ESTIMATING THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM USING DATA FROM MULTIPLE MARKETS Martin Lally* School of Economics and Finance Victoria University of Wellington John Randal** School of Economics and Finance Victoria University of Wellington Abstract This paper has developed an estimator for a country’s market risk premium that involves optimally combining an estimator based upon only local data and the cross-country average of these estimators. The analysis suggests that the usual practice of invoking only local data to estimate a country’s market risk premium is significantly inferior to the use of a cross-country average or a combined estimator with high weighting on the crosscountry average. 1. Introduction The market risk premium for an individual market is a critical parameter in portfolio analysis of the Markowitz type (Markowitz, 1952, 1959) and the widely used standard version of the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM: Sharpe, 1964; Lintner, 1965; Mossin, 1966). In turn, the CAPM is used to estimate the cost of equity capital, which in turn is used for equity valuations of the Discounted Cash Flow type and in setting allowed output prices for firms subject to price control. In estimating the market risk premium for a particular market, a widely used and long-standing method involves a simple average over annual ex-post outcomes (market returns net of the risk free rate) for a long period. Following Ibbotson and Sinquefield’s (1976) estimate for the US, such estimates have been generated for a wide range of markets and a range of alternative periods (Siegel, 1992; Dimson and Marsh, 1982; Officer, 1989; Chay et al, 1993). More recently, Dimson et al (2002) have presented estimates for 17 markets over the common period from 1900-2000, and have subsequently updated these results and expanded the coverage to 19 markets (Dimson et al, 2011). In addition, a wide range of alternative estimation techniques have been proposed and estimates presented for various markets (Merton, 1980; Siegel, 1992; Scruggs, 1998; Cornell, 1999; Pastor and Stambaugh, 2001; Claus and Thomas, 2001; Jagannathan et al, 2001; Fama and French, 2002; Mayfield, 2004; Maheu and McCurdy, 2009; Donaldson et al, 2010). For any given methodology, some of the variation in the estimates across markets will be estimation error and these estimation errors across markets are less than perfectly 2 correlated, which points to using the cross-country average. Furthermore, in respect of the historical averaging method, this approach has been proposed by Dimson et al (2003, pp. 13-14). However, true market risk premiums are likely to differ across markets and this argues for using local data for each market. Taking account of both points suggests that one should form a weighted average of the estimator based upon only local data and the cross-country average of these estimators. At the firm level, such an approach has been adopted for estimating betas (Vasicek, 1973), variances (Karolyi, 1993), and expected returns (Jorion, 1986; Grauer and Hakansson, 1995). More generally, the use of combined estimators of this type is well established in the statistical literature (James and Stein, 1961; Efron and Morris, 1975; Efron, 2010). In light of all this, the present paper has three goals. The first is to develop an estimator of the market risk premium for an individual market that optimally combines the estimate based upon data for only that market and the cross-country average, i.e., to determine the optimal weight on local data; we call this the “combined estimator”. The second goal is to empirically assess the statistical advantage from using the combined estimator over each of its two components. The third goal is to estimate the confidence interval surrounding the point estimate for the optimal weight on local data. 2. Theory The relative merits of using a cross-country average rather than exclusively local data depend upon the extent of cross-country variation in true market risk premiums. Such 3 variation can exist if markets are completely segmented and if markets are completely integrated, although the causes will differ. If markets were completely segmented and (consistent with this) the standard version of the CAPM (Sharpe, 1964; Lintner, 1965; Mossin, 1966) applied, then the market risk premium for market j would be the product of the variance for market j and the coefficient of relative risk aversion for the representative investor in market j (Guo and Whitelaw, 2006). Both of these underlying parameters can vary across markets and estimates of market variances suggest that there is significant variation across markets (Cavaglia et al, 2000, Table 1). Thus, if markets were completely segmented, market risk premiums could differ significantly across markets. On the other hand, if markets were completely integrated and (consistent with this) the Solnik (1974) version of the CAPM applied, then the market risk premium for market j would be the product of the world market risk premium and the beta of market j against the world market. The latter coefficient can vary across markets and estimates of such betas suggest that there may be significant variation across countries (Harvey, 2000, Exhibits 1A and 1B). Thus, if markets were completely integrated, market risk premiums could differ significantly across markets. So, regardless of the extent to which markets are segmented, true market risk premiums could differ significantly across markets. This would tend to undercut the value from a cross-country average of estimates of the market risk premium. However, due to estimation error, some combination of a cross-country average and the estimate using only data from the country of interest might still be superior to the latter. We now seek to determine the optimal combination. 4 Define as the mean of the population from which the true market risk premiums for a set of countries are drawn, j as the true market risk premium for country j, ˆ j as the estimate for j using only local data, and ˆ as the cross-country average of the ˆ j . We express j as j j , where j is a random and independent drawing from the cross-sectional distribution of countries’ true market risk premiums (with mean zero and variance denoted 2 ). Letting ej denote the estimation error for country j, being the estimate using only local data less the true value, it follows that the estimated market risk premium for country j using only local data is as follows.1 ˆ j j e j j e j We now consider one of these (randomly selected) countries (designated as country 1). Defining k as the weighting applied to ˆ1 , the combined estimator for the market risk premium of country 1 is then as follows (1) 1 ˆc kˆ1 (1 k )ˆ This approach, in which the true market risk premiums are treated as random variables, follows Efron and Morris (1975). The alternative approach (James and Stein, 1961) is to treat the true market risk premiums as a set of fixed numbers, but the resulting estimators are the same. In addition the derivations of results within the statistics literature assume that the parameters in question are estimated using time-series data. By contrast, we do not make this assumption in this section, and therefore our results are more general. 5 and the estimation error associated with this estimator for 1 is as follows. ˆc 1 kˆ1 (1 k )ˆ 1 In choosing the weighting k, and consistent with the literature (Efron and Morris, 1975), we choose k to minimise the MSE of a randomly selected country (country 1) with the expectation over both estimation errors and countries. If the estimation errors ej have the same variance e2 for all markets and all distinct pairs of the random variables e1,….,eN have the same correlation coefficient denoted ρ, then the optimal country weights within the cross-country average ˆ will be equal.2 Letting N denote the number of countries used in forming the cross-country average, the MSE from the combined estimator (with the expectation over both estimation errors and countries) is then as follows.3 (2) 2 1 1 1 1 MSE 2 (1 k ) 2 1 e2 k 2 1 e2 1 k 2 1 N N N N The weights are optimal in the sense of minimising the variance of the estimator. This remains true even if there is cross-country variation in the market values of the countries’ market portfolios. However, ceteris paribus, larger markets will tend to have smaller estimates for 3 e2 and this will justify a higher weighting if differential e2 are acknowledged. Section 4 will address this issue. The proof for equation (2) appears in the Appendix. 6 To find the value for k that minimises this function, denoted k0, we set the first derivative to zero and this implies the following.4 (3) k0 2 2 e2 (1 ) The intuition for this result is apparent by consideration of extreme cases. If the variance in the cross-sectional distribution of true market risk premiums ( 2 ) is zero, then equation (3) implies that the optimal weight on local data (k0) should be zero and hence the cross-country average should be used, i.e., if all countries have the same market risk premium then the best estimator for each country’s market risk premium would be the cross-country average (because there is no disadvantage in using data from other countries whilst gaining the ‘diversification’ benefit from doing so). On the other hand, if 2 is positive but the variance in the estimation error for any country ( e2 ) is zero, then equation (3) implies that k0 = 1, i.e., if countries have different market risk premiums and there is no estimation error when using local data, then the best estimator for a country’s market risk premium would use only local data (so as to avoid the ‘bias’ from using data from other markets, which is drawn from distributions with different means to that of the local market). Finally, if 2 is positive and e2 is positive but the correlation coefficient in the estimation errors of any pair of countries ( ) is 1, then equation (3) still implies that k0 = 1, i.e., if countries have different market risk premiums and there is estimation error when using only local data but perfect correlation in such errors across 4 The second derivative is positive, and therefore the second order condition for a minimum is satisfied. 7 countries, then the best estimator for a country’s market risk premium would still involve using only local data because there is no diversification benefit from using data from other markets (due to perfect correlation) whilst the bias from using data from other markets still holds (the data from other markets are drawn from distributions with different means). Turning now to the implementation of equation (3), this requires estimates for 2 , e2 and . The first of these cannot be directly estimated, but can be deduced from the cross-sectional distribution of the locally-based estimates of the market risk premiums for the N countries. Defining V as the expectation of the cross-sectional sample variance in these locally-based estimates of the market risk premiums, it follows that5 (4) 2 V e2 (1 ) Substitution of this into equation (3) yields the following value for the optimal weight on local data: (5) k0 V e2 (1 ) V Reference to equations (3) and (4) also reveals that k0 is the ratio of 2 to V, i.e., the proportion of cross-sectional variance in the local-data based estimates of the market risk premiums that is attributable to cross-sectional variance in true market risk premiums. 5 The proof for equation (4) appears in the Appendix. 8 To estimate k0, equation (5) is invoked along with estimates for V, e2 and ρ, and estimates of the latter three parameters arise from the set of estimates for the market risk premiums of the N countries or from the underlying data. 3. An Example Before proceeding to look at empirical data, we first consider an example to illustrate the advantages of the combined estimator over that based on only local data or the crosscountry average. Suppose that there are 20 countries (N = 20) with e2 .03 2 and ρ = .30. If only local data are used (k = 1) then the MSE (equivalent to the variance) of the estimator is .03 2 . By contrast, if equal weight is placed on all markets (k = 0), then the MSE of the estimator (given by equation (2) with k = 0) differs from this. If 2 0 , in which case all markets have the same true market risk premium, the MSE of the estimator is .017 2 , and this is naturally less than from using only local data because there is no disadvantage (bias) from using data from other markets but there is a diversification benefit from using data from a set of imperfectly correlated markets. However, as 2 increases, the use of foreign data introduces growing bias and therefore the MSE of the cross-country average will eventually exceed that from using only local data because the bias effect eventually outweighs the diversification effect. Furthermore, as 2 increases, the optimal value for 9 k given by equation (3) rises. Consequently, the MSE of the combined estimator (given by equation (2) with the optimal value for k) is always below that from using only local data. In addition, apart from when 2 is zero in which case the MSEs are the same, the combined estimator always has a lower MSE than the cross-country average. All of this is shown in Figure 1. This example demonstrates the advantages of the combined estimator over that using only local data and the cross-country average. As the disadvantage from foreign data decreases, in the form of lower cross-sectional variation in true market risk premiums, the optimal weight on local data goes to zero and the MSE from the combined estimator will be significantly less than that from using only local data. Also, as the disadvantage from foreign data increases, in the form of greater cross-sectional variation in true market risk premiums, the optimal weight on local data goes to 1 and the MSE from the combined estimator will be significantly less than that from using the cross-country average. The key issue is then the extent of cross-sectional variation in true market risk premiums and the next section uses empirical data to estimate this. 4. Comparison of Estimators Section 2 has developed a formula for the MSE of the combined estimator, the optimal weight on local data, and procedures for estimating other relevant parameters. This section now seeks to estimate this optimal weight, the MSE of the resulting combined estimator, and to compare it with the MSE arising from use of the cross-country average 10 (k = 0) and from the use of only local data (k = 1). To do this, we consider methodologies for estimating the market risk premium for which estimates have been generated for a wide range of markets and the methodology readily allows for estimating both the standard deviation of the point estimate and the correlation coefficient between point estimates for different countries. At the present time, the only methodology that appears to meet both requirements is the historical averaging methodology, and the natural choice of estimates are those provided for 19 markets over the common period 1900-2010 by Dimson et al (2011).6 Table 1 reports the estimates for these markets along with their estimated standard errors.7 In respect of the expectation of the cross-sectional sample variance in the locally-based estimates of the market risk premiums (V), an unbiased estimate will arise from the cross-sectional sample variance in the estimated market risk premiums shown in the first column of Table 1, and this is .0182 2 . In respect of the variance in the estimation error using only local data ( e2 ), an unbiased estimate arises by averaging over the estimates in the last column of Table 1, and this yields .0224 2 . Finally, in respect of the correlation coefficient between the estimation errors for any pair of markets (), an unbiased estimate arises by averaging over the estimated correlations between all pairs of markets, using 111 years of data in each case, and the resulting 6 The more limited information available from other methodologies will be considered in a later section. 7 The estimates are arithmetic means on stock returns net of the yield on bills, supplied by Mike Staunton from the Dimson, Marsh and Staunton data. The figures differ slightly from those given in Dimson et al (2011, Table 9) in that the latter employ geometric rather than arithmetic differencing. 11 estimate is .355.8 Substituting these parameter estimates into equation (5) then yields an estimate for the optimal weight on local data as follows. (6) k0 .0182 2 .0224 2 (1 .355) .021 .0182 2 The numerator here is .0026 2 and a comparison of equations (4) and (5) reveals that it is an estimate of the variance of the distribution from which the true market risk premiums are drawn ( 2 ).9 Following equation (2), with these estimates for 2 and k0, the RMSE of the combined estimator is .014. The result is identical (to three decimal points) from using a cross-country average (k = 0). By comparison, and again following equation (2), the RMSE when only local data are utilised (k = 1) is .022. Thus, using the optimal value for k or a cross-country average lowers the RMSE of the estimator by almost 40%. These results and the underlying parameter estimates are summarised in Table 2. 8 For each pair of markets, the correlation in the point estimates for the market risk premium is equal to the correlation in the annual equity returns net of the risk free rate, and is estimated using the time series of these annual outcomes. The returns must be in local currency units for each of the two markets, consistent with the definition of the correlation coefficient. The correlations estimated in this way were provided by Mike Staunton using the Dimson, Marsh and Staunton data, and are shown in Table 4. 9 If the estimate of k0 were negative, and therefore the estimate of 2 would also be negative, then resetting the estimate for k0 to zero is recommended to reduce the MSE of the combined estimator (see Efron and Morris, 1975, p. 312). 12 The impact from using a combined estimator rather than an estimator based upon only local data varies across countries. As shown in Table 1, at one extreme (Italy), use of the combined estimator rather than the estimator based upon only local data lowers the point estimate by almost 300 basis points from .102 to .073. At the other extreme (Denmark), use of the combined estimator rather than the estimator based upon only local data raises the point estimate by 240 basis points from .048 to .072. On the other hand, the point estimate would not change much for many markets such as the US (.074 versus .072). However, even when the point estimate would not significantly change, the statistical reliability of the estimator is dramatically improved by use of the combined estimator or the cross-country average, i.e., a 40% reduction in the RMSE of the estimator. 5. Alternative Assumptions All of the analysis so far is premised on the assumption that the standard deviation in the estimation error ej is the same for all countries ( e ) and all distinct pairs of the random variables e1,….,eN have the same correlation coefficient (ρ). Neither of these assumptions is likely to be true, and there is also considerable variation across countries or country pairs in the estimates for both of them (as shown in Tables 1 and 3). In view of this, we now consider the implications of allowing the standard deviations in the estimation errors to vary across countries. This requires equations (2) to (5) to be modified. In addition, the country weights within the cross-country average may require adjustment. With country weights wi, the 13 Appendix shows that the MSE for a randomly selected country (country 1) from use of the combined estimator (with the expectation over both estimation errors and countries) is now as follows. (7) N 2 MSE 2 (1 k ) 2 (1 w1 ) 2 (1 k ) 2 w j e21 k (1 k ) w1 2 (1 k ) N 2 w 2 j N 2 ej 2 e1 k (1 k ) w1 (1 k ) w j ej 2 2 N N (1 k ) 2 wi w j ei ej i 2 j 2, j i Differentiating this with respect to k, and setting this derivative to zero, yields the optimal value for k in respect of country 1 as follows:10 (8) k0 X1 Y1 where N N X 1 2 (1 w1 ) 2 w 2j e21 w1 (1 w1 ) w 2j ej2 2 2 N N N wi w j ei ej e1 (1 2w1 ) w j ej i 2 j 2 2 j i 10 Since any country can be designated as country 1, the formula can be applied to any country. 14 N N Y1 2 (1 w1 ) 2 w 2j e21 (1 w1 ) 2 w 2j ej2 2 2 N N N wi w j ei ej 2 e1 (1 w1 ) w j ej i 2 j 2 2 j i With V defined in the same way as in the previous section, the Appendix also shows that N N (9) 2 V 1 N N 1 2 ej i 1 j 1 j i ei ej N ( N 1) In respect of the country weights within the cross-country average, the variance of the estimation error arising from the cross-country average is minimised using weights that are proportional to the inverse of the individual market variances.11 These weights are shown in Table 4. The unbiased estimates for V and are still .0182 2 and .355 respectively (as in the previous section) whilst the unbiased estimates for ei are shown in Table 1. Substitution of the relevant parameter estimates into equation (9) yields an estimate for 2 of .0004 2 . Substitution of this estimate for 2 and other relevant parameter values into equation (8) then yields the optimal value for k for each country, designated k0, and the results are shown in the penultimate column of Table 4. These k0 values range from -0.117 for Germany to 0.192 for Canada, and are monotonically 11 See Granger (1989, section 8.3) for a discussion of combining estimators and the use of this particular weighting scheme. 15 decreasing in the estimated standard deviation for the market.12 Interestingly the weight of the US in the cross-country average is only fifth largest (at .065), because its estimated standard deviation is only fifth smallest, and the optimal weight on the estimator using only US data (as part of the combined estimator) is only .062. Substitution of these values for k0 along with other relevant parameter values into equation (7) then yields the MSE of the estimation error for each country. Despite the cross-country variation in the k0 values, the resulting MSEs are .013 in all cases (to three decimal points). By comparison, in the previous section, k0 was estimated at .021 for all countries and the MSE of the estimator was .014. Thus, the recognition of differential standard deviations across markets gives rise to variation in k0 values across countries but it does not materially change the MSE of the estimator. This holds even for the market with the smallest estimated standard deviation (Canada) and therefore the largest value for k0. Furthermore, the cross-country variation in the estimated standard deviations is likely to exceed the true cross-country variation and therefore the benefits from both 12 Negative k0 values arise from the coefficient on p in the numerator of equation (8) because the first term in the numerator (involving 2 ) is positive and the next two terms net to zero under the scheme for setting wi described above. Thus, a necessary condition for k0 being negative is that p is non-zero. The intuition for negative k0 values is apparent by considering an extreme case in which 2 is zero (implying that all countries have the same market risk premium), p = 1, N = 2 and country 1 has the larger variance. Following equation (8), k0 is negative because this reduces the MSE (equivalent to the variance) of the combined estimator to zero. Similarly, for a two-asset portfolio with a correlation coefficient between the two assets of 1, a sufficiently negative weight on the higher variance asset will also reduce the portfolio variance to zero. 16 differentially weighting markets in forming the cross-country average and from different values for k0 across countries are likely to be exaggerated.13 In short, assuming all markets have the same standard deviation on the estimation error, and therefore both equally weighting markets in forming the cross-country average and applying the same k0 value to each market (.021), is only slightly inferior to recognising differential crosscountry standard deviations for the estimation errors, and even the slight apparent advantage of the latter approach will be overestimated. This suggests that one should equally weight all markets in forming the cross-country average and apply the same k0 value to all markets. Furthermore, as shown in the previous section, this common k0 value (.021) is so close to zero that there is no material benefit to departing from a zero value. This suggests that one should equally weight all markets in forming the crosscountry average then use this cross-country average to estimate the market risk premium for each market. This conclusion springs from the fact that the estimated cross-country variation in true market risk premiums is very low. 6. Statistical Inference The analysis so far utilises point estimates for the parameters in equations (5) and (8). However the estimates of these parameters are subject to sampling variation and consequently the estimate for the optimal weight on local data is also subject to sampling 13 The cross-sectional distribution of the estimates is the cross-sectional distribution of true values subject to adding an estimation error to each true value and the latter are uncorrelated with the former. So, the cross-sectional variation in the estimates is likely to exceed the cross-sectional variation in the true values. 17 variation. Accordingly it is desirable to estimate the confidence interval around the point estimate of the optimal weight on local data. However there are difficulties in doing so directly via equation (5) or (8). Consequently, we turn to an alternative approach that readily lends itself to determination of a confidence interval around the point estimate. Let ˆ1 j and ˆ2 j denote the estimates of the market risk premium for country j based upon only local data for two non-overlapping time periods. In the presence of sampling errors, these estimates will exhibit mean reversion, i.e., high (low) estimates in the first period relative to the cross-country average will tend to be followed by lower (higher) estimates in the second period. This is expressed in the following regression model (10) ˆ2 j a bˆ1 j j with b less than 1 in general. If the true market risk premiums in the two subperiods were equal, the slope coefficient in a regression of ˆ2 j on ˆ1 j would be an unbiased estimate of the true value b, i.e., (11) 1 N ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ N 1 (1 j 1 )( 2 j 2 ) j 1 b E 1 N ˆ (1 j ˆ1 ) 2 N 1 j 1 In general, it cannot be shown that the RHS of the last equation matches that of equation (3), and therefore it cannot be shown in general that the coefficient b is equal to the 18 optimal weight k0.14 However, consideration of certain extreme cases suggests that there is a close correspondence between these two parameters. For example, if the crosssectional variation in true market risk premiums were zero, meaning that the population mean characterised each country, then the estimates ˆ1 j and ˆ2 j would cease to be positively correlated, i.e., ˆ2 j e2 j ˆ1 j e1 j So the parameter b in equation (10) would be zero. Under the same scenario, k0 would also be zero as discussed following equation (3). Alternatively, if cross-sectional variation in the true market risk premiums were positive and sampling error went to zero, then ˆ2 j ˆ1 j Following equation (10), b then becomes 1. Under the same scenario, k0 = 1 as discussed following equation (3). Finally, if cross-sectional variation in the true market risk premiums is positive and sampling error exists but the correlation in sampling errors across countries goes to 1, then ˆ2 j ˆ1 j e2 e1 14 By contrast, it can be shown that the expectation of the numerator in equation (11) matches that in equation (3) and that the expectation of the denominator in (11) matches that in (3). 19 where e1 (e2) is the estimation error common to all firms in the first (second) subperiod. Again, following equation (10), this implies that b becomes 1. Under the same scenario, k0 = 1 as discussed following equation (3). Thus, in all three extreme cases, the regression model parameter b matches the optimal weight k0. In view of all this, we investigate the question of whether an estimate of b derived from a regression of the type shown in equation (10) would be an unbiased estimator of k0. If it is unbiased, or the degree of bias is slight, then this provides an alternative approach to estimating k0 with the advantage that such an approach allows the confidence interval around the point estimate to be determined. simulation. We therefore conduct the following We draw 19 true market risk premiums independently from a normal distribution with mean .07 and standard deviation .005; these two parameter values approximate the estimates obtained in section 4. The estimated market risk premiums are then determined by adding a normally distributed estimation error to each true market risk premium, with mean zero, standard deviation .031 and a correlation coefficient between all pairs of the estimation errors of .35; the latter figure matches the averages of the individual country pairs in section 4 whilst the standard deviation of .031 is the average of the individual countries in section 4 (.022) subject to scaling up by 2 to reflect the halving of the time period in the regression. These estimated market risk premiums are designated as those for the first subperiod. The process is then repeated to yield the estimated market risk premiums for the second subperiod, with the estimation errors for the second subperiod being independent of those in the first subperiod. The 20 cross-sectional regression of estimates for the second subperiod on those for the first subperiod is then run, and both the estimate of b and its standard error are recorded. This process is then repeated 5000 times. Consequently, the average of these estimates for b can be treated as closely approximating the true value for b. Since the correlations are positive, the Cholesky decomposition of the correlation matrix is computed and the resulting triangular matrix is used to form linear combinations of independent normal random variables with the required correlation structure. In addition, the fact that the estimation errors for countries are correlated implies that the regression residuals will have the same property. So, an HAC (heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent) estimate for the standard error of b̂ is presented (Andrews, 1991) as well as the conventional estimate. Finally, and consequent upon the use in section 5 of differential estimates across countries for the standard deviation of the estimation errors, we repeat the simulation using the differential point estimates of these standard deviations. The results of the simulation are shown in Table 5. The second column shows the k0 value determined in accordance with equation (3) or the cross-country average of the k0 values determined in accordance with equation (8). The third column shows the average of the b̂ values across the 5000 simulation runs, which should closely approximate the expected value. The fourth column shows the average across the 5000 simulation runs of the conventionally estimated standard error of b̂ . Finally, the last column shows the average across the 5000 simulation runs of the HAC estimates for the standard error of 21 b̂ . The difference between the values in the second and third columns is very small in both cases. Accordingly, the value of b̂ from the regression shown in equation (10) can be treated as an approximately unbiased estimator of k0 or the cross-country average of the k0. In addition the values in the last column are materially different to those in the third column, implying that the HAC approach should be adopted in estimating the standard error of b̂ . We therefore conduct the cross-sectional regression in equation (10), with ˆ1 j and ˆ2 j equal to the estimates of the market risk premium for country j based upon only local data for 1900-1950 and 1951-2010 respectively.15 This data is shown in Table 6. The OLS regression yields b̂ = 0.048 with an HAC estimated standard error of 0.095. The 95% confidence interval on b is then from -0.152 to 0.248. Accordingly, one cannot reject the hypothesis that b = 0 whilst one can clearly reject the hypothesis that b = 1.16 It follows that one cannot reject the hypothesis that k0 = 0 whilst one can clearly reject the hypothesis that k0 = 1. Thus, the use of the cross-country average would seem to be clearly superior to the use of only local data in estimating the market risk premium for a particular market, and any weighting given to local data in a combined estimator should not exceed 0.25. This point estimate here for b, and hence k0, of .048 is similar to the point estimate of .021 obtained in section 4, but with the advantage of now providing a 15 As with the estimates in section 4, the estimates are arithmetic means on stock returns net of the yield on bills, supplied by Mike Staunton from the Dimson, Marsh and Staunton data. 16 The conventional estimate for the standard error of the slope coefficient is .121, giving rise to a 95% confidence interval from -0.21 to 0.30. Even in this case, the hypothesis that b = 1 is clearly rejected. 22 confidence interval around the point estimate. In addition, following equation (3), an estimate for k0 equal to 0.048 in conjunction with the earlier estimates for e and ρ of 0.0224 and 0.355 respectively implies an estimate for of 0.4%, which is larger than the estimates of 0.26% in section 4 and 0.04% in section 5. In summary, using data from each market from both the first and second half of the data series to generate estimates of the market risk premiums for each market, and crosssectionally regressing the later estimates on the earlier ones, generates an estimate for k0 of .048, which is very similar to the estimate obtained in section 4 but with the advantage of now providing a 95% confidence interval on the estimate, from -0.152 to 0.248. Furthermore, this new estimate for k0 implies an estimate for the standard deviation on the cross-country distribution of true market risk premiums of 0.4%. 7. Forecasting Although the focus of this paper is estimation rather than forecasting, some techniques useful for forecasting can also be applied to estimation. One such approach would be to use estimates of the market risk premiums in the first half of the time series examined earlier to generate forecasts of the market risk premiums in the second half of the time series under various forecasting models, use estimates of the market risk premiums in the second half of the series to proxy for the true values (because the latter are unobservable), and then examine the comparative accuracy of various forecasting models. The natural forecasting models to examine would be the use of only local data, the cross-country 23 average, and the optimal combination (from the first half of the time series). However, the evidence obtained so far indicates that the optimal combination is virtually indistinguishable from the cross-country average. So, we compare the forecasting ability of local data and the cross-country average. In respect of proxies for the market risk premiums in the second half of the time series, standard practice is to use the ex-post outcome (such as Welch and Goyal, 2008) and this corresponds to the use of only local data. However, having judged that the cross-country average is a superior estimator, we also consider the cross-country average (from the second half of the time series) as a proxy for the true market risk premium in each market in that period. The RMSE of these forecasts is shown in Table 7. The first row of results arises when using only local data to proxy for the market risk premiums in the second half of the series. Forecasting these proxy values using the cross-country average in the first half of the series yields a smaller RMSE than using only local data in the first half of the series (2.64% versus 4.01%). Similarly, the last row of the table shows the results arising using the cross-country average from the second half of the series to proxy for the true market risk premiums in that period. Again, forecasting using the cross-country average in the first half of the series yields a smaller RMSE than using only local data in the first half of the series (2.11% versus 3.81%). It is also noticeable that, for any given method of forecasting (i.e., either column in Table 7), the better proxy for the market risk premiums in the second half of the series is the cross-country average rather than the use of only local data. So, consistent with the previous analysis, the cross-country average is clearly 24 superior to the use of only local data for both forecasting and proxying for the true market risk premiums in the second half of the time series. By contrast, in a pure forecasting exercise, the model presented earlier would require extension to include the time series properties of the estimation errors ej. In the simulation exercise reported in section 6, we assumed that estimation errors in the successive periods were independent, an assumption that seems reasonable when estimates are each based upon 55 years of data. However, in a pure forecasting exercise, estimates might be annual and the assumption of independence would be less reasonable. For example, a stationary ARMA process might be assumed. In summary, application of a forecasting technique to the data in section 6 also reveals the clear superiority of the cross-country average over the use of only local data. Furthermore, irrespective of the forecasting model used to generate the forecasts, the assessment of the forecasts requires a procedure for estimating the unobservable market risk premiums and again the cross-country average is superior to the use of only local data. 8. Alternative Methodologies The use of multi-country estimates of the market risk premium has so far been limited to the historical averaging methodology because estimates for a wide range of markets are available and the historical averaging methodology also readily allows for estimating 25 both the standard error of the point estimates and the correlation coefficient between point estimates for different markets. Nevertheless, it is possible to draw some conclusions about the results from using multi-country estimates from estimation methodologies other than historical averaging. Amongst these alternative methodologies, the lack of estimated market risk premiums for a wide range of countries prevents us from estimating the variance in the cross-sectional distribution of true market risk premiums ( 2 ). However the true value for 2 is invariant to the methodology used to estimate the market risk premium and our estimates for it from the historical averaging methodology range from .0004 2 to .004 2 .17 The same extrapolation is not necessarily justified for ρ but for the present purposes we use the estimate obtained in section 4 from the historical averaging methodology (0.355). Finally, regarding the variance of the estimator ( e2 ), some empirical work using these alternative methodologies provides estimates of e2 . Furthermore, equation (3) reveals that the optimal weight on local data is inversely related to e2 and positively related to 2 . So, providing we can extrapolate the estimate for ρ from the historical averaging methodology to these alternative methodologies, the highest weight on local data will arise from the highest estimate for 2 ( .004 2 ) along with the use of that methodology for estimating the market risk premium that provides the lowest estimate of e2 . 17 Section 4 estimates this variance at .0026 2 whilst section 5 estimates it as .0004 2 and section 7 2 estimates it as .004 . 26 Amongst these alternative methodologies, the lowest estimate for e2 appears to be that in Fama and French (2002), where the market risk premium is estimated from the average dividend yield plus the average expected capital gain (estimated from the average growth rate in dividends) less the risk free rate; when using this methodology, Fama and French (ibid, page 644) estimate e2 at .0074 2 . With this estimate and the highest estimate for 2 ( .004 2 ), application of equation (3) shows that the optimal weight on local data would be as follows k0 2 .004 2 .31 2 e2 (1 ) .004 2 .0074 2 (1 .355) Using other estimation methodologies or lower estimates of 2 , the estimate of k0 would be lower. Thus, even for estimation methodologies other than historical averaging, the optimal weight on local data is still low. Furthermore such results are not particularly sensitive to ρ; for example, if ρ rises from .355 to .50, then the estimate of k0 in the last equation only rises to .37. In summary, preliminary application of the combined estimator to a range of methodologies other than historical averaging indicates that the optimal weight on local data would still be low. 9. Conclusions 27 This paper has developed an estimator for a country’s market risk premium, which involves optimally combining an estimator based upon only local data with the crosscountry average of these estimators. This paper has also compared this combined estimator to that of its two components, using historical data, and the conclusions are as follows. Firstly, using the historical averaging methodology and assuming that the standard deviations for the estimation errors arising from the use of only local data are the same for all countries, very little of the cross-country variation in estimated market risk premiums appears to be due to cross-country variation in true market risk premiums, and therefore the combined estimator places very little weight upon the estimator based upon only local data. Secondly, both the combined estimator and the cross-country average have RMSEs that are almost 40% less than that arising from using only local data. Thirdly, recognition of differential standard deviations in estimation errors across countries, which leads to differential country weights in the cross-country average as well as differences across countries in the optimal weight on local data, produces only small reductions in the RMSE of the combined estimator. Fourthly, using historical data from each market from both the first and second half of the data series to generate estimates of the market risk premiums for each market, and regressing the later estimates on the earlier ones, also generates an estimate for the optimal weight on local data that is close to zero, but with the advantage of also generating a 95% confidence interval around the point estimate with an upper bound of 0.25. Fifthly, using data from the first half of the data series to generate forecasts for the market risk premiums for each market, and 28 estimating the latter from data in the second half of the data series, the cross-country average is again clearly superior to the use of only local data both for generating the forecasts and estimating the subsequent unobservable market risk premiums in the course of assessing the accuracy of the forecasts. Lastly, preliminary application of the combined estimator to a range of methodologies other than historical averaging indicates that the optimal weight on local data would still be low. All of this suggests that, regardless of the methodology for estimating the market risk premium, the usual practice of invoking only local data is significantly inferior to the use of a cross-country average or a combined estimator with very high weighting on the cross-country average. 29 APPENDIX This Appendix provides the proofs for equations (2), (4), (7) and (9) in the paper. We start with the scenario examined in section 2, in which the estimation errors arising from using only local data for each market have the same standard deviation, all country pairs have the same correlation coefficient for the estimation errors, and therefore the optimal country weights within the cross-country average are equal. In respect of country j, the estimator for the market risk premium using only data for that market ( ˆ j ) is the sum of the true value j and an estimation error e j , and j is the sum of the mean of the crosssectional distribution of countries’ true market risk premiums ( ) and a random drawing j from that distribution: ˆ j j e j j e j The combined estimator places weight k on ˆ j and the balance on the cross-country average of these estimates ( ˆ ). For a randomly selected country (designated 1), the estimation error associated with the combined estimator is therefore as follows. ˆc 1 kˆ1 (1 k )ˆ 1 In choosing the weighting k, and consistent with the literature (Efron and Morris, 1975), we minimise the sum across countries of the mean squared errors. This is equivalent to minimising the MSE of a randomly selected country (country 1) with the expectation 30 over both estimation errors and countries. Furthermore, across both countries and estimation errors, the estimation error shown in the last equation is mean zero and therefore minimising the MSE (with the expectation over both countries and estimation errors) is equivalent to minimising the variance of the estimation error for the randomly selected country 1. Letting N denote the number of countries used in forming the crosscountry average, recognising that the random variables 1.... N are mutually independent, that j and ej are independent for each j, and that the random variables e1….eN are correlated with correlation coefficient denoted ρ, the MSE using the combined estimator is as follows. MSE Var ˆc 1 1 N Var k ( 1 e1 ) (1 k ) ( j e j ) ( 1 ) N j 1 1 k 1 N 1 N 1 k Var 1 k 1 (1 k ) j e1 k (1 k ) e j N N j 2 N N j 2 2 2 1 k (1 k ) 2 1 k (1 k ) 2 2 k 1 ( N 1 ) k ( N 1) e 2 2 N N N N 2 2 1 k 1 k 2 (1 k ) 2 e2 k ( N 1 ) ( N 1) 2 ( N 1) e 2 N N N 1 1 1 1 2 (1 k ) 2 1 e2 k 2 1 e2 1 k 2 1 N N N N This is equation (2). Defining V as the expectation of the cross-sectional sample variance in these locally-based estimates of the market risk premiums, it follows that 31 N ˆ ˆ 2 ( j ) j 1 V E N 1 1 N E (ˆ j ˆ ) 2 N 1 j 1 N E (ˆi ˆ ) 2 N 1 ˆ 1 N ˆ N E i j N 1 N j 1 2 N 1 E i ei N 1 N ( j e j ) j 1 N 2 N 1 N 1 N 1 1 E i ei j e j N 1 N N j i N N j i 2 2 2 2 e2 N 2 N 1 N 2 N 1 ( N 1 ) ( N 1) e 2 2 N 1 N N N N 1 N N 1 1 N ( N 1) 2 ( N 1) e2 2 ( N 1) N 1 N2 N N 2 e2 e2 Solving this equation for 2 yields equation (4) as follows: 2 V e2 (1 ) 32 We now turn to the scenario examined in section 5, in which the standard deviations of the estimation errors from using only local data differ across countries and therefore the country weights within the cross-country average (wj) may differ. As before, we minimise the MSE with the expectation over both countries and estimation errors and this is equivalent to minimising the variance of the estimation error for randomly selected country 1 arising from the combined estimator: MSE Var ˆc 1 N Var k ( 1 e1 ) (1 k ) w j ( j e j ) ( 1 ) j 1 N N Var 1 (1 k )( w1 1) (1 k ) w j j e1 k w1 (1 k ) (1 k ) w j e j j 2 j 2 N N 2 2 (1 k ) 2 ( w1 1) 2 (1 k ) 2 w 2j e21 k (1 k ) w1 (1 k ) 2 w 2j ej2 j 2 j 2 N N N 2 e1 k (1 k ) w1 (1 k ) w j ej (1 k ) 2 wi w j ei ej j 2 i 2 j 2 j i This is equation (7), which reduces to equation (2) in the special case in which the wi are equal and the ei are also equal. Turning to V, still defined with the cross-country average equally weighted, this is now as follows: 33 N ˆ ˆ 2 ( j ) V E i 1 N 1 1 N E (ˆi ˆ ) 2 N 1 i 1 1 N ˆ 1 N ˆ j E i N N 1 i 1 j 1 2 1 N 1 N E e ( j e j ) i s N 1 i 1 N j 1 2 1 1 N N 1 N 1 1 N ei j e j E i N 1 i 1 N N j 1 N N j 1 j i j i 2 N Since the random variables j and ej are independent, and 1 ,...., N are mutually independent, and the correlation coefficient between the estimation errors for country pairs is the same for all pairs (ρ), it follows that 2 1 N 2 ( N 1) 2 N 1 1 2 N 1 ei V 2 2 N 1 i 1 N N N 1 N 1 i 1 N 2 N N N j 1 k 1 j i k i k j ej ek ( N 1) N 1 N 2 2 ei2 ( N 1) N 2 N i 1 j 1 j i N 2 ej N 1 2 2 ei ej N j 1 j i N N j 1 2 ej 34 ( N 2) ( N 1) N 2 2 1 N N i 1 ei N N ei ej i 1 j 1 j i N 2 N2 N i 1 j 1 j i N ( N 1) N i 1 j 1 j i N ei ei ej ej Solving this equation for 2 yields the following: N N 2 V 1 N N 1 2 ej p i 1 j 1 j i ei ej N ( N 1) This is equation (9), which reduces to equation (4) in the special case in which the ei are equal. 35 Table 1: Estimated Market Risk Premiums and Standard Deviations _____________________________________________________________________ ˆ ˆ (ˆ) _____________________________________________________________________ Australia .0851 .0167 Belgium .0572 .0234 Canada .0573 .0163 Denmark .0485 .0195 Finland .0995 .0287 France .0896 .0233 Germany .0998 .0305 Ireland .0558 .0204 Italy .1020 .0303 Japan .0952 .0263 Netherlands .0663 .0216 New Zealand .0596 .0174 Norway .0611 .0251 S Africa .0861 .0209 Spain .0557 .0207 Sweden .0694 .0209 Switzerland .0520 .0179 UK .0631 .0189 US .0738 .0188 Mean .0725 .0220 _____________________________________________________________________ This table shows estimates of the market risk premiums for 19 markets using the historical averaging methodology and only local data for each market ( ˆ ), along with the estimated standard deviations of these estimators ˆ (ˆ) . 36 Table 2: The RMSE of Competing Estimators ________________________________________________________________________ N Vˆ ˆ e2 ̂ ˆ 2 k0 RMSE RMSE RMSE k=1 k = .021 k=0 ________________________________________________________________________ 19 .0182 2 .0224 2 .355 .0026 2 .021 .022 .014 .014 ________________________________________________________________________ This table shows the estimated RMSE of competing estimators of the market risk premium, arising from a range of weights on local data (k). The underlying parameter values are also shown. 37 Table 3: Estimated Correlation Coefficients _____________________________________________________________________ UK US Ge Ja Ne Fr It Swi Au Ca Sw De Sp Be Ire SA Nor NZ _____________________________________________________________________ US .55 Ger .28 .28 Jap .21 .19 .31 Ne .45 .40 .39 .15 Fr .43 .29 .37 .21 .45 It .23 .30 .14 .14 .24 .47 Swi .60 .53 .41 .22 .53 .55 .33 Aus .54 .44 .36 .15 .41 .47 .33 .51 Can .47 .83 .31 .22 .38 .35 .29 .55 .55 Swe .45 .47 .31 .26 .53 .48 .30 .53 .40 .51 Den .38 .35 .24 .34 .48 .37 .27 .47 .36 .44 .61 Sp .23 .21 .09 .12 .26 .47 .34 .36 .30 .28 .40 .31 Bel .34 .36 .44 .13 .57 .62 .21 .49 .34 .37 .41 .33 .37 Ire .65 .39 .31 .17 .47 .48 .27 .64 .61 .45 .47 .57 .37 .42 SAf .32 .45 .16 .24 .19 .22 .23 .26 .42 .55 .28 .26 .11 .19 .32 Nor .16 .24 .11 .17 .36 .38 .27 .38 .31 .43 .42 .46 .22 .28 .23 .36 NZ .37 .28 .15 .19 .35 .39 .27 .31 .62 .34 .49 .42 .40 .22 .49 .38 .33 Fin .23 .29 .16 .24 .32 .32 .07 .35 .23 .47 .56 .45 .38 .33 .31 .30 .37 .32 _____________________________________________________________________ This table shows estimated correlation coefficients for the estimation errors for market pairs, based upon annual data over the period 1900-2010. 38 Table 4: Optimal Market Weights _____________________________________________________________________ w k0 _____________________________________________________________________ Australia .082 .166 Belgium .042 -.061 Canada .086 .192 Denmark .061 .036 Finland .028 -.110 France .042 -.058 Germany .025 -.117 Ireland .055 .005 Italy .025 -.116 Japan .033 -.094 Netherlands .049 -.027 New Zealand .076 .126 Norway .036 -.083 S Africa .052 -.010 Spain .053 -.005 Sweden .052 -.010 Switzerland .071 .099 UK .064 .056 US .065 .062 _____________________________________________________________________ This table shows the optimal country weights within the cross-country average when differential standard deviations across countries for the estimation errors using local data are recognised (w). In addition the optimal weight on local data in the combined estimator for each country (k0) is also shown. 39 Table 5: Simulation Results _____________________________________________________________________ e AV (bˆ) k0 AV (sbOLS ) AV (sbHAC ) ˆ ˆ _____________________________________________________________________ .031 .038 .038 .242 .219 Varying .042 .036 .242 .225 _____________________________________________________________________ This table shows the average results from 5000 simulation trials, for each of two scenarios relating to the standard deviation of the estimation errors for individual markets when only local data is used. The first column shows the true value for the standard deviation of the estimation error for each market. The second column shows the true value for k0 or the cross-country average of the true values if they differ across countries. The third column shows the average regression slope, the fourth column shows the average estimate of the OLS standard error on the regression slope, and the last column shows the average estimate of the HAC standard error. 40 Table 6: Sub-period Estimates of the Market Risk Premiums _____________________________________________________________________ ˆ1 ˆ2 _____________________________________________________________________ Australia .0993 .0730 Belgium .0634 .0519 Canada .0606 .0544 Denmark .0249 .0686 Finland .0971 .1014 France .0821 .0960 Germany .0873 .1090 Ireland .0210 .0854 Italy .1355 .0736 Japan .0857 .1032 Netherlands .0388 .0898 New Zealand .0604 .0589 Norway .0314 .0864 S Africa .0838 .0880 Spain .0290 .0784 Sweden .0356 .0982 Switzerland .0199 .0792 UK .0320 .0896 US .0718 .0756 _____________________________________________________________________ This table shows estimates of the market risk premiums for 19 markets using the historical-averaging methodology and local data for each market for both 1900-1950 ( ˆ1 ) and for 1951-2010 ( ˆ ). 2 41 Table 7: Forecasting Results _____________________________________________________________________ Forecasting Using Forecasting Using MRP Proxy Local Data Cross-Country Average _____________________________________________________________________ Local Data 4.01% 2.64% Cross-Country Average 3.81% 2.11% _____________________________________________________________________ This table shows the RMSE from forecasting the market risk premiums in the period 1951-2010 using either local data or the cross-country average from 1900-1950, and proxying the market risk premiums in the period 1951-2010 using either the local data or the cross-country average from that period. 42 This figure shows the relationship between the RMSE of various estimators and the standard deviation of the cross-sectional distribution of true MRPs. The estimators considered involve placing all weight upon local data (k = 1), placing all weight on the cross-country average (k = 0), and the optimal combination of these two estimators. The figure shows the extent of superiority of the combined estimator over each of its components. 43 REFERENCES Andrews, D. “Heteroscedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation.” Econometrica, 59 (1991), 817-858. Cavaglia, S.; C. Brightman; and M. Aked. “The Increasing Importance of Industry Factors.” Financial Analysts Journal, Sept-Oct (2000), 41-54. Chay, J.; A. Marsden; and R. Stubbs. “Historical Rates of Return to Equities, Bonds, and the Equity Risk Premium: New Zealand Evidence.” Pacific Accounting Review, 5 (1993), 27-46. Claus, J., and J. Thomas. “Equity Premia as Low as Three Percent?: Evidence from Analysts’ Earnings Forecasts for Domestic and International Stocks.” The Journal of Finance, 56 (2001), 1629-1666. Cornell, B. The Equity Risk Premium, New York: John Wiley & Sons (1999). Dimson, E., and P. Marsh. “Calculating the Cost of Capital.” Long Range Planning, 15 (1982), 112-120. ______________________ M. Staunton. Triumph of the Optimists, New Jersey: Princeton University Press (2002). __________________________________ “Global Evidence on the Equity Risk Premium.” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15 (4), Fall (2003), 27-38. ____________________________________ Credit Suisse Global Investment Returns Sourcebook 2011. Credit Suisse (2011). Donaldson, G.; M. Kamstra; and L. Kramer. “Estimating the Equity Premium.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45 (2010), 813-846. Efron, B. Large Scale Inference: Empirical Bayes Methods for Estimation, Testing and Prediction, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (2010). _______ and C. Morris. “Data Analysis Using Stein’s Estimator and its Generalisations.” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 70 (1975), 311-319. Fama, E., and K. French. “The Equity Premium.” The Journal of Finance, 57 (2002), 637-659. Granger, C. Forecasting in Business and Economics, 2nd edition, Boston: Academic Press Inc (1989). 44 Grauer, R., and N. Hakannson. “Stein and CAPM Estimators of the Means in Asset Allocation.” International Review of Financial Analysis, 4 (1995), 35-66. Guo, H., and R. Whitelaw. “Uncovering the Risk-Return Relation in the Stock Market.” The Journal of Finance, 61 (2006), 1433-1463. Harvey, C. “Drivers of Expected Returns in International Markets.” Emerging Markets Quarterly, Fall (2000), 1-17. Ibbotson, R., and R. Sinquefield. “Stocks, Bonds, Bills and Inflation; Year by Year Historical Returns (1926-1974).” Journal of Business, 49 (1976), 11–47. Jagannathan, R.; E. McGrattan; and A. Scherbina. “The Declining US Equity Premium.” Federal Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 24 (2001), 3-19. James, W., and C. Stein. “Estimation with Quadratic Loss.” Proceedings of the Fourth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, 1 (1961), 361-379. Jorion, P. “Bayes-Stein Estimation for Portfolio Analysis.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 21 (1986), 279-292. Karolyi, A. “A Bayesian Approach to Modelling Stock Return Volatility for Option Valuation.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 28 (1993), 579-594. Lehmann, E., and G. Casella. Theory of Point Estimation, 2nd edition, New York: Springer (1998). Lintner, J. “The Valuation of Risky Assets and the Selection of Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 47 (1965), 13-37. Maheu, J., and T. McCurdy. “How Useful are Historical Data for Forecasting the LongRun Equity Return Distribution.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 27 (2009), 95-112. Markowitz, H. “Portfolio Selection.” The Journal of Finance, 7 (1952), 77-91. ___________ Portfolio Selection, New Haven: Yale University Press (1959). Mayfield, S. “Estimating the Market Risk Premium.” Journal of Financial Economics, 73 (2004), 465-496. Merton, R. “On Estimating the Expected Return on the Market.” Journal of Financial Economics, 8 (1980), 323-61. Mossin, J. “Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market.” Econometrica, 24 (1966), 768-783. 45 Officer, R. “Rates of Return to Equities, Bond Yields and Inflation Rates: An Historical Perspective.” In Share Markets and Portfolio Theory, 2nd edition, Ball, R., F. Finn, P. Brown, and R. Officer, eds. University of Queensland Press (1989). Pastor, L., and R. Stambaugh. “The Equity Premium and Structural Breaks.” The Journal of Finance, 56 (2001), 1207-1245. Scruggs, J. “Resolving the Puzzling Intertemporal Relation between the Market Risk Premium and Conditional Market Variance: A Two-Factor Approach”. The Journal of Finance, 53 (1998), 575-603. Sharpe, W. “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium Under Conditions of Risk.” The Journal of Finance, 19 (1964), 425-442. Siegel, J. “The Equity Premium: Stock and Bond Returns since 1802.” Financial Analysts Journal, Jan-Feb (1992), 28-38. Solnik, B. “An Equilibrium Model of the International Capital Market.” Journal of Economic Theory, 8 (1974), 500-524. Vasicek, O. “A Note on Using Cross-Sectional Information in Bayesian Estimation of Security Betas.” The Journal of Finance, 28 (1973), 1233-1239. Welch, I., and A. Goyal. “A Comprehensive Look at the Empirical Performance of Equity Premium Prediction.” The Review of Financial Studies, 21 (2008), 1455-1508. 46