1 C7PARDER.DOC The partial derivative of a function of two or more variables is the ordinary derivative of the function with respect to only one of the variables (or “partials”), considering the others as constants. Let z = f(x, y). Holding y constant, we take the derivative with respect to x, the partial derivative may be denoted in several ways. dz dx y f fx x, y f1 x, y fx f1 x Here the subscript 1 denotes the 1st argument of the function, 2 the second, etc. Example 1 Let the budget line be M = px + qy. Then, M M p and q. x y That is, when the consumer purchases one extra unit of x, expenditure must increase by the amount of its price. Example 2 Let the utility function be U Ux, y 3x 2 1/ 2 2y 3 1 /3 Then the marginal utility of x and y are 1 1/ 2 1/3 U 1 x, y MU x 3x 2 32y 3 2 3 1 / 2 3x 2 2y 3 1/3 2 U 2 x, y MU y 3x 2 1/ 2 1 2y 3 3 2/3 2 2 1/ 2 2/3 3x 2 2y 3 3 At x = 1 and y = 3 we may calculate the marginal utility as 3 1/ 2 1 /3 U 1 1,3 31 ( ) 2 ( ) 3 23 2 2 1/ 2 2/3 U 2 1,3 31 ( ) 2 23 ( ) 3 3 Here the units of utility are given as “utils”. Example 3 Let the production function be given as a function of labor L and capital K. 2 C7PARDER.DOC Q FK, L 25KL K 2 3L2 Then the marginal productivities of capital and labor are Q MPL 25K 6L L Q MPK 25L 2K K Illustration of Q = F(L, K). Figure 1 shows the marginal productivity of labor (FL) as the slope of the curve. The curve is called the labor productivity curve. The position of this curve depends on the amount of capital associated with labor. In general, the more capital associated with labor, the more productive the labor becomes. In this case the MPL at L0 becomes steeper as K increases. But in other cases this may not be so. Y Y F L, K Y F L, K Y F L, K FL 0 L0 L Figure 1 The Productivity Curve of Labor Applications of Partial Derivatives Definition: The problem of Comparative Statics Analysis is to find the effects of the change in a parameter on the equilibrium value, quantitatively and qualitatively. 3 C7PARDER.DOC The problem can be solved by finding the partial derivatives of an equilibrium variable with respect to each parameter. Two questions may be answered from these partial derivatives. (i) Qualitative changes (direction of changes) Increase, decrease, or no changes (ii) Quantitative changes (magnitude of changes) value of partial derivatives. Examples. 1. A Market Model In chapter 3 we have seen that a market model is given as D = a - bp S = -c + dp D=S where a, b, c, and d are positive parameters. From Chapter 3 on static analysis, we know that the equilibrium values are p* = (a + c)/(b + d) Q* = (ad - bc)/(b + d) (1) (2) The comparative static analysis asks what are the effects of changes in parameters a, b, c, d on the equilibrium values p* and Q*? (a) the effects on p* are given by p*/a, p*/b, p*/c, p*/d, (b) the effects on Q* are given by Q*/a, Q*/b, Q*/c, Q*/d, There are two equilibrium values and four parameters. Here there are a total of 2x4=8 partial derivatives. These partial derivatives are called the comparative static derivatives (CSD). The CSD are derived as follows 1. p a 1 0 b d 4 C7PARDER.DOC which shows that an increase in a (the intercept of the demand function) will increase the equilibrium price p, and its magnitude depends only on b and d, the slopes of the supply and demand curves 2. Q a d 0 b d which shows that if a increases, the equilibrium quantity also increases. The magnitude of the change depends on b and d D,S D,S a’ a a S D D S E’ + E Q* - E Q * b d p* E’ d P + -c b p * b’ P + -c Figure 2 3. Figure 3 a c p 0 b b d2 which shows that if b (the slope of the demand function, which shows the increase in demand when price increases by $1) increases, the equilibrium price will decrease. 4. c b d ad bc d a c 1 Q 0 2 b b d b d2 which shows that if b increases, the equilibrium quantity decreases. The magnitude of the change depends on a, b, c, and d. These two CSD are shown in figures 2 and 3. 5 C7PARDER.DOC In figure 2 the original equilibrium point is at E. When a increases, that is, the demand curve shifts upward, holding b, c, and d constant the equilibrium price and quantity increase. D,S a D,S S D a S D E’ + E - Q* Q * E E’ b d p* b d’ d P p + -c * - P -c -c’ Figure 5 Figure 4 On the other hand, when b increases, holding other parameters constant, then the demand curve shifts downward, holding the intercept a constant. In this case figure 3 shows clearly that, when E changes to E’, both equilibrium price and quantity decrease. These results conform with the results obtained from the CSD. Similarly we may show that p 1 0 c b d Q c a c p 0 d b d2 ba c Q 0 d b d2 b 0 b d The results are illustrated in figures 4 and 5. Note that in each case only one parameter changes while the others are held constant. 2. A National Income Model From chapter 3, a national income model may be given as Y = C + I0 + G0 a > 0, 0 < b < 1 6 C7PARDER.DOC C = a + b(Y - T) c > 0, 0 < t < 1 T = c + tY There are three equations in three endogenous variables (Y, C, T). The exogenous variables are I0 and G0, and the parameters are a, b, c, and t, a total of 6 constants. The equilibrium values of the model are Y C T a bc I 0 G0 1 b bt a bc b 1 t I 0 G0 1 b bt c 1 b t a I 0 G0 1 b bt Take the derivatives with respect to the parameters in Y*, C*, T*, each with a, b, c, t, I0 and G0, we have a total of 3x6 = 18 comparative statics derivatives. Interpretation of the comparative statics derivatives: For some CSD there are some familiar names Y = Investment multiplier I0 Y = Government multiplier G0 Y = MPC multiplier b Y = Income tax multiplier t Example What are the effects of changes in the subsistence level of consumption a, on equilibrium national income, equilibrium consumption, and equilibrium tax revenue? To answer this question we need only take the partial derivatives of Y*, C*, and T* with respect to a. They are Y C =k 0 a a T = tk 0 a 7 C7PARDER.DOC where we denote k = 1/(1-b+bt) = 1/(1-b(1-t)), which is the multiplier with the tax rate. Thus when the subsistence level of consumption increases, all equilibrium values increase. The magnitudes of the increases depend on the multiplier k. 3. Input-output models a11 a12 d1 A , d a21 a22 d2 where d1 and d2 are non-negative numbers. The fundamental equation of the Input-Output model is (I - A)x = d Using the inverse matrix method, we have x = (I - A)-1d or, a12 d1 x1 1 a22 1 x a 1 a11 d2 I A 21 2 Hence, x1 x2 1 a22 d1 a12d2 I A a12d2 1 a11 d2 I A Taking d1 = 1 and d2 = 0, we see that the first column of the inverse matrix shows the total requirement of equilibrium output x1* when d1 changes one unit and holding d2 constant. Y,C Y T Y=C+I0+G0 T C C=a+bY slope = t a’ c a 45 AS Figure 6 Y Y 8 C7PARDER.DOC Similarly, taking d1 = 0 and d2 = 1, we see that the second column of the inverse matrix shows the total requirement of equilibrium output x2* when d2 changes one unit and holding d1 constant. The effects of changes in d1 on x1* and x2* may be derived separately by using the comparative statics derivatives. x1 1 a22 , d1 I A x1 a12 d2 I A x2 a21 , d1 I A x2 1 a11 . d2 I A Thus the above derivatives show how much equilibrium gross output must change, when the final demand for commodity 1 changes by one unit, in order to maintain the equilibrium condition in the economy.