Can diversification degree amplify momentum and contrarian anomalies? Co-authored by: Houda BEN MHENNI HAJ YOUSSEF Economics and Applied Finance Research Unit The Institute of High Commercial Studies Carthage, Tunisia hbenmhenni@ yahoo.fr (216) 21 32 76 48 Lassad EL MOUBARKI Paris Dauphine University elmoubarki_lassad@yahoo.fr (216) 97 37 91 04 Olfa BENOUDA SIOUD Associate Professsor Economics and Applied Finance Research Unit The Institute of High Commercial Studies Carthage, Tunisia olfa.benouda@ihec.rnu.tn (216) 98 64 80 64 Abstract This paper analyses the impact of industrial diversification on the profitability of contrarian and momentum strategies. Our findings show that the momentum strategy seems to be no more profitable in the recent years. In fact, while momentum strategies earn large positive and significant returns before the 2000 crash, these returns are negative after the crash. Then, firms are classified into two groups according to the intensity of their industrial diversification by the Ward (1963) method. We find that, for the non -diversified sample, no effect is significant. However, for the diversified sample, the significant contrarian effect observed in the medium term disappears in the long run. Before the crash, we find a more pronounced momentum effect for the non -diversified sample. After the crash, we identify a contrarian effect more important for this sample. Moreover, the Bootstrap without replacement results do not support the risk based explanation. 1 Keywords: corporate diversification, momentum, Bootstrap, cross-sectional variance of expected return, risk 1. Introduction The momentum and contrarian anomalies have been witnessed not only in the American market but also in many international financial markets (Patro and Wu, 2004; Lewellen, 2002; Rouwenhorst, 1998; Richards, 1997). Based on the fact that the best (bad) performing stocks will continue their upward (downward) trend, the momentum strategies, which consist in buying stocks with high returns (winners) and selling stocks with low return (losers), are profitable in the medium run (Jegadeesh and Titman 1993). In the long run, the trend will reverse and the contrarian strategy, implying a long position in the past losers and short position in the winners, will be profitable during 3-5 years (DeBondt and Thaler, 1985, 1987). Two competing approaches are put forward to account for the profitability of these trading strategies: the first is the rational approach that consists in explaining the momentum anomaly by systematic factors of the risk ignored by the standard models. The second is the behavioral approach that explains the strategy’s profits by judgment biases. These judgment biases induce investors’ over-reaction or under-reaction to information and produce continuation and of stock returns’ reversals. The behavioral models also suggest that momentum and contrarian effects should be more severe for firms that are hard-to-value (Daniel and Titman 1999) and suffering from a higher level of informational asymmetry (Jegadeesh and Titman 2001). Prior studies recorded a significant relation between industrial diversification and information asymmetry.Nonetheless, they offer contradictory predictions about how diversification affects the level of information asymmetry. On the one hand, the degree of information asymmetry between managers and outsiders may differ for the diversified versus the focused firms. The reason is twofold. First, diversified firms are required to report only limited accounting information for their business segment. Therefore, diversified firms’ managers can observe divisional cash- flows while outsiders can observe only noisy estimates of divisional cash flows (Rajan et al. 2000; Nanda and Narayanan, 1999). Aware of this advantage, managers may manage earnings and exercise considerable discretion in allocating revenues, costs, and assets across the business segments (Givoly et al. 1999; Dunn and Nathan, 1998). Thus, the consolidated nature of earnings for the diversified firms could actually imply less transparency to outsiders and reported earnings will convey less value-relevant information (Habib et al. 1997). Second, diversified firms operate in many industries and have more complex structures while individual financial analysts often specialize within a particular industry (Boudoukh et al. 1994).Hence, analyzing the firm’s earnings 2 reports requires more resources and expertise and dealing with a diversified firm will be a difficult task (Zuckerman, 2000; Dunn and Nathan, 1998). As a result, the degree of informational asymmetry is likely to be more acute in diversified firms. On the other hand, corporate diversification may reduce the asymmetric information problems because of the aggregate nature of firms’ accounting reports. Indeed, firms that operate in different industries are likely to derive cash flows that are not perfectly correlated. Thus, the errors made by outsiders’ in predicting these cash flows are imperfectly or negatively correlated across the segments and the absolute value of the percentage error in the forecast of diversified firm’s consolidated cash flows may be lowered. In other words, if the errors that outsiders make in forecasting segment cash flows are not perfectly positively correlated then the consolidated forecast may be more precise for a diversified firm than a forecast for a focused firm. Therefore, the degree to which the predictions of outsiders differ from the managers’ private information could be reduced (Hadlock et al. 1999; Thomas, 2002; Clarke et al. 2004). In brief, prior studies affirm that industrial diversification has an impact on the level of information asymmetry. The behavioral models also suggest that momentum anomaly is affected by information asymmetry. Specifically, they argue that the momentum (and contrarian) effect is attributed to inefficient stock price reaction to the firm’s specific information (Jegadeesh and Titman, 2001). Empirical evidence support that it is related to various proxies for the quality and type of information that is provided about the firm, the relative amounts of information disclosed publicly and being generated privately (Hong et Stein, 1999). Therefore, mispricing should be more severe among securities that are hard to value and momentum and contrarian effects are likely to be greater. Thus, this paper aims to study the impact of industrial diversification on the profitability of contrarian and momentum strategies. If industrial diversification decreases the level of asymmetric information, the momentum and contrarian effects must be less pronounced for the diversified firms. Contrarily, if industrial diversification increases the level of asymmetric information, the momentum and contrarian effects must be less pronounced for the diversified firms. Using Monthly returns, the WRSS strategy were applied to 249 American listed stocks from January 1994 to April 2004. In contrast to previous studies using older data, our results show that the momentum strategy seems to stop being profitable. To study the impact of the 2000 crash on our results, we implement the WRSS strategy during the [01/1994-03/2000] and [04/2000-04/2004] sub-periods. Our results indicate that while momentum strategies earn large positive and significant returns during the first sub- period, these returns are negative during the second subperiod. As Hong and Stein (2003) report, the 2000 market crash is qualified by negative returns. 3 Then, firms are classified according to the intensity of their industrial diversification by Ward‘s (1963) method of hierarchical cluster analysis. According to this method, our sample should be classified into two subsamples: the diversified and non diversified samples. By re-implementing the WRSS strategy on these sub-samples, we find that, for the non diversified sample, no effect is significant. However, for the diversified sample, the significant contrarian effect observed in the medium term disappears in the long run. Before the crash, we find a momentum effect more pronounced for the non diversified sample. After the crash, we note a contrarian effect which is more important for this sample. The Bootstrap without replacement is used to explore the risk- based explanation of the profitability of trading strategies. Our results imply that the cross-sectional difference in expected returns does not, entirely, explain the trading strategies’ profits. Our investigation extends the literature both in behavioural finance and corporate diversification. Really, it’s noteworthy to verify the persistence of the momentum and contrarian anomalies in recent years for two reasons: The first is to avoid data mining problems and the second is to assess the extent to which investors have learned from earlier trends. Moreover, many studies revealed that the contrarian or momentum portfolios formed by firm characteristics such as size, book-to-market, and/or dividend can yield a significant positive return. Nevertheless, in spite of its importance, industrial diversification remains not studied. Also, our study contributes to the literature on corporate diversification. According to the latest surveys, the values of diversified firms are discounted compared with non diversified firms (Jensen, 1986; Stulz, 1990; Denis, et al., 1997). We provided evidence that diversified firms are more efficiently valued. In fact, before the crash, the non diversified firms were more overvalued and after the crash they become more undervalued. The paper is outlined as follows. Section 1 presents a literature review. Section 2 introduces the sample and the methodology. As for the results, they are presented in section 3, while alternative explanations are examined in section 4, and we shall conclude our research in the last section. 2. Literature review: Momentum and Contrarian effects The profitability of contrarian and momentum strategies was confirmed by empirical studies 1. Momentum portfolios, which entail long positions in the past best performing stocks (winners) and short positions in the past worst performing stocks (losers), yield significant positive profits in the medium term: 3–12 months (Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993). In contrast, a systematic reversal effect is found when a longer holding period (more than 3 years) is 1 Jegadeesh et Titman (1993), DeBondt et Thaler (1985), Daniel et al (1998), Barberis et al (1998), Hong et Stein (1999), Rouwenhorst (1999). 4 considered, and reversing the momentum strategy (buying past losers and selling past winners) results in the production of contrarian profits (DeBondt and Thaler 1985). While most of the empirical works point to some level of predictability in stock returns, the underlying explanation for this type of predictability remains challenging. The rational approach asserts that the standard models like CAPM or the three -factor model fail to take into account the systematic risk (Fama, 1998). To bypass this shortfall, Conrad and Kaul (1998) adopt the bootstrap and Monte Carlo -simulation techniques. They find that momentum and contrarian profits are explained by the cross-sectional variance of the stocks’ expected returns: The momentum strategy tends to buy the stocks with higher than average unconditional mean returns and sell the stocks with lower than average mean returns, and hence the momentum effect is not related to stock predictability. Advocates of the behavioral approach propose a number of theoretical models of investors’ behaviour to explain these serial correlation properties in stock prices. The underpinning of the Daniel et al. (1998) model is investor overconfidence. They consider that stock prices are determined by the informed investors who are subject to two biases: overconfidence and self-attribution. Overconfidence in their signals causes overreaction to their private information, and self-attribution causes under-reaction to public information. Overreaction to private information leads them to push up the prices of the winners above their fundamental values. This trend will be reversed, in the long run, when public information will be confirmed. Baberis et al. (1998) present a pattern consisting of a representative investor who believes that earnings tend to move between two different “regimes”. In regime A, earnings are mean reverting and in regime B earning are trending. Specifically, when a positive earnings surprise is followed by another positive (negative) surprise, the investor raises the likelihood that he is in the trending regime, he tends to become too optimistic (pessimistic) about the future profitability of the firm. As a result, firms realizing good earnings’ growths tend to become overvalued, and those realizing bad earnings’ growths tend to become undervalued. The prices of these stocks ultimately undergo reversals as achieved earnings fail to meet expectations. Whereas when a positive surprise is followed by a negative surprise, the investor raises the likelihood that he is in the mean-reverting regime and he will under-react to earnings’ announcement. When this expectation is not confirmed by later earnings, stock prices show a delayed response to earlier earnings. Hong and Stein (1999) propose a model which focuses on the interactions between heterogeneous agents rather than the psychology of the representative agent. The informed investors or the “news watchers” make forecasts based only upon private information. The other investors “momentum traders” condition only on the most recent price change. The information obtained by the news watchers is broadcast slowly and hence is partially 5 incorporated in the prices. This slow diffusion of information generates momentum. To benefit from the prices’ momentum, the momentum traders continue to trade pushing up the prices above their fundamental value and generating an overreaction that will be later reversed. 3. Sample and methodology Momentum strategies will be profitable if stock returns display a positive serial correlation, whereas contrarian strategies will be profitable in case of negative serial correlation of stock returns. In order to examine the profits of these trading strategies, we employ the weighted relative strength strategy (WRSS) first proposed by Lo and MacKinlay (1990) and used by Conrad and Kaul (1998), Jegadeesh and Titman (2002), Lewellen (2002) to mention but a few. Under this strategy, investors hold assets in proportion to their market-adjusted returns. Specifically, they take long positions in stocks that have above average past returns and short stocks with below average past returns. So, the investment weight assigned to stock i at time t is given by Wi , t 1 * ri , t 1 N Where: N Rt 1 is the total number of stocks in the sample ri,t-1 is the return of stock i during ranking period t-1 Rt-1 is the average return across all stocks in the sample at time t-1 The profit of the WRSS strategy is given by: it n W r it it 1 ri,t is the return of stock i during holding period t A positive (negative) profit indicates that a momentum (contrarian) strategy is profitable. As Conrad and Kaul (1998) highlight, this strategy has, at least, three advantages. First, it captures the philosophy of return-based trading strategies since its success depends on the time-series’ behavior of asset prices. Second, the weighing scheme reflects investor’s beliefs. Third, weights on all stocks sum up to zero; that is, they imply a zero-cost portfolio. Our sample consists of 250 American firms listed from January 1, 1994, to April 30, 2004. Monthly returns are yielded from Datastream data files and the data for segment sales were taken from firm’s 10K annual reports published by the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). 6 We, first, implemented the WRSS strategy, on the entire sample, during different time periods ([1994, 2004]; [1994, 03/2000] and [04/2000, 04/2004]), for different holding periods (3, 6, 9 and 12 months) and for different ranking periods (3, 6, 9, 12 months). We stop our time period to March 2000 because it corresponds to the millennium crash and to be able to compare our results with prior studies. To minimize small-sample bias and raise the power of our tests, like Conrad and Kaul (1998) and Jegadeesh and Titman (2002), we construct trading strategies for overlapping holding periods on a monthly -frequency. Hence, we obtain 16 trading strategies for each time period. Then, firms of the sample are classified in two sub-samples according to their berry’s index: The diversified sample (Div) and the non diversified (NDiv) sample. We then re-implemented these strategies on these two sub-samples. The Berry Index is an entropy measure of industrial diversification which takes into account both the number of segments in which a firm operates and the relative importance of each segment in total firm sales (Jacquemin and Berry, 1979; Palepu, 1985). This measure increases with the number of segments, holding constant variance of the segment size, and decreases with variance of the segment size, holding the number of segments constant. Thus, a two-segment firm with equal segment sales is more diversified than a two-segment firm with unequal segment sales. The lower bound of the Berry index is 0 (a single segment) and it tends to 1 for a highly diversified firm (but not equal to 1). The Berry Index is defined as: n Berry 1Pi 2 i 1 Where n is the number of industry segments in which the firm is active and Pi is the share of the ith segment in the total sales of the firm. Firms are taxonomised as diversified and non diversified by Hierarchical cluster -analysis. The Hierarchical cluster- analysis is a statistical method for finding relatively homogeneous clusters of cases based on measured characteristics. It starts with each case in a separate cluster and then combines the clusters sequentially, reducing the number of clusters at each step until only one cluster is left. When there are N cases, this involves N-1 clustering steps, or fusions. Ward (1963) put forward a clustering procedure that computes the distance between two clusters. This popular method combines the two clusters at each stage which minimize the squared error function, or Euclidean sum of squares, E. Objective function E is defined as follows: MinE = kik (xi- k)2 249 15 247 248 241 245 239 240 234 236 226 230 223 224 221 222 214 216 208 211 204 207 200 201 196 197 194 195 191 192 193 187 190 185 186 178 181 176 177 171 172 167 169 159 165 149 150 147 148 143 146 139 140 134 136 128 131 118 124 116 117 114 115 105 111 103 104 95 98 92 93 87 88 82 86 80 81 77 78 73 74 76 69 72 66 68 64 65 60 62 54 55 49 50 43 44 35 39 32 33 30 31 28 29 26 27 23 25 14 22 10 11 8 9 6 2 243 5 145 164 225 1 203 129 108 228 132 84 173 198 206 85 237 130 99 242 57 235 122 157 168 102 162 119 38 137 53 217 67 229 233 170 17 127 232 215 18 227 7 166 20 202 142 63 3 231 12 161 37 48 47 180 100 144 40 151 101 97 70 121 244 126 125 219 199 61 213 56 220 13 138 71 133 91 109 36 183 45 75 46 123 94 246 83 179 58 158 154 163 141 210 189 218 4 113 34 188 19 96 90 120 155 152 212 182 107 112 89 205 209 174 59 51 42 184 160 153 106 24 238 16 79 52 175 135 156 41 110 21 249 248 245 247 240 241 236 239 230 234 224 226 222 223 216 221 211 214 207 208 201 204 197 200 195 196 193 194 190 191 192 186 187 181 185 177 178 172 176 169 171 165 167 150 159 148 149 146 147 140 143 134 136 128 131 118 124 116 117 114 115 105 111 103 104 95 98 92 93 87 88 82 86 80 81 77 78 74 76 69 72 73 66 68 64 65 60 62 54 55 49 50 43 44 35 39 32 33 29 31 26 27 23 25 14 22 10 11 81 9 6 2 164 139 132 5 145 129 57 228 229 198 242 203 84 237 108 122 85 166 99 246 142 12 119 227 161 233 37 17 18 7 202 20 215 38 217 162 225 102 212 173 127 168 130 157 206 137 170 235 232 53 40 67 184 58 158 154 182 46 160 94 156 21 174 96 112 48 113 59 51 42 120 209 100 47 3 163 231 218 4 155 34 15 63 189 19 123 183 179 90 107 141 210 83 135 152 188 175 220 56 243 110 36 13 138 109 125 133 180 45 126 71 101 89 199 61 91 79 219 28 121 97 153 75 238 213 41 205 151 52 24 30 16 244 70 144 106 249 248 245 247 240 241 236 239 230 234 224 226 222 223 216 221 211 214 207 208 201 204 197 200 195 196 193 194 190 191 192 186 187 181 185 177 178 172 176 169 171 165 167 148 149 146 147 136 140 131 134 117 128 111 116 103 105 93 98 88 92 81 82 78 80 76 77 73 74 69 72 63 68 55 60 50 54 48 49 35 39 44 31 33 27 29 23 26 11 14 2 9 5 8 132 43 164 101 143 32 202 47 215 163 159 16 170 151 137 6 157 141 168 166 102 227 64 18 233 173 217 85 209 38 246 162 212 3 145 53 133 225 142 130 67 232 99 237 228 127 89 118 84 108 235 122 37 242 198 203 120 57 4 229 1 129 100 15 13 107 155 135 83 95 34 218 12 189 152 206 10 20 19 119 17 175 46 161 97 213 114 231 22 182 179 96 174 123 106 40 75 45 153 527 154 94 183 156 24 87 42 184 124 113 86 110 51 158 65 70 62 90 91 210 28 25 79 160 205 112 21 219 61 121 199 126 56 244 150 41 30 238 59 220 180 243 139 58 188 138 144 66 104 71 109 125 115 36 249 15 247 248 243 245 240 241 236 239 230 234 224 226 222 223 216 221 211 214 207 208 201 204 197 200 195 196 192 193 194 190 191 186 187 181 185 178 179 176 177 171 172 167 169 149 165 147 148 140 146 134 136 117 131 111 116 103 105 93 98 88 92 81 82 78 80 76 77 73 74 69 72 63 68 55 60 50 54 39 44 49 33 35 29 31 26 27 14 23 11 9 8 2 101 132 180 110 164 47 213 5 202 85 143 119 157 34 215 3 232 168 163 159 227 53 170 122 133 67 84 6 151 17 38 16 233 65 162 141 173 217 212 104 90 145 129 100 225 130 1 229 37 57 4 203 166 118 108 127 86 237 99 142 46 228 198 235 242 174 120 205 66 244 28 126 160 238 150 199 61 112 56 25 18 154 41 58 30 109 139 219 36 138 125 144 135 115 79 21 220 71 91 43 231 102 137 95 114 32 64 97 161 113 75 19 96 42 189 20 209 13 218 10 155 206 121 175 152 22 182 12 107 123 183 83 156 24 59 52 184 89 188 48 87 7 246 128 62 70 51 210 40 124 45 158 153 106 94 1994 1995 132 101 249 15 247 248 243 245 240 241 236 239 230 234 224 226 222 223 216 221 211 214 207 208 201 204 197 200 194 195 196 192 193 190 191 186 187 181 185 178 179 176 177 171 172 167 169 149 165 147 148 140 146 134 136 117 131 111 116 103 105 93 98 88 92 81 82 78 80 76 77 73 74 69 72 63 68 60 62 50 54 55 44 49 35 39 31 33 27 29 23 26 11 14 2 9 47 8 164 213 160 5 219 114 139 110 180 53 118 242 133 4 122 6 151 65 104 84 162 90 143 85 119 173 113 215 168 212 202 138 233 64 232 217 17 67 38 227 141 157 34 159 225 145 52 229 129 137 1 130 100 228 37 120 203 166 237 170 127 108 57 99 86 142 46 174 235 198 210 124 128 158 183 707 106 94 182 40 12 45 153 83 107 123 20 102 19 13 96 121 209 206 175 218 152 189 75 231 10 95 22 163 3 161 97 32 16 155 41 199 61 43 66 112 24 188 246 156 89 51 42 184 25 220 56 244 59 205 48 115 87 109 58 135 30 126 125 36 144 18 154 21 238 150 79 28 91 71 1996 1997 0 0 0 0 0 10 10 10 10 10 20 20 20 20 20 30 30 30 30 30 40 40 40 40 40 50 50 231 170 127 108 212 138 152 106 209 34 214 182 217 242 141 229 218 4 123 107 143 91 246 97 130 37 184 18 215 183 41 90 52 189 48 179 51 132 100 94 75 155 58 113 79 153 42 154 65 233 227 53 57 202 157 160 19 166 168 158 119 198 67 232 102 17 3 161 16 174 162 122 12 175 20 173 99 203 228 206 84 85 137 235 156 237 129 1 225 145 248 249 245 247 240 241 236 239 230 234 224 226 222 223 216 221 208 211 205 207 201 204 197 200 195 196 193 194 191 192 187 190 185 186 178 181 176 177 171 172 167 169 159 163 165 150 151 148 149 146 147 140 142 134 139 128 131 118 124 116 117 114 115 109 111 103 105 95 98 92 93 87 88 82 83 80 81 77 78 74 76 72 73 68 69 64 66 60 62 55 56 50 54 44 47 49 39 40 35 38 31 33 28 29 26 27 23 25 14 22 10 11 8 9 2 7 63 6 180 36 133 220 199 61 210 45 164 238 244 96 89 21 101 135 70 46 188 121 112 86 136 32 59 5 104 30 243 24 13 110 15 125 43 219 71 120 126 213 144 170 231 229 91 212 108 127 100 130 34 232 182 209 141 106 206 138 218 246 4 152 97 107 242 132 123 156 75 214 155 94 179 90 51 42 153 79 48 41 183 46 215 58 18 65 52 37 184 70 188 145 225 1 129 84 228 203 237 235 99 85 173 137 158 17 157 53 67 57 198 19 202 168 160 233 227 16 119 174 166 102 3 154 113 161 20 122 175 162 12 248 249 245 247 240 241 236 239 230 234 224 226 222 223 216 221 208 211 205 207 201 204 197 200 195 196 193 194 191 192 187 190 185 186 178 181 176 177 171 172 167 169 159 163 165 150 151 148 149 146 147 142 143 139 140 131 134 124 128 117 118 115 116 111 114 105 109 103 104 96 98 93 95 88 92 82 87 80 81 77 78 74 76 72 73 68 69 64 66 60 62 55 56 49 50 54 44 47 39 40 35 38 31 33 28 29 26 27 23 25 14 22 10 11 8 9 2 7 217 6 112 86 121 13 189 32 136 43 59 5 238 133 45 36 101 244 164 135 21 89 126 83 210 219 220 180 125 63 61 199 71 144 120 213 15 110 30 243 24 24 30 120 63 213 71 133 112 220 126 144 110 219 61 210 199 164 45 249 51 247 248 241 245 239 240 234 236 224 226 230 222 223 216 221 208 211 205 207 201 204 197 200 195 196 193 194 191 192 187 190 185 186 178 181 176 177 171 172 167 169 163 165 151 159 149 150 147 148 143 146 140 142 134 139 128 131 118 124 115 116 117 111 114 105 109 103 104 96 98 93 95 88 92 82 87 80 81 77 78 74 76 72 73 68 69 65 66 62 64 56 60 54 55 49 50 44 47 40 43 38 39 33 35 29 31 27 28 25 26 22 23 14 15 18 10 11 8 9 2 7 121 61 86 5 32 13 145 59 225 129 85 84 99 203 173 237 228 100 12 161 3 122 20 158 233 154 119 160 202 227 198 168 102 157 53 229 57 235 179 137 17 166 123 107 132 242 97 90 108 246 170 138 231 212 162 67 232 91 83 34 106 209 182 141 127 4 130 152 175 217 113 218 206 19 214 37 58 52 42 41 183 79 153 189 156 75 155 94 243 174 101 36 180 238 244 135 89 136 125 184 16 215 48 188 70 46 21 249 248 245 247 240 241 236 239 230 234 224 226 222 223 216 221 213 214 208 211 204 207 200 201 196 197 194 195 191 192 193 187 190 185 186 178 181 176 177 171 172 167 169 159 165 149 150 147 148 143 146 139 140 131 134 124 128 117 118 115 116 111 114 104 105 103 98 95 96 92 93 87 88 82 86 80 81 77 78 73 74 76 69 72 66 68 64 65 60 62 55 56 50 54 44 49 40 43 38 39 33 35 31 32 29 30 27 28 25 26 22 23 14 15 10 11 8 9 6 2 164 5 136 59 219 13 37 63 215 113 112 94 155 120 75 156 52 42 18 45 51 180 58 135 184 189 21 188 79 70 16 158 41 126 71 109 133 238 220 125 91 144 106 199 61 183 110 243 121 151 36 101 97 160 174 244 24 67 3 175 12 107 231 162 161 127 108 170 212 90 218 19 182 209 217 34 141 100 166 46 123 83 210 205 163 152 132 4 206 232 235 246 137 17 227 202 168 157 153 122 102 154 233 138 48 71 229 47 119 142 53 20 225 145 129 173 130 179 242 237 228 57 99 85 198 84 203 89 249 248 245 247 240 241 236 239 230 234 224 226 222 223 216 221 212 214 208 211 204 207 200 201 196 197 194 195 191 192 193 187 190 185 186 178 181 176 177 171 172 167 169 159 165 149 150 147 148 143 146 139 140 131 134 124 128 117 118 115 116 111 114 104 105 103 98 93 95 88 92 86 87 81 82 78 80 76 77 72 73 74 68 69 65 66 62 64 55 60 50 54 44 49 40 43 35 39 32 33 30 31 28 29 26 27 23 25 14 22 10 11 8 9 6 2 213 5 108 15 217 164 157 235 119 233 173 154 179 206 137 17 127 53 48 142 166 229 232 202 71 227 20 168 102 225 145 129 203 198 85 84 130 228 237 57 242 99 122 56 220 13 36 91 219 109 133 71 125 180 144 238 199 61 136 151 106 97 126 121 110 101 243 244 45 24 46 189 70 183 52 174 79 21 59 120 135 158 58 123 94 170 160 205 75 42 89 155 51 184 156 246 41 188 16 209 38 12 3 175 18 215 153 162 37 161 67 96 47 138 107 83 90 100 152 231 112 63 141 34 210 19 182 163 113 132 218 4 0 0 0 0 0 10 10 10 10 10 20 20 20 20 20 30 30 30 30 30 40 40 40 40 40 50 50 7 Where for a given classification, firm i belongs to cluster k, xi is the value of the Berry Index for the firm i, and k is the mean of Berry Index in cluster k. The summations are, firstly, the squared error of firm i in cluster k for the Berry Index; secondly, for all observations (firms) i within cluster k; and finally, to total the error over all clusters k. This hierarchical clustering process can be displayed as a tree, or dendrogram, where each step in the clustering process is illustrated by a join of the tree. The choice of the number of clusters in the classification tree relies on the Euclidean distances: A great distance between classes indicates a high degree of dissimilarity between classes. Each year we classify our sample firms according to their Berry Index ( the variable x i ) . The ward methods’ tree, displayed in figure 1, shows that our sample should be classified in two classes: Diversified and non diversified. In fact, the Euclidean distance is maximal for a number of classes equal two for all years. hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") hclust (*, "w ard") FIGURE 1 The Ward MethodTree The centre and the number of stocks of each class are presented in Table 1. The number of stocks in the non -diversified sample is more important than the diversified sample until 1997. After this date, the number of diversified firms exceeded the number of non- diversified firms indicating that more firms have become diversified. The centres of the two classes have dropped from 1994 to 2003, while the non diversified sample, plummeted from 0.0535 in 1994 to 0.0077 in 2003. TABLE 1 CENTRES AND NUMBER OF STOCKS 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 8 NDiv Div centers 0.0535 0.0458 0.02528 0.0028 0.0010 0.0008 0.0007 0.0013 0.0027 0.0077 number 159 159 148 126 121 119 116 98 102 107 centers 0.558 0.5534 0.5232 0.4908 0.4828 0.4894 0.4815 0.5068 0.5116 0.5238 number 90 90 101 123 128 130 133 151 147 142 This implies that firms of the non -diversified samples became more and more specialized. Regarding the diversified sample, the centre has slightly fallen from 0.558 to 0.5238. These findings are similar to those of Wrigley (1970) According to this author, American firms chose to be highly- specialized or highly -diversified but not in the middle state. We first implemented the strategies on the entire sample and for the [1994-1999] period because it matched with the time period used in the previous studies (Jegadeesh and Titman, 2001) and we will concentrate on the 6month -ranking period strategies because they were the primary focus of the original Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)research. 4. Results 4.1 Profitability of the trading strategies: Medium term results We first implemented the strategies on the entire sample and for the [01/1994-03/2000] period because it corresponds with the time period used in the early studies (Jegadeesh and Titman, 2001) and we will focus on the six month -ranking period strategies because they were the primary focus of the original Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) study. Table 2 shows the profits of the trading strategies. For the [1994, 2004] time period, fourteen returns out of sixteen were negative, whereas only two returns were positive. Among the fourteen negative returns, four are not significant, four are significant at the 10% level and six are significant at the 5% level. The returns of six monthranking period are all negative and are significant for the nine and twelve month- holding periods. The most profitable strategy is the 12-12 month contrarian strategy with a return of 1.3%. The return of the famous 6-6 month strategy is negative and not significant. TABLE 2 AVERAGE RETURNS OF THE MEDIUM TERM TRADING STRATEGIES FOR THE DIFFERENT PERIODS 9 3 6 9 12 3 -0.0027 (0.18) -0.0020 (0.31) -0.0042 (0.04) -0.0054 (0.03) 6 -0.0019 (0.58) -0.0038 (0.15) -0.0066 (0.04) -0.0089 (0.02) 9 0.0044 (0.339) -0.0008 (0.070) -0.0107 (0.040) -0.0125 (0.038) 12 0.0074 (0.073) -0.0009 (0.064) -0.0108 (0.060) -0.0129 (0.064) 3 0.0005 (0.596) 0.0014 (0.214) 0.0024 (0.058) 0.0039 (0.036) 6 0.0012 (0.292) 0.0030 (0.039) 0.0053 (0.008) 0.0102 (0.000) 9 0.0022 (0.12) 0.0057 (0.01) 0.0092 (0.00) 0.0197 (0.00) 12 0.0042 (0.01) 0.0093 (0.00) 0.0134 (0.00) 0.0290 (0.00) 3 -0.0042 (0.46) -0.0065 (0.14) -0.0157 (0.00) -0.0144 (0.00) 6 -0.0052 (0.68) -0.0143 (0.02) -0.0283 (0.01) -0.0342 (0.00) 9 -0.017 (0.34) -0.0301 (0.01) -0.0488 (0.01) -0.0590 (0.01) 12 -0.0288 (0.07) -0.0351 (0.00) -0.0526 (0.01) -0.0646 (0.01) Ranking period 04/2000-04/2004 01/94-03/2000 01/94-04/2004 Holding period This table comprises the average returns of the zero-cost trading strategies implemented during 01/94-04/2004; 01/9403/2000 and 04/2000-04/2004 for 3, 6, 9 and 12 month- holding periods and 3, 6, 9, 12 month- ranking periods. The trading strategies buy winners and sell losers based on their past performance relative to the performance of an equal- it weighed index of all stocks. The dollar profits are given by n W 1 r it it where ri,t is the return of stock i Wi , t 1 * ri , t 1 Rt 1 N during the holding period t and the investment weight assigned to stock i at time t is given by , N is the total number of stocks in the sample, ri,t-1 is the return of stock i during the ranking period t-1, Rt-1 is the average return across all stocks in the sample at time t-1 The numbers in parentheses are significance level of the strategies ‘real ized profits. During the [1994-03/2000] period, all the returns of the 16 strategies are positive and only 4 are not statistically significant (3-3, 3-6, 3-9 and the 6-3 strategies). The 12-12 month- strategy is the most profitable with a return of 2.91%. The WRSS strategy based on the previous 6-month performance gains a positive but not significant return in the following 3 months (holding period = 3 months). This return is 0.31%; 0.58% and 0.94% for 6, 9 and 12-month holding period resp. These results are very close to those found in the previous studies. In fact, Jegadeesh and Titman (2002) and Conrad and kaul (1998) found a 6-6 month WRSS strategy return of 0.37% and 0.36% respectively. These results are in favor of the profitability of the momentum strategy in the 1990s. But our results are 10 reversed for the [04/2000, 04/2004] time period. All the return becomes negative and 12 are significant. The 66month contrarian strategy earns 1.44% while the 9-12 month strategy is the most profitable with a return of 5.90%. These results indicate that while momentum strategies earn large positive and significant returns during the 1994-2000 sample period, the latter are negative or insignificant for the entire sample period. It’s clear that, in later years, only the contrarian strategy is profitable in the medium run. This finding is in contrast to earlier studies based on older and different datasets which record a significant momentum effect in the medium run. This is to be accounted for by our time period which is more recent and by ending our time period in March 2000, we obtain results that are similar to prior studies. Our results corroborate, however, recent studies that assert that the momentum anomaly has disappeared in recent years. According to Malkiel (2003), momentum strategies occurred to generate positive relative returns during some periods of the late 1990s, but highly- negative relative returns during 2000. Mengoli (2004) reports that the most recent period shows a peculiar behavior both in terms of low-momentum and negative-reversal returns. In the same vein, Campbell (2004) affirms that momentum strategies have performed well on average but have been highly inconsistent, generating large profits in some years and losses in others. Schwert (2003) points out two possible explanations for such a pattern. The first is that the apparent profitability of momentum strategies was an artifact statistic. The second is that investors learn about any true predictable pattern and exploit it until it becomes no longer profitable. Finally, Shiller (2000) reports a fast growth in prices during the late 1990s followed by a crash after 2000 in all the international financial markets and attributes the decline in the market to the shifts in investor psychology. Moreover, regardless of the ranking period, average returns increase with the holding period for all time periods. Yet, contrary to Conrad et al. (1998), these returns do not go up geometrically with the length of the holding period so that we could not conclude that security prices follow the random -walk process. 4.2 Industrial diversification and profitability of the trading strategies To study the potential impact of industrial diversification on the profitability of trading strategies, we implement the WRSS strategy on two sub-samples: The diversified sample (Div) and the non- diversified sample (NDiv). Table 3 displays average returns of 162 trading strategies for 01/1994-04/2004 time period and the numbers in brackets represent the significance level. Regarding the non -diversified sample, the WRSS strategy based on the previous 6 months performance presents positive returns of 0.15% ; 0.24% ; 0.01 % respectively, in the following 3, 6, 9 months and a negative return of 0,2304% during the following 12 months. This evidence is in favor of momentum profitability and contrarian strategies, respectively, in the medium horizon and the long horizon. TABLE 3 11 AVERAGE RETURNS OF THE TRADING STRATEGIES IMPLEMENTED ON THE DIVERSIFIED FIRMS’ SAMPLE AND NON DIVERSIFIED FIRMS’ SAMPLE Holding period→ 3 6 9 12 NDiv -0.0008 (0.49) 0.0007 (0.64) 0.0007 (0.74) -0.0013 (0.61) Div -0.0045 (0.18) -0 .0040 (0.49) -0.0083 (0.28) -0.0119 (0.06) NDiv 0.0014 (0.31) 0.0024 (0.26) 0.0001 (0.97) -0.0023 (0.56) Div -0.0048 (0.13) -0.0085 (0.07) -0.0143 (0.05) -0.0138 (0.06) NDiv 0.0008 (0.73) -0.0012 (0.69) -0.0037 (0.41) -0.0062 (0.25) Div 0.0079 (0.01) -0.0103 (0.04) -0.0157 (0.04) -0.0141 (0.08) NDiv -0.0022 (0.49) -0.0039 (0.38) -0.0064 (0.28) -0.0097 (0.19) Div -0.0077 (0.02) -0.0124 (0.01) -0.0168 (0.03) -0.0153 (0.07) Ranking period 3 6 9 12 This table exhibits the average profits to medium -term trading strategies implemented on two sub-samples: The diversified sample (Div) and the non -diversified sample (NDiv). The Berry Index is defined as: n Berry 1Pi 2 i 1 where n is the number of industry segments in which the firm is active and Pi is the share of the ith it n W it rit 1 segment in the total sales of the firm. The dollar profits are given by where ri,t is the return of stock i during the holding period t and the investment weight assigned to stock i at time t is given by Wi , t 1 * ri , t 1 N Rt 1 , N is the total number of stocks in the sample, ri,t-1 is the return of stock i during the month ranking period t-1, Rt-1 is the average return across all stocks in the sample at time t-1 The numbers in parentheses represent the significance level of realized strategise’ profits. To gauge the success of the momentum and contrarian strategies on the non -diversified sample, we tested the statistical significance of the sixteen strategy’s returns. Surprisingly, none is reliably distinguishable from zero. Opposite to the diversified sample, all the returns are negative and twelve are significant indicating that only the contrarian strategy is profitable. The 12-9 strategy is the most profitable with a return of -1.68%. When we hold a ranking period constant, the returns of the contrarian strategies rise with the holding period up to 9 months,but decrease in the 12th month. For example, the return of a 6- month ranking strategy grows from 0.48% in the next three months to 1.44% during the next nine months and fall to 1.38% in the next twelve months. This trend leads us to believe that the return will revert to the mean in the long run. On the whole, these findings support the existence of a non -significant momentum effect in the medium term followed by a non -significant contrarian effect in the non -diversified sample. However, for the diversified sample, our results are in favor of the profitability of the contrarian strategy in the medium term. To study the impact 12 of the 2000 crash on our results, we study the profitability of the 6-month ranking period of the WRSS strategy, on the two sub-samples, during the [01/1994-03/2000] and [04/2000-04/2004] time periods. Table 4 displays the results. TABLE 4 RETURNS OF THE TRADING STRATEGIES IMPLEMENTED ON THE DIVERSIFIED AND THE NON -DIVERSIFIED SAMPLES DURING DIFFERENT TIME PERIOD 3 6 9 12 1/94-03/2000 04/200004/2004 1/94-04/2004 NDiv 0.0039 (0.01) -0.0018 (0.483) 0.0014 (0.31) Div -0.0008 (0.62) -0.010191 (0.16) -0.0048 (0.13) NDiv 0.0060 (0.01) -0.0042 (0.249) 0 .0024 (0.26) Div 0.0008 (0.68) -0.0215 (0.05) -0.0085 (0.07) NDiv 0.0079 (0.02) -0.0141 (0.01) 0.0001 (0.97) Div 0.0042 (0.25) -0.0408 (0.01) -0.0143 (0.05) NDiv 0.0111 (0.02) -0.0240 (0.00) -0.0023 (0.56) Div -0.0092 (0.22) -0.0229 (0.15) -0.0138 (0.06) This table comprises the average profits to medium term trading strategies implemented on the diversified sample and the non diversified sample during 01/94-04/2004; 01/94-03/2000 and it 04/2000-04/2004. The dollar profits are given by n W 1 r it it where ri,t is the return of stock i during the holding period t and the investment weight assigned to stock i at time t is given by Wi , t 1 * ri , t 1 N Rt 1 , N is the total number of stocks in the sample, ri,t-1 is the return of stock i during the 6 month ranking period t-1, Rt-1 is the average return across all stocks in the sample at time t-1 The bracketed numbers stand for the significance level of realized strategies’ profits of. With regard to the [01/1994, 03/2000] time period, the non- diversified sample exhibits a significant momentum effect for all the holding period. The return hikes from 0.4 % for the 3-month holding period to 1.12 % for the 12-month holding period but less than geometrically. The return of 0.60% of the 6-6 month strategy which is almost the double of the return of the entire sample and the return found in earlier studies. Nevertheless, the diversified sample shows a non- significant momentum effect for the 6 and 9-month holding period. The famous 66-month strategy generates a return of 0.08% witch represents 1/4 of the return of the entire sample but this return is not significant. For 04/2000- 04/2004 time period, the most important evidence is that the signs of returns are inverted and all returns become negative. The momentum effect observed in the time period of late March 2000, for 13 the non diversified sample becomes a contrarian effect. In fact, the return of 0.60% for the 6 month holding period drops to a non significant return of -0.42% and become significant for the nine and twelve month- holding period. As far as the diversified sample is concerned , all the returns are negative too, but higher then those of the non diversified sample. The most profitable strategy for the diversified sample is the 6-9 month contrarian strategy with a return of -4.08%. This return is more important than the most profitable 6-12 month contrarian strategy for the non diversified sample (2.40%). These findings contradict the pervious literature on the profitability of the momentum strategy in the medium run. Nonetheless, they are obviously driven by the March 2000 crash. Hong and Stein (2003) and Hong et al. (2001) state that a market crash is qualified by negative returns. Consequently, two important results are drawn from Table 4. First, independently from the time period studied, the stock price behavior for the two groups is different. Second, this behavior has changed in the 2000’s: In the [1994, 2000] time period, the trend of the non -diversified exhibits a momentum effect but the diversified firms were almost, efficiently priced. By expanding the time period to the year 2004, the results are reversed. The non diversified sample becomes efficiently valued and the diversified sample exhibits a contrarian effect instead of a momentum effect in the medium run. 4.3 Industrial diversification and the profitability of trading strategies: Long term results Figure 2 presents the average return of the 6 -month ranking period strategy during the different holding periods. For the whole sample, all the returns are negative. This evidence is in favor of the profitability of the contrarian strategy in both the medium and long run. Indeed, it seems to be driven by the presence of diversified firms in our sample. Actually, the contrarian effect is very pronounced for the diversified sample. The average return dips until it reaches -1.44%, which represents almost 150% the return of the entire sample. From the 12th month, it starts rising, while for the non diversified sample, the trend indicates a slight momentum- effect that begins to reverse from the 9th month. 14 0,01 0,005 0 3 6 9 12 15 18 NDiv 24 -0,005 Div Sample -0,01 -0,015 -0,02 FIGURE 2 Average Return of the 6 -Month Ranking Period Strategy Further details on the returns of the trading strategies in the first 24 months are displayed in Table 5. Among the 24 trading strategies, 20 strategies yield negative returns. The four remaining positive returns are related to the 24 month holding period in the non diversified sample. For this sample, the six -month ranking -period strategy generates TABLE 5 RETURNS OF THE LONG TERM TRADING STRATEGIES IMPLEMENTED ON DIVERSIFIED AND NON DIVERSIFIED FIRMS SAMPLES Ranking period 3 6 9 12 NDiv -0.0019 (0.51) -0.00274 (0.55) -0.0069 (0.29) -0.009 (0.29) Div -0.0050 (0.18) -0.00638 (0.21) -0.0064 (0.29) -0.0098 (0.18) NDiv -0.0006 (0.86) -0.000741 (0.89) -0.0035 (0.66) -0.0045 (0.69) Div -0.0045 (0.25) -0.00437 (0.40) -0.0059 (0.35) -0.0116 (0.11) NDiv 0.0012 (0.78) 0.0052 (0.51) 0.0083 (0.47) 0.0123 (0.44) Div -0.0037 (0.39) -0.0070 (0.21) -0.0113 (0.10) -0.0164 (0.05) Holding period 15 18 24 This table contains the average profits to the long term trading strategies implemented on the non diversified firms sample and the diversified firm sample. The trading strategies buy winners and sell losers based on their past performance relative to the performance of an equal-weighted index of all stocks. The dollar profits are given by it n W 1 r it it where ri,t is the return of stock i during the holding period t and the investment weight assigned to Wi , t 1 * ri , t 1 Rt 1 N stock i at time t is given by , N is the total number of stocks in the sample, ri,t-1 is the return of stock i during the ranking period t-1, Rt-1 is the average return across all stocks in the sample at time t-1 The numbers in parentheses are significance level of realize profits of strategies. 15 a return of -0.27% in the fifteen following months. This return rises to -0.0741% in the 18 following months and become positive in the 24 following months. This upward trend is recorded too for the 3, 9 and the 12- month ranking period. As for the diversified sample, and independently of the ranking period, the return surges in the 18 following months but drops in the 24 following months. However, the figures’ significance, in Table 5, indicates that all returns are not reliably different from zero for the two samples. Thus, we find that, for the non -diversified sample, the momentum in the medium run and the contrarian effect in the long run are both non significant; whereas , for the diversified sample, the significant contrarian effect observed in the medium term disappears in the long run . Table 6 presents the returns of the 6 -month ranking period strategy up to 24 months before and after the crash. Before the crash, all the returns are positive and statistically significant. First, these results prove the profitability of the momentum strategy in the long run for the two samples. Second, the significant momentum effect observed in the medium run in the non diversified sample continues to occur in the long run. The non -significant momentum effect recorded, in the medium run, in the diversified sample becomes significant in the long run. Third the momentum effect is more obvious for the non diversified sample. Finally, the returns of the trading strategies increase dramatically with the holding period in the long run. TABLE 6 RETURNS OF THE LONG TERM TRADING STRATEGIES IMPLEMENTED FOR THE DIFFERENT TIME PERIODS 15 18 21 24 01/199403/2000 04/200004/2004 1/199404/2004 NDiv 0.0107 (0.04) -0.0310 (0.000) -0.0027 (0.559) Div 0.0093 (0.007) -0.0261 (0.034) 0.5156 (0.231) NDiv 0.0183 (0.007) -0.0330 (0.000) -0.0007 (0.896) Div 0.0160 (0.000) -0.0260 (0.035) 0.3447 (0.460) NDiv 0.0365 (0.000) -0.0368 (0.001) 0.0016 (0.811) Div 0.0204 (0.000) -0.0251 (0.035) -0.0003 (0.546) NDiv 0.0521 (0.000) -0.0415 (0.002) 0.0052 (0.512) Div 0.0154 (0.001) -0.0344 (0.017) -0.0071 (0.213) This table contains average returns to long term trading strategies implemented on the non diversified firms sample and the diversified firm sample and for different time period. The trading strategies buy winners and sell losers based on their past performance relative to the 16 performance of an equal-weighted index of all stocks. The dollar profits are given by it n W r it it 1 where ri,t is the return of stock i during the holding period t and the Wi , t 1 * ri , t 1 Rt 1 N investment weight assigned to stock i at time t is given by , N is the total number of stocks in the sample, ri,t-1 is the return of stock i during the 6 month ranking period t-1, Rt-1 is the average return across all stocks in the sample at time t-1 The numbers in parentheses are significance level of realize profits of strategies. After the crash, all the returns become negative and statistically significant. First, this evidence is in favour of the profitability of contrarian strategy in the long run for the two samples. In fact, the contrarian effect identified in the medium run continues to exist in the long run. Second, the contrarian effect become significant in the 6 th month for the diversified sample and in the 9 th month for the non diversified sample. Third, the contrarian effect that was more important for the diversified sample in the medium run becomes more important for the non diversified sample in the long run. The reason is that, for the diversified sample, the return of the contrarian strategy is stabilized around 2,5% but for the non diversified sample, it grows more quickly and attains 4.1%. This implies that the diversified firms are more rapidly influenced by the crash but their prices are less affected. 5. Industrial diversification and the profitability of trading strategies: Alternative explanations 5.1 Behavioral explanation The behavioral models have attempted to provide a framework for integrating predictability in stock returns. In this subsection, following Lee and Swaminathan (2000), we briefly summarize our results (Table 7) and discuss their relation to the behavioral models. TABLE 7 RESULTS’ SUMMARY: IMPACT OF THE INDUSTRIAL DIVERSIFICATION ON THE PROFITABILITY TRADING STRATEGIES Horizon 01/1994-03/2000 04/2000-04/2004 01/1994-04/2004 Medium run Momentum Effect Contrarian Effect Contrarian Effect Long run Momentum Effect Contrarian Effect Contrarian Effect non significant Medium run Momentum Effect Contrarian Effect ( 9th month) Momentum Effect non- significant Sample Non -Diversified sub-sample 17 Long run Momentum Effect more pronounced Contrarian Effect more pronounced Medium run Momentum Effect non significant Contrarian Effect ( 6th month) Contrarian Effect Long run Momentum Effect less pronounced Contrarian Effect less pronounced Contrarian Effect non significant Diversified subsample none First, we have noted that the trading strategies implemented on the non diversified sample do not earn significant returns and they earn negative returns when implemented on the diversified sample in the medium run. In the long run, however, all the trading strategies do not generate significant returns for the two samples. These outcomes seem to be driven by the important variability of the return before and after the March 2000 crash. So, we split our sample period at this date. We have found that, before the crash, the significant momentum effect observed in the medium run in the non diversified sample continues to exist in the long run. The non significant momentum effect recorded, in the medium run, in the diversified sample becomes significant in the long run. Nevertheless, the momentum effect is more pronounced for the non diversified sample. After the crash, only a contrarian effect is identified for both samples in both the medium and long run but it is more important for the non diversified sample. Daniel et al. (1998) argue that stocks that are more difficult to value tend to generate greater overconfidence among investors. Therefore mispricing should be more severe among securities that are hard to value. If diversified firms tend to be difficult to value, then Daniel et al. (1998) would predict that return’s anomalies should be stronger among these firms. This is inconsistent with our finding that both before and after the crash mispricing is more pronounced among non diversified firms. The Hong and Stein (1999) model predicts that momentum profits should be larger for stocks with slower information diffusion 2. If the following diversified firms require more resources and skills, these firms suffer from insufficient spread of information. If this is the case, the Hong and Stein model predict greater mispricing among these firms. Likewise, owing to less public information available about these stocks, one might expect relatively more private information to be produced. The Daniel et al. (1998) model suggests that mispricing is more severe among these stocks. Our results revealed this to be true among non diversified samples. Thus, our results fit with the hypothesis implying that corporate diversification is associated with a reduction in asymmetric information. Investor’s previsions about diversified firms seem to be less biased. A plausible explanation is that the errors that outsiders make in the forecasting segment cash flows are not 18 perfectly positively- correlated so that the consolidated forecast is more accurate for a diversified than the forecast for a focused firm. Therefore, the price of the diversified firms diverge less from their fundamental value. Nevertheless, the behavioral models predict a medium- horizon momentum -effect that reverse in the long horizon. Like Jegadeesh and Titman (2001), we found no evidence of reversals of the momentum effect in the 1990s (prior to the crash). After the crash, we identify only a contrarian effect and we find no evidence of momentum. This result corroborates recent works implying that the momentum strategies are not profitable. Shiller (2000), Campbell (2004) report that in the last twenty years simple momentum strategies have performed well on average, but in the period 2000-2003, these strategies performed relatively poorly. This may be accounted for by the widespread use of this strategy. 5.2 The Risk hypothesis The momentum (contrarian) profits may be brought about by a cross-sectional dispersion in the expected stock returns rather than to their time series patterns. According to Conrad and Kaul(1998), purchasing past winners may imply a long position on high-risk stocks that earn higher expected returns. Inversely, selling past losers entails a short position on low-risk stocks that earn lower expected returns. Since the standard models like CAPM or the threefactor model fail to account for the cross-section of expected returns, the bootstrap simulation with replacement was proposed by Conrad and Kaul (1998). This technique allows to eliminate any time series’ properties in each security’s returns while maintaining the cross-sectional distribution of its mean returns; However, Jegadeesh and Titman (2002) show that the bootstrap with replacement introduce a small sample bias and they recommend the use of the bootstrap simulation without replacement. This bootstrap experiment consists in re-sampling without replacement, for each stock’s actual monthly returns: We generate 500 random samples by drawing without replacement the monthly returns. On each random sample, called bootstrapped sample, we implement the WRSS strategy. Table 8 contains the average actual and average simulated profits of the 6-month ranking period strategies implemented on the diversified and the non -diversified samples. The holding periods range from six to 24 months. Panel A presents results for the 01/94-03/2000 time period and panel B presents results for the 01/94-04/2004. The first column (1) of each panel displays the average actual profit. The second column of each panel, presents the average simulated profits The simulated profit is an average of the 500 simulated returns yielded from the bootstrap without replacement with 500 replications. The third column presents percentage of simulated profit in actual profit. 19 TABLE 8 AVERAGE PROFIT OF THE ACTUAL AND SIMULATED TRADING STRATEGIES IMPLEMENTED ON DIVERSIFIED AND NON DIVERSIFIED FIRMS SAMPLES Pannel A 01/94-03/2000 (1) Actual profit 6 (2) Simulated profit (3) Percentage 0.0024 -0.0008 -33.33 62.50 -0.0085* -0.0009 10.59 0.0059 74.68 0.0001 -0.0011 -100.00 0.0042 0.0015 35.71 -0.0144** -0.0016 11.11 0.0111** 0.0077 69.37 -0.0023 -0.0020 86.96 -0.0092 0.0019 -20.65 -0.0138* -0.0021 15.22 NDiv 0.0183*** 0.0111 60.66 -0.0007 -0.0020 285.71 Div 0.0160*** 0.0043 26.88 0.3447 -0.0032 -0.93 NDiv 0.0521*** 0.0135 25.91 0.0052 -0.0029 -55.77 Div 0.0154*** 0.0069 44.81 -0.0070 -0.0043 61.43 NDiv Div 9 NDiv Div 12 NDiv Div 18 24 (2) Simulated profit (3) Percentage 0.0060*** 0.0040 66.67 0.0008 0.0005 0.0079** Pannel B 01/94-04/2004 (1) Actual profit This table contains average actual and average simulated profits to 6-month ranking period strategies implemented on the diversified sample and the non diversified sample. The holding periods range from 6 to 24 months. Pannel A presents results for the 01/94-03/2000 time period and the pannel B presents results for the 01/94-04/2004. The column (1) of each panel display average actual profit. The column, (2) of each panel, presents average simulated profits. The simulated profit is an average of the 500 simulated returns obtained from the bootstrap without replacement with 500 replications. The column (3) presents percentage of simulated profit in actual profit (percentage) *Significant at 10% level **Significant at 5% ***Significant at 1% Before the crash, the simulated profit of the non -diversified sample increases from 0.4% for the 6-month holding period strategy to 1.35% for the 24-month holding period strategy. However, the simulated profit of the diversified sample rises from 0.05% for the 6-month holding strategy to 0.69% for the 24-month holding strategy. This implies that the average simulated return goes up with the holding period but less than geometrically for the two samples. Second, the simulated returns of the diversified firms’ sample are lower than those of the non-diversified sample. The percentage of the simulated profit in actual profit is less than 100% for all the strategies and it doesn’t exceed 75% for the non diversified firm sample and 63% for the diversified firm sample. Therefore, the crosssectional difference in expected returns does not, utterly, explain trad the ing strategies’ profits. By expanding the time period to 2004, the results indicate that only for the diversified sample, a contrarian strategy generates significant profits. The simulated profit of this strategy does not exceed 15.5%3. 6. Conclusion 3 Here we ignore non significant actual profit 20 Prior studies affirm that industrial diversification has an impact on the level of information asymmetry. The behavioral models also suggest that momentum anomaly is affected by information asymmetry. Thus, the purpose of this paper is to analyze the impact of industrial diversification on the profitability of contrarian and momentum strategies. Using Monthly returns, the WRSS strategy is applied to 249 American listed stocks from January1,994 to April ,2004. Unlike the previous studies, which used older data, our findings reveal that the momentum strategy seems to stop being profitable. In order to study the impact of the 2000 crash on our results, we implemented the WRSS strategy during the [01/1994-03/2000] and the [04/2000-04/2004] sub-periods. Our results indicate that while momentum strategies earn large positive and significant returns during the first sub-period, these returns are negative during the second sub- period. As Hong and Stein (2003) report, the 2000 market crash is qualified by negative returns. The stocks are divided into two groups according to the intensity of their industrial diversification using Ward (1963) method of hierarchical classification. Our results entail that the trading strategies implemented on the non -diversified sample do not earn significant returns but earn negative returns when implemented on the diversified sample in the medium run. In the long run, however, all the trading strategies do not generate significant returns for the two samples. These results seem to be driven by the great variability of return before and after the of March 2000 crash. In fact, we find that, before the crash, the significant momentum effect observed in the medium run in the non diversified sample continues to occur in the long run. The non -significant momentum effect recorded, in medium run, in the diversified sample becomes significant in the long run. Nevertheless, the momentum effect is more pronounced for the non diversified sample. After the crash, only a contrarian effect is identified for both samples in medium and long run but it is more important for the non diversified sample. We then try to explain these results with the predictions of several behavioral models. Like Lee and Swaminathan (2000), we conclude that each model has specific features that help explain some aspects of our findings but that no single model accommodates all our findings. Then, the Bootstrap without replacement is used to explore the risk- based explanation of the profitability of the trading strategies. We find that the cross-sectional differences in expected returns do not, entirely, account for the trading strategies’ profits. BIBLIOGRAPHY Barberis N, Shleifer A. and Vishny R. A model of investor sentiment. Journal of Financial Economics1998; 49; 307–343. 21 Boudoukh J, Richardson M. and Whitelaw R. “Industry returns and the Fisher effect”, Journal of Finance 1994; 49; 1595-1616. Campbell, J. Y. “Understanding Momentum,” Arrowstreet Capital; 2004. Clarke J E , Fee C. E. and Thomas S. Corporate diversification and asymmetric information: evidence from stock market trading characteristics. Journal of Corporate Finance 2004; 10; 105-129 Conrad J, Kaul G. An Anatomy of Trading Strategies. Review of Financial Studies 1998; 11; 489-519. Daniel K, Hirshleifer D. and Subrahmanyam A. Investor Psychology and Security Market Under-and Overreactions. Journal of Finance 1998; 53; 1839-1886 Daniel K and Titman S. Market Efficiency in an Irrational World. Financial Analyst Journal 1999; 55; 28-40. DeBondt W, Thaler R. H. Does the stock market overreact?”, Journal of Finance, 40 (1985), 793-805. Denis, D. J.; Denis, D. K.; and Sarin, A. 1997. “Agency problems, equity ownership, and corporate diversification”. Journal of Finance 52 (March): 135-60. Dodd, P. Merger proposals, management discretion and stockholder wealth. Journal of Financial Economics 1980; 8 105-137. Dunn K , Nathan S. The Effect of Industry Diversification on Consensus and Individual Analysts' Earnings Forecasts. SSRN Working Paper 1998. Fama, E. Market Effciency, Long-Term Returns, and Behavioral Finance. Journal of Financial Economics 1998; 49 283–306. Givoly D, Hayn C, D'Souza J. Measurement Errors and the Information Content of Segment Reporting. Review of Accounting Studies 1999; 29 ; 15-43 Habib M A, Johnsen B and Naik N. Spinoffs and information. Journal of Financial Intermediation 1997; 6 ;153-176 Hadlock, C, Ryngaert M and Thomas S. Corporate structure and equity offerings: are there benefits to diversification. Journal of Business 1999; 74 ; 613-35 Hong H, Stein J. A Unified Theory of Underreaction, Momentum Trading and Overreaction in Asset Markets. Journal of Finance 1999; 54 ; 2143-2184. Hong H, Stein J. Differences of Opinion, Short-Sales Constraints and Market Crashes. Review of Financial Studies 2003; 16; 487-525. Hong H, Chen J, and Stein J. Forecasting Crashes: Trading Volume, Past Returns and Conditional Skewness in Stock Prices. Journal of Financial Economics 2001; 61; 345-381. Jacquemin A P , Berry C H. Entropy measure of diversification and corporate growth. The Journal of Industrial Economics 1979; 27; 359-369. Jegadeesh N, and Titman S. Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency. Journal of Finance 1993; 48; 65–91. Jegadeesh N, and Titman S. Profitability of momentum strategies: An evaluation of alternative explanations. The Journal of Finance 2001a; 56 ; 699–720. Jegadeesh N, Titman S. Momentum. University Of Illinois. Working Paper 2001b. Jegadeesh N, and Titman S. Cross-Sectional and Time-Series Determinants of Momentum Returns. Review of Financial Studies 2002; 15; 143-157 22 Jensen M.C. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeover. American Economic review 1986; 76; 323-329. Lee C and Swaminathan B. Price Momentum and Trading Volume. Journal of Finance 2000; 55 ;1217-1269 Lewellen J. Momentum and autocorrelation in stock returns. The Review of Financial Studies 2002; 15; 533–563. Lo A, and MacKinlay A C. When are Contrarian Profits Due to Stock Market Overreaction?. Review of Financial Studies1990; 3 ; 175-208. Malkiel B .The Efficient Market Hypothesis and Its Critics. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2003; 17; 59 – 82 Mengoli S. On the source of contrarian and momentum strategies in the Italian equity market. International Review of Financial Analysis 2004; 13 ; 301– 331 Nanda V and Narayanan M P. Disentangling Value: Financing Needs, Firm Scope, and Divestitures. Journal of Financial Intermediation 1999; 8 ; 174-204 Palepu K. Diversification strategy, profit performance and entropy measure. Strategic management journal 1985; 6 239-255. Patro D K and Wu Y. Predictability of short-horizon returns in international equity markets. Journal of Empirical Finance 2004; 11 ; 553-584 Rajan, R, Servaes H , Zingales L. The cost of diversity: The diversification discount and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance 2000; 55; 35-80. Richards A J. Winner-Loser Reversals in National Stock Market Indices: Can They Be Explained?. Journal of Finance1997; 52 ; 2129-2144 Rouwenhorst K G. International momentum strategies. Journal of Finance1998; 53 ; 267–284 Schwert, G. W. Anomalies And Market Efficiency, 1st ed , Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Shiller Robert J. Irrational Exuberance. Princeton University Press; 2000. Stulz R M. Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies . Journal of Financial Economics 1990; 26; 3-27 Thomas S. Firm Diversification and Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Analysts’ Forecasts and Earnings Announcements. Journal of Financial Economics 2002 ; 46 ; 373-396. Ward J H. Hierarchical grouping to optimize an objective function. Journal of the American Statistical Association 1963; 58 ; 236–244. Zuckerman E. Focusing the corporate product: Securities analysts and de-diversification. Administrative Science Quarterly 2000; 45 ; 591-619 23 24