Algebraic manipulation of CES functions. The standard form of a CES production function is: 1/ Y A. i X i i -(1) Where Y is output, Xi is input of factor I and is a substitution parameter. A is a scale parameter and i is a share parameter for input I. Factor inputs: Cost minimisation implies dY/dXi = wi/P, ie real product wage equals marginal product of input i. Differentiating (1) wrt Xi we obtain: Y / Xi A i Y / X i 1 wi / P -(2) Doing the same for input j and using wi/wj = (wi/P)/(wj/P), we obtain: Wi / W j ( i / j ).X j / X i 1 -(3) Which can be rearranged as: X i / X j ( i / j )1 / 1 .W j / Wi 1 / 1 -(4) The elasticity of substitution, 1, between Xi and Xj is dln(Xi/Xj)/dln(Wj/Wi) It follows from (4) that: 1/1 (5a) Or alternatively that: ( 1) / (5b) 1 This is defining the elasticity of substitution so it is normally positive It follows that when = 1, = 0 and the CES function becomes indeterminate. CES Cost Function (Price Index). Taking equation (2) and rearranging: X i / Y P1 / 1 . A / 1 .i / wi 1 / 1 -(6) Since CES functions have constant returns to scale, price will equal average cost (zero profit condition). This means: P Wi X i / Y i -(7) Substituting for Xi/Y from equation (6), we obtain: P Wi ( X i / Y ) A / 1 .P1 / 1 . i i 1 / 1 .wi / 1 i -(8a) Rearranging to get P onto the RHS: 1 / 1 / 1 P 1/ A. i .wi i ( 1) / -(8b) An increase in all wi will lead to an equiproportionate increase in P. Calibration. Starting from rearranging equation 2, we can write: i A .Si . X i / Y -(9) where Si is the expenditure share of Xi: Si=wiXi/PY If we assume the beta ‘share’ parameters sum to 1, we can estimate A: 1/ A Si .(Y / X i ) i -(10) We can also substitute for A and for Si, to allow us to write i wi X i1 / w j X j1 j -(10a) Own Price Elasticities. Assuming Y is a fixed amount, the elasticity of demand for input I is calculated from equation 2. This can be rearranged as follows: 1 / 1 X i Y . A / 1 .i 1 / 1 .P1 / 1 .Wi -(11) Differentiating wrt Wi yields the result: X i / dWi Y . A / 1 .i1 / 1 .P1 / 1 .wi1 / 1 (1/1 ).P / dwi .(1/ P) (1/ wi ) -(12) and substituting from (2) we get: X i / dWi X i .(1 / 1 ).P / dwi .(1 / P) (1 / wi ) -(13) For dP/dWi, we can use Roy’s identity: If C=P.Y and is the cost of producing a fixed amount of Y, then C / Wi X i And hence P / dWi X i / Y -(14) Substituting into (13) yields the following: X i / dWi X i .(1 / 1 ).X i / PY (1 / wi ) ( X i / Wi ).(1 / 1 )1 Si -(15) Where Si denotes the expenditure share of input I in total inputs. The own-price elasticity of demand for input I if Y is fixed is therefore: i (X i / Wi ).(Wi / X i ) (1/1 ).1 Si 1 Si -(16) It follows that when the input has a small share in total input costs, its own-price elasticity tends towards the elasticity of substitution -, while if its share is close to 1 its own-price demand elasticity is small. These results are, of course, changed if output of Y is sensitive to input costs. In that case, if the own-price elasticity of demand for Y is , then we can write: i ln X i / ln Wi ln( X i / Y ) / ln Wi ln( Y ) / ln Wi -(17) But the first term is the same as i when Y is fixed, ie: i (1 Si ) ln( Y ) / ln Wi -(17a) While the second term can be rewritten: ln Y / ln Wi Y / Wi .(Wi / Y ) .( X / Y ).(Wi / Y ) -(18) Where is the own-price elasticity of demand for good Y. It follows that: i (1 Si i ) Si Si ( ) -(19) Hence the effect of whether increasing input I’s share in good Y increases or decreases its own-price elasticity of demand depends on whether the elasticity of substitution in industry Y, , exceeds the own-price elasticity of demand for good Y, . This has implications for the effects of degree of monopoly on pricing when the inputs are imperfectly-substituting products of rival firms (the Dixit-Stiglitz framework). Huw Edwards 22 March 01