Some Notes on Limit Pricing The theory of limit pricing suggests that an incumbent firm may be able to make it unprofitable for a potential entrant to enter the industry. The argument is that the incumbent firm can produce a certain output before entry, and threaten to continue producing that output even if entry occurs. If the potential entrant believes the claim, he will decide it is unprofitable to enter. Later economists were critical of “limit pricing” theory, except when the incumbent firm can impose restrictions on itself to make its threat credible. The example below explores limit pricing theory. (You will have to look at the textbook (page 361) for the graph of this model). Assume market demand is P = 100 – Q. There is one incumbent firm in the industry (a monopoly), and its output is designated by qi. There is a potential entrant to this industry and its output is designated by the symbol qe. Both firms have the same costs of production: TC = 400 + 10q, and therefore AC = (400/q) + 10. The incumbent firm knows that there is a potential entrant, and believes that the potential entrant believes that the incumbent will not change its output even if the potential entrant decides to enter. The incumbent firm therefore wants to choose qi so that entry will be unprofitable. In fact, the incumbent knows that the potential entrant will not enter unless it earns a positive profit (∏e > 0), so the incumbent will choose qi to make the entrant’s profit equal to zero. This will happen if the residual demand curve of the potential entrant just touches (is tangent to) its AC curve but does not rise above it anywhere. To find the tangency point, take dAC/dq = -400q-2 and set this equal to the slope of the residual demand curve dP/dq = -1. Therefore, -400q-2 = -1 or q = 20. When q = 20, AC = (400/20) + 10 = $30. This means that the residual demand curve must pass through the point q =20, P = $30 and have a slope of –1. The general equation for this residual demand curve will be P = X - qe (where X is the vertical intercept), and at the point of tangency, this equation will satisfy 30 = X – 20. Therefore, X = 50, and the residual demand curve which just touches the AC curve will have the equation, P = 50 – qe. The market demand curve is P = 100 – Q or P = 100 - qi – qe. To leave the appropriate residual demand curve, qi must = 50. This is the entry-deterring output for the incumbent firm. Given the beliefs of the potential entrant, it will calculate its best output this way: P = 50 – qe, therefore MRe = 50 – 2qe. Setting this equal to MC, we have 50 – 2qe = 10, or qe = 20. Therefore Pe = 50 – 20 = $30. At this price and quantity, profit for the entrant is: ∏e = (30 x 20) – [400 + (10 x 20)] = $0. Given this calculation, the potential entrant would decide not to enter (i.e., the limit pricing scheme works). The price of $30 is called the “limit price” because the incumbent firm, by threatening to produce 50 units of output after entry occurs, is threatening to drive the price down to $30 after entry (a price which will limit the possibility of entry). What would the price and profits be before entry occurred? Before entry, the incumbent has to produce 50 units of output. To make 50 units of output clear the market, the price must be P = 100 – 50 = $50. Therefore, the profit earned before entry would be ∏i = (50 x 50) – (400 + [10 x 50]) = $1,600. Is this the monopoly price and profit for the incumbent firm? No, it’s not. The incumbent firm did not choose the output and price to maximize profits, but to deter entry by the potential entrant. The monopoly output would be: P = 100 – q; MR = 100 – 2q = MC = 10, so qi = 45 and P = $55. Monopoly profit would be ∏i = (55 x 45) – (400 + [10 x 45]) = $1,625. Would the incumbent firm make a profit if it produced 50 units of output after the potential entrant entered the industry? The price would be $30 and output 50 units, so ∏i = (30 x 50) – (400 + [10 x 50]) = $600. The answer is yes…a reduced profit compared to before entry, but the incumbent firm would profit while the entrant earned zero. What’s wrong with the model? The logic of the model is perfect, as long as you accept the assumption that the potential entrant will believe that the incumbent will keep its output constant after entry. But this assumption seems pretty shaky. Why would a potential entrant believe this? For instance, let’s imagine that the potential entrant entered the market and decided to produce 45 units of output. Would the incumbent keep producing 50 units of output? Total output in the industry would be 95 units so price would be P = 100 – 95 = $5. At this price, the new entrant would be earning: ∏e = (5 x 45) – (400 + [10 x 45]) = -$625 (a loss), but the incumbent would be doing even worse: ∏i = (5 x 50) – (400 + [10 x 50]) = -$650 (a bigger loss). Under these conditions, it’s unlikely the incumbent would keep producing 50 units of output. If the two firms settled down into a Cournot duopoly result, the incumbent would be much better off. As you can calculate on your own, the Cournot result would be that each firm produces 30 units of output and the price is $40. Therefore, profit of each firm would be: ∏ = (40 x 30) – (400 + [10 x 30]) = $500. How could the incumbent firm make a credible threat? The incumbent firm would have to be able to make a credible threat to produce 50 units of output if entry occurred. It could do this by precommitting to produce 50 units of output. This would require adoption of an inflexible production technology that only permitted this level of production (and not any other level of output). Restricting its own options means that the potential entrant can expect a protracted period of low prices and negative profits (losses) if entry occurs. This makes entry of the potential entrant very unlikely. In an extensive form game, you might look at the options and the payoffs this way: Enter ($600, $0) Inflexible Technology Potential Entrant (#2) Don’t Enter Incumbent Firm (#1) Enter Flexible Technology ($1,600, $0) ($500, $500) Potential Entrant (#2) Don’t Enter ($1,625, $0) The bottom result is the monopoly result (flexible technology, no entry). However, if entry does occur and technology is flexible, we conclude that the entrant would be able to force the incumbent to change its output and that the Cournot result would occur ($500, $500). The adoption of inflexible technology requires investment in changes to plant and equipment, so that could change the costs of the incumbent. In these calculations, we assume the firm was able to sell its old equipment and get this new plant and equipment for the same price, so its costs do not change. If the potential entrant enters, it can no longer get the incumbent to change its output by threatening to produce 45 units of output, so the best the entrant could do would be to produce 20 units and earn a profit of zero (which we assume is not enough to encourage entry). If the potential entrant doesn’t enter, the incumbent does not earn the monopoly profit, because the inflexible technology does not allow him to produce the monopoly output, so the profit is $1,600. Our analysis of this game tells us that the potential entrant will not enter if the incumbent adopts the inflexible technology, but will enter if there is a flexible technology (because the threat to produce 50 units of output is not credible). Therefore, the best strategy for the incumbent firm is to adopt the inflexible technology to deter entry.