesting and important point of the above models is that the time at which a structural change occurs is endogenous to the model. Hamilton (1989) proposes a tractable state-dependent Markov-switching model. We can apply it to the important case of structural changes in the parameters of an autoregressive 9 process. Compared to the traditional models, there are at least three advantages of this model. First, the model sorts data endogenously into regimes. Second, unlike the traditional models, in this latent variable model, we do not need to assume the information set of the researcher, i.e., the econometrician, coincides with that of the agent in the market. Thirdly, empirically, among other studies, Ryden et al (1998) show that the Markov-switching model can explain the temporal and distributional properties of stock returns. The model has drawn a lot attention in modeling structural changes in dependent data. In economics, it has been used to identify business fluctuations, see Hamiltion (1989); to study the changes in real interest rates, Garcia and Perron (1996). Recently, the model has been used extensively in finance area, esp. to model the nonlinear structure in time series data. Turner et al (1989) use the model to explain a time-varying risk premium in stock returns. Methodologically, they consider a Markov-switching model which allows either the mean or the variance or both to differ between the two regimes. Hamilton and Lin (1996) adapt the model to capture the dynamics between the stock market and business cycle. Gordon and St-Amour (2000) use a two-state Markov process to model risk aversion, called as preference regimes, and link this model with the cyclical pattern of asset prices. Specifically, some research has been conducted on identifying market states. Borrowing the method from Turner et al (1989), Schaller and van Norden (1997) find strong evidence for switching behavior in stock returns in the US market. By allowing for 10 switch in both means and variances, they discover two distinct states: in one state, the excess returns are low and the variance is low; in the other state, the excess return goes to negative and the variance is high. The results agree with Brock et al (1992) and Maheu and McCurdy (2000). For the point of illustration, a specific description of the market state from Nielsen and Olesen (2000) will be cited in Section III. III. Research Design and Data 3.1 Data The data are all NYSE and AMEX stocks listed on the CRSP monthly file. To be consistent with Cooper et al (2003), the sample period is from January 1926 to December 1995. To identify the market states, I will collect monthly excess returns on the valueweighted market index. Excess return is the difference between the market returns on CRSP Value-Weighted Index (adjusted for dividends) and the one-month Treasury-bill rate. 3.2 Methodology and Research Design 3.2.1 On identifying market states In this study, I will mainly follow Hamilton’s (1989) Markov-switching model to identify two market states. A normal regression model without any switching is: 11 yt xt et , et ~ i.i.d .N (0, 2 ) (1) A model with structural breaks in the parameters is: yt xt St et , t 1, 2, 3..., T . (2) et ~ N (0, St ) (3) S (1 S t ) S t (4) 2 t S 2 02 (1 S t ) 12 S t (5) S t 0 or 1, (6) t (Regime 0 or 1) where under regime 1, parameters are given by and 12 , and under regime 0, parameters are given by and 02 . If the dates of switching or structural breaks are know a priori, the above will be reduced to a dummy variable model. The problem here is we do not know when St is 0 or 1. The evolution of the discrete variable St may be dependent upon S t 1 , S t 2 , …, S t r , in which case the process of St is named as an r-th order Markov switching process. Here, I adapt the standard Hamilton’s (1989) model into the following model: Rt RFt St ( Rt 1 RFt 1 St 1 ) t (7) ~ N (0, 2 ) (8) S 0 (1 S t ) 1 S t (9) t t Pr S t 1 S t 1 1 p, Pr S t 0 S t 1 0 q (10) 12 where St , equals to 0 or 1, follows a first order Markov switching process. Rt is monthly return on the CRSP Value-Weighted Index (adjusted for dividends). RFt is risk-free interest rate, here I use one-month Treasury bill rate. Please note that this model allows for the switching in means, and that an autoregressive term is included in each state. The parameter estimates can be obtained by numerically maximizing the log likelihood function. The likelihood function and the maximizing procedure are standard for regime-switching models and described in both Hamilton (1994), section 22.4 and Kim and Nelson (1999), chapter 4. Given parameter estimates of the model, we can make inference on St using all the information in the sample by using Hamilton’s (1989) filter and Kim’s (1994) smoothing. Thus, we can get the smoothed probability of stock returns. By way of illustration, I would like to cite one of the results from Nielsen and Olesen (2000), which studies the Danish market. 13 In their figure 2 is the probability that observation t is in state 0 given the information on current and past stock returns available at time t. It is natural to use a 50% probability cutoff point to delineate between UP and DOWN market. That is, at time t, if the smoothed probability of the UP state is say 0.7, I label the market state then as an UP state. If the smoothed probability is 0.4, I label the market state then as a DOWN state. States with probability bigger than 0.5 are assigned a value of “1” to indicate a bull market. States with probability equal to or less than 0.5 are assigned a value of 0 to indicate a bear market. Since the smoothed probability of market states can be very volatile, to decide the prior market state, I look at the entire lagged period, say month t-6 to t-1. To decide whether the entire lagged period is an UP or DOWN state, I use the following formula: N D i 1 t i /N (11) 14 For example, suppose the lagged period has 10 months, and this comprises 7 months (not necessary contiguous) where the market is in UP state (probability of UP state > 0.5) and 3 months in which the market is in down state. Then, the probability of the market being in the up state over the last 10 months is 0.7. Based on this, I classify the prior market as being in an UP state. Likewise, if the same probability is say 0.4, I classify the prior market as being in a DOWN state. I use the similar formula to decide the contemporaneous market state. I look at the entire holding period, say month t to t+6. The formula is: N D i 1 t i 1 /N (12) The rest is the same as defining prior market state above. 3.2.2 On calculating the momentum and long-run reversal profits I will mainly follow Cooper et al (2003). Here I would just outline the major steps. For details, please refer to Cooper et al (2003). It is a rather standard process including prior 6-months of formation-period and 6, 12, and 60 months of test-period. The momentum portfolio is defined as long in the prior 6-month winners (highest decile) and short in the prior 6-months losers (lowest decile). To form the Fama-French (1993) risk-adjusted profits, for each holding-period month, I regress the time series of raw profits on three factors and a constant. The three factors are a) the excess return of the value-weighted market index over the one-month Treasure bill rate (MKTRF), b) the small-minus-big return premium (SMB) and the high-book-to-market-minus-low-book-to-market return premium (HML). Thus, the risk-adjusted profits are 15 Rktadj Rkt ˆ1k MKTRFt ˆ2k SMBt ˆ3k HMLt (13) where Rkt is the raw profit for the strategy in the holding-period month k, for k=1, 2,…60, in calendar month t. The ˆ s are the estimated loading of the time-series of raw profits in holding-period-month k on their respective factors. The monthly raw or FamaFrench-adjusted profits are cumulated to form the holding-period profits (CAR). CARt K 2 K2 R k K1 * k ,t k (14) where R* is either raw ( Rkt ) or risk-adjusted ( Rktadj ) profits and the (K1, K2) pairs are (1, 6), (1, 12), and (13, 60). 3.2.3 On analyzing the profits across market states Cooper et al’s (2003) results may be contaminated by the contemporaneous market state. In particular, it is not clear whether the strong momentum that they find following UP states is due to delayed overreaction (their explanation) or simply due to the fact that momentum happens to be strong during a holding period in which the market is also in an UP state. a. Contingency table To disentangle the prior and contemporaneous market state influences, I first use a 2 x 2 contingency table to document the distribution of momentum profits by prior and contemporaneous market states. Table 1 presents the contingency table where I document in each cell: 1) Mean raw CAR, 2) Mean risk-adjusted CAR (using FF model), 3) 16 Proportion of holding periods where CAR is greater than 0, and 4) Proportion of holding periods where CAR less than or equal to 0. CON = UP CON = DOWN PRIOR = UP 1), 2) 3), 4) 1), 2) 3), 4) PRIOR = DOWN 1), 2) 3), 4) 1), 2) 3), 4) Table 1. CAR measures contingent on prior (PRIOR) and contemporaneous (CON) market states A series of tests would be conducted to investigate (a) whether CARs differ across prior states, and (b) whether CARs differ across contemporaneous states. In addition, I use the Chi-square test (see Siegel and Castellan (1988)) to test whether (a) the proportion of positive CARs differs across prior and contemporaneous states and (b) the proportion of negative CARs differs across the two groups. To investigate the impact of lagged and contemporaneous market states on momentum profits, I perform CAR regressions on prior and contemporaneous market states. I first perform regressions using dummy variables as described above to measure market states. I then perform regressions using continuous rather than discrete measure of the state of the market. b. Dummy Variable Regressions Regression 1 CARt K2 0 1 Dlag t t 17 Regression 2 CARt K2 0 1 Dlag t 2 Dcont t Regression 3 CARt K2 0 1 Dlag t 2 Dcont 3 ( Dlag t )( Dcont ) t Where: CARt K 2 is cumulative excess returns of the momentum portfolio which is formed at the beginning of month t and held for K2 month. K2 =6, 12 or 60. Dlag = 1 if the market is UP prior to holding period and 0 otherwise Dcon = 1 if the market is UP during the holding period and 0 otherwise. Dlag t * Dcon t is an interactive variable to measure the impact on CAR of the combined effects of an UP market in both prior and contemporaneous periods. Here, regression 1 is similar to the tests in Cooper et al (2003) to see whether the mean momentum profits following UP and DOWN markets are equal. The overreaction theories predict that 1 is significantly positive, when K2 is 6 or 12. When K2 is 60, 1 is significantly negative. In regression 2 and 3, we can ask many interesting questions. Is 2 significant or not? If yes, what happens to the significance of 1 , when 2 is added? What is the sign of 2 ? How about 3 ? c. Regressions using a Continuous Measure of Market State Following Coopers et. al.(2003), I perform CAR regressions on the lagged market returns as well as contemporaneous holding-period market returns. Again, we can ask similar questions about the signs and magnitudes of the s. Regression 4 CARt K 2 0 1 LAGMKTt 2CONMKTt t 18 where LAGMKTt is lagged 36-month market return at time t, and CONMKTt is contemporaneous holding-period market return. To summarize all the three series of tests, I want to point out four possible results that might be interesting for discussion. a) The prior market state influences momentum profits, but the contemporaneous one does not. b) The contemporaneous market state influences momentum profits, but the prior one does not. c) Both have significant influences. And d) neither of them have significant influences on momentum profits. Result d) is less likely to happen, since the tests in this study are somewhat consistent to the tests in Cooper et al (2003). Market state is expected to play a role on momentum profits. Result a) will best support the overreaction models (mainly DHS (1998) and HS (1999)), while c) cannot reject the overreaction models and needs future study. If result b) comes out, the overreaction models will be put into greater doubt, or at least, we need to turn to other overreaction models that can incorporate the influence of the contemporaneous market state. IV. Further Study Firstly, to continue with the discussion of the results in last section, if result b) comes out, further tests may need to check the risk of the contemporaneous market states. For example, if UP market is associated with higher risk, then the momentum profits may simply be the compensation for bearing the extra risk, which supports the tradition riskbased theories. 19 Besides, instead of identifying the market into two states as in Cooper et al (2003), I may also add a medium state between UP and DOWN markets. By adding this state, we get the chance to see whether momentum or long-run reversal profits will disappear in the middle states. This may serve as a further test of the overreaction theories. Reference: Alonso, A. and Rubio, G., (1990), "Overreaction in the Spanish equity market', Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 14, 1990, pp. 469-481 Brock, W., Lakonishok, J., and LeBaron, B. (1992), "Simple technical trading rules and the stochastic properties of stock returns", Journal of Finance, 47, 1731-64 Campbell, K. and Limmack, R. (1997), "Long-term overreaction in the UK stock market and size adjustments', Applied Financial Economics, Vol. 7, 1997, pp. 537-548. Chan, Hameed and Tong (2000), "Profitability of Momentun Strategies in the International Equity Markets", Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, June 2000 Cooper, M., Gutierrez, R., and Hameed, A. (2003), "Market States and Momentum", Working paper, forthcoming in Journal of Finance 2004. Da Costa, N., (1994), "Overreaction in the Brazilian stock market", Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 18, 1994, pp. 633-642 Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D. and Subrahmanyam, A., (1998), "Investor Psychology and Security Market Under- and Overreactions", Journal of Finance, Vol. LIII, No. 6. December 1998. De Long, J. Bradford, Shleifer, A., Summers, L., and Waldmann, R., (1991), "The survival of noise traders in financial markets", Journal of Business 64, pp. 1-20 DeBondt, W.F.M., and Thaler, R.H., (1985), "Does the stock market overract?", Journal of Finance 40, 793-808 Fama, E.F., and French, K.R., (1993), "Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds", Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 3-56 Farley, J.U., and Hinich, M.J., (1970), "A test for a shifting slope coefficient in a linear model.", Journal of the American Statistical Association, 65, 1320-1329 Forner, C. and Marhuenda, J., (2003), "Contrarian and Momentum Strategies in the Spanish Stock Market", European Financial Management, Vol. 9, No. 1, 2003, pp. 67-88 Garcia, R., and Perron, P., (1996), "An analysis of real interest under regime shift", Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, 111-125 Gordon, S., and St-Amour, P., (2000), "A preference regime model of bull and bear markets", The American Economic Review, Vol 90, No. 4 (Sep., 2000), 1019-1033 20 Hamilton, J.D. (1994), "Time series analysis", Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. Hamilton, J.D., (1989), "A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle.", Econometrica, 57(2), 357-384 Hamilton, J.D., and Lin, G. (1996), "Stock Market Volatility and the Business Cycle." Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11, 573-593 Hirshleifer,D., Subrahmanyam, A., and Titman, S., (1994), "Security analysis and trading patterns when some investors receive information before others", Journal of Finance 49, pp. 1665-1698 Hong, H. and Stein, J., (1999), "A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading and overreaction in asset markets", Journal of Finance, Vol. LIV, No 6, Dec 1999 Jegadeesh, N., and Titman, S., (1993), "Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency", Journal of Finance 48, 65-91 Kim C., and Nelson, C.R., (1999), "State-space models with regime switching", The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, London, England. Kim, C., (1994), "Dynamics linear models with markov-switching", Journal of Econometrics, 60, 1-22 Kim, H. J., and Siegmund, D., (1989), "The likelihood ratio test for a change-point in simple linear regression.", Biometrika, 76, 409-423 Kim, I.-M., and Maddala, G.S., (1991), "Multiple structural breaks and unit roots in the nominal and real exchange rates.", Unpublished manuscript. Department of Economics, The University of Florida. MacDonald, R. and Power, D., (1991), "Persistence in UK stock market returns: aggregated and disaggregated perspectives", in Taylor (ed.), Money and Financial Markets (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1991), pp. 277-296 Maheu, J.M., and McCurdy, T., (2000), "Identifying bull and bear markets in stock returns", Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Jan 2000, 18, 1, 100-112 Mai, H., (1995), "Sur-reaction sur le marche francais des actions au Reglement Mensuel 19771990", Finance, Vol. 16, 1, 1995, pp. 113-136 Nielsen, S., and Olesen. J. O. (2000), "Regime-switching stock returns and mean reversion", Working paper, Department of Economics, Copenhagen Business School. Quandt, R. E. (1958), "The estimation of the parameters of a linear regression system obeying two separate regimes.", Journal of American Statistical Association, 53, 873-880. Quandt, R. E. (1960), "Tests of the hypothesis that a linear regression system obeys two separate regimes.", Journal of the American Statistical Association, 55, 324-330 Quandt, R. E. (1972), "A new approach to estimating switching regressions.", Journal of the American Statistical Association, 67, 306-310. Rouwenhourst (1998), "International Momentum Strategies", Journal of Finance, 267-284 21 Ryden, T., Terasvirta, T., and Asbrink, S., (1998), "Stylied facts of daily return series and the hidden markov model", Journal of Applied Econometrics, 1998, 13, 217-244 Schaller, H., and Van Norden, S., (1997), "Regime switching in stock market returns", Applied Financial Economics, 1997, 7, 177-191 Siegel and Castellan (1988), "Nonparametric Statistics in Behavioral Science", Chapter 6 Turner, C.M., Startz, R. and Nelson, C.R. (1989), "A markov model of heteroscedasticity, risk and learning in the stock market," Journal of Financial Economics, 25, 3-22 22