Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials Priority Medicines for Europe and the World "A Public Health Approach to Innovation" Background Paper Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-to-Head Comparative Trials By Warren Kaplan, Ph.D., JD, MPH 7 October 2004 8.4-1 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials Table of Contents Executive Summary................................................................................................................................... 3 1. Introduction ....................................................................................................................................... 4 1.1 Comparative Effectiveness .................................................................................................... 4 1.2 Cost-Effectiveness ................................................................................................................... 5 2. Experiences with Comparative Effectiveness and Cost-Effectiveness ................................... 6 2.1 EMEA........................................................................................................................................ 6 2.2 National Institute for Clinical Excellence ............................................................................ 6 2.3 Australia ................................................................................................................................... 6 2.4 United States ............................................................................................................................ 7 2.4.1 Medicare Program ................................................................................................................ 7 2.4.2 `Prescription Drug Comparative Effectiveness Act of 2003’ .......................................... 8 2.4.3 Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act (MMA) ............ 8 3. Comparative Effectiveness and the Need for Head-to-Head Clinical Trials ........................ 8 3.1 The Value of Comparative Clinical Trials ........................................................................... 9 3.2 Criticism of Comparative Clinical Trials ............................................................................. 9 4. Sponsoring Comparative Trials ................................................................................................... 12 4.1 Industry Sponsored Trials ................................................................................................... 12 4.2 Government-Sponsored Trials ............................................................................................ 12 5. Alternatives ...................................................................................................................................... 12 5.1 Partnerships Between Public and Private Sectors to Conduct Post Marketing Studies ................................................................................................................................................. 12 5.2 Electronic Prescribing and Comparative Effectiveness: The Future? ............................ 13 6. Conclusions...................................................................................................................................... 14 References ................................................................................................................................................. 15 8.4-2 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials Executive Summary Prescription drugs can be very expensive and their cost may be a barrier to universal access. Governments of most developed countries have subsidy systems to achieve equity of access to pharmaceuticals. For a number of these medications at launch, we know little about their effectiveness beyond comparison to a placebo. In most circumstances, this is the most scientifically robust comparison available to demonstrate efficacy. The EMEA and other regulatory authorities will find that a new product meets the statutory requirement for efficacy if superior to placebo. To estimate comparative efficacy between two medicines, large trials are needed since there are often small differences between treatment outcomes when the interventions are compared. Regulatory agencies neither examine products under conditions of routine use nor determine whether a product is better value for the money than alternatives (cost effectiveness) although, for making reimbursement decisions cost effectiveness is very important and many countries do incorporate some sort of economic evidence into their reimbursement schemes. The industry does conduct comparative trials after approval if they have not been conducted during development. Nevertheless, it is certainly fair to say that the discovery that a new product, which has yet to establish a market, is no better than an older and cheaper one could be commercially problematic.. Comparative trials can be expensive and take many years to complete. There are at least two alternatives to having either the industry or the government pay for comparative clinical trials. In one approach, private insurers and the government would set aside some fraction of their annual drug spending to endow a new institute to provide an independent source of reputable research into comparative effectiveness and cost. The other approach relies on electronic prescription and medical databases to conduct Phase IV and/or pharmacoepidemiologic studies to supplement or even take the place of randomized, controlled, comparative clinical trials. The EU is presently discussing so-called “e prescribing” and other IT approaches. We see a great comparative advantage in the EU, as such electronic linkage of prescribers and medical records is still fragmented in the United States. 8.4-3 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials 1. Introduction From a public health and equity viewpoint, drugs are not normal items of commerce but are “public goods” that should be distributed on the basis of "end user" need or ability to benefit rather than "end user" ability to pay.1 Because many drugs are very expensive, availability on the market is therefore not sufficient to ensure access for all the population. Governments of most developed countries have subsidy systems to achieve equity of access to pharmaceuticals. Such subsidy systems involve delicate balancing acts. Given the costs to provide and deliver health care today, as costs rise, the need to look for every opportunity to extract “value” has become much more important.1 1.1 Comparative Effectiveness Unfortunately, for most of these medications at the time they are launched, we know little about their effectiveness beyond comparison to a placebo. This is because, for the most part, the ability of a medicine to provide “efficacy” is still derived from randomized clinical trials and, under the current licensing regulations of major industrialized countries, the manufacturer must show clinical trial evidence from placebo-controlled trials. Thus, a sponsor must show absolute, not comparative, efficacy in scientific terms to achieve marketing approval. So long as a new product is more effective than placebo, barring other issues, the FDA and the EMEA will find it meets the statutory requirements.i Comparator studies may be set up to statistically demonstrate “superiority” to the comparator or as a a “non-inferiority” trial which occurs when a new drug is tested against a standard treatment with similar efficacy and the trial must be designed to show that the new treatment is equivalent to, or not worse than, the standard therapy.2 If one cannot reasonably determine what the absolute effect of a standard treatment is in a study (sometimes referred to as the equivalence or non-inferiority margin), it is not possible to interpret a non-inferiority study. Defining the effect of the standard treatment control is more difficult where the effect of the standard therapy is relatively small (e.g., increased survival by 2-3 months). A risk in any given study population is that the standard therapy control actually had no absolute effect and that a new treatment that was indistinguishable from control might have no effect either. To estimate comparative efficacy or to show equivalence studies that are much larger than the usual placebo controlled studies are needed. 3 Comparative benefit can be determined without placebos, indeed placebo-controlled trials are not possible in some cases, because when an efficacious treatment already exists it is unethical to assign placebo treatment to patients as it violates the ethical principle of equipoise, a state of uncertainty regarding which of the treatments studied is better.2 On the other hand, FDA does consider relative safety, and will refuse to approve a new product that has a distinctly less favorable risk-benefit ratio than already marketed products. i 8.4-4 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials Industry has a preference for comparison with placebo as the main determinant of efficacy for regulatory approval.4 Currently in most major drug regulatory authorities, a requirement for active treatment comparative studies is still the exception, although requests for active comparator studies are increasing. Indirect comparisons involve creating a comparison between drugs A and B when there are two placebo controlled trials: A v. placebo and B v. placebo.5 Another type of indirect study involves a review of clinical trials between A v. B and C v. B to enable a comparison between A versus C. 6 Such indirect comparisons are problematic. 5, 6 Biases may arise due to differences in methodology, outcome measurement, or the populations included in studies of the two drugs. The best information will come from large, properly constructed randomized trials, using valid outcomes, and done in a way that is meaningful to clinical practice. Data from trials prone to bias because of faulty design will not be of use and may give rise to misleading conclusions. Sufficient numbers of patients and events are required to overcome any random effects. 1.2 Cost-Effectiveness Moreover, the systems for pharmaceutical evaluation in most countries do not allow for studies to determine whether the product is better value for the money than alternatives (cost effectiveness. Generally, the assessment of comparative cost has not been germane to scientific assessment in the regulatory process. In making reimbursement decisions, however, cost effectiveness is very important. Several EU countries , including the Netherlands, Portugal, Finland, Denmark and the UK, have all introduced procedures in reimbursement decisions to use some economic evidence.7 Many other EU countries do not mandate cost effectiveness data for reimbursement, however it is implicit that manufacturers need to include this evidence in the reimbursement dossier. Additionally other EU countries (France, Italy, Spain) require or strongly encourage economic evidence for pricing rather than reimbursement. One source of cost-effectiveness research is the pharmaceutical industry itself. However, public and private managers of drug benefits might not consider research by manufacturers a sound basis for decisions about which drugs to favor. 8, 9 The objectivity of manufacturer-sponsored research seeking to justify claims that a drug is better than its competition can be questioned. There is evidence that studies sponsored by drug companies are more likely to have findings favoring the sponsor’s drug than are those having other sponsors.8, 9, 10 Conversely, large purchasers and insurers have also shown interest in sponsoring research on the relative value of different drugs, but the potential bias of their results also could be raised, especially by manufacturers or patients and their physicians.8 8.4-5 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials 2. Experiences with Comparative Effectiveness and Cost-Effectiveness 2.1 EMEA New pharmaceutical legislation for the EMEA came into force on 20 May 2004. 11 The new legislation made it clear that, although “…[M]ember States have developed an evaluation of the comparative efficacy of medicinal products aimed at positioning a new medicinal product with respect to those that already exist in the same therapeutic class… this evaluation should not be conducted in the context of the marketing authorization for which it is agreed that the fundamental criteria should be retained.“11 (italics added). Thus, it would appear that the EMEA is still considering safety and efficacy using placebo-controlled trials. However, comparator studies are often requested on grounds of assessment of risk/benefit. 2.2 National Institute for Clinical Excellence The National Institute for Clinical Excellence (NICE) was established in 1999 and now regularly bases its decisions regarding drugs on evidence- based evaluation of their comparative effectiveness and cost effectiveness, comparing their costs, and benefits with other treatments.12 Manufacturers can be requested by NICE to provide quantitative comparisons with other forms of treatment, so that data comparing the new product with current standard therapy “head tohead” is sometimes available by the time NICE reviews the product. It is incumbent upon manufacturers to provide everything to NICE, which would include comparator information. 2.3 Australia The Pharmaceutical Benefits Advisory Committee (PBAC), a statutory committee established under the National Health Act of 1953, consists of family and specialist medical practitioners, pharmacists, and a consumer representative. The PBAC is charged with making recommendations to the minister for health and aged care about which drugs and medicinal preparations should be listed for subsidy. 1 The PBAC must consider comparative effectiveness and cost in making its recommendations. To fulfill this requirement, cost-effectiveness requirements were phased in during 1991 and 1992 and became mandatory in 1993. The choice of an existing treatment with which the new drug will be compared is critical.1 The most prescribed pharmacological analogue used for the same indication is usually preferred. If the drug is in a new pharmacological class, the drug most prescribed on the Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme (PBS) for the same indication is the comparator.1 If no currently listed drug is available, the main comparator usually is the standard medical (nondrug) management. The industry has argued that using these criteria could disadvantage new drugs, as they are compared with cheaper old drugs that are off-patent. PBAC prefers (but does not require) randomized trials that directly compare the proposed drug with the main comparator. Since head-to-head comparisons are rarely available, an analysis of two sets of randomized trials involving a common reference will often be acceptable (i.e., drug A v. comparator and drug B v. same 8.4-6 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials comparator). The clinical evidence is supposed to indicate whether a drug is better than, no worse than, or worse than the comparator and guides the type of economic analysis. Drugs that are worse overall than the comparator are generally not subsidized.1 Australia’s system, has been criticized by the drug industry. It is one model for how to obtain value for money in prescription drugs. Compared with other countries Australia pays a lower price for drugs and across all categories of drug it pays less than half the price paid in the United States.1 2.4 United States Individual states of the USA have begun to use economic analyses as part of their state Medicaid programs. For example, in 2001, the Oregon legislature directed the state’s Department of Human Services to consider the effectiveness and relative cost of different drugs. Under contract, researchers at the Oregon Health and Science University have conducted evidencebased reviews of published and unpublished studies on drugs in four therapeutic classes: gastrointestinal medications, two types of pain medications, and cholesterol-lowering drugs. These reviews serve as input into a public process through which the state identifies preferred drugs for its Medicaid plan.13 Individual states are using clinical and economic analysis as part of the Medicaid program. Evidence based practice centers are established in the USA (in which Oregon is one) and Canada to develop evidence reports and technology assessments based on rigorous, comprehensive syntheses and analyses of the scientific literature .The Academy of Managed Care Pharmacy which has ‘guidelines’ (a format for submission to Formularies) for clinical and economic evaluation which is often used by managed care firms, pharmacy benefit managers, and hospitals in the US. 14 2.4.1 Medicare Program The U.S. Medicare law reads, in part: “No payment may be made under [Medicare] for any expenses incurred for items or services [that] are not reasonable and necessary for the diagnosis or treatment of illness or injury or to improve the functioning of a malformed body member…”15 In 1989 the agency administering the Medicare program prepared a set of criteria, including cost-effectiveness.16 This later factor was not officially adopted. The Medicare program has developed a process by which national coverage decisions are made.17 These decisions affect all Medicare beneficiaries. The process relies on the evaluation of scientific evidence and can rely on outside technology assessments and the opinion of a newly created Medicare Coverage Advisory Committee. The question presented to the technology assessment body or to the advisory committee is generally, “is the evidence sufficient to demonstrate that the item or service provides a net health benefit compared to standard or accepted treatment.” The issue then is one of comparative benefit and that benefit requires an evidence basis. In practice, however, the level of evidence becomes directly proportional to the fiscal impact of the service resulting in a de facto cost-effectiveness.8 8.4-7 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials 2.4.2 `Prescription Drug Comparative Effectiveness Act of 2003’ In 2003, proposed legislation would have enabled the Director of the National Institutes of Health, in coordination with the Director of the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (AHRQ), to “conduct research, which may include clinical research, to develop valid scientific evidence regarding the comparative effectiveness, cost-effectiveness, and, where appropriate, comparative safety of covered prescription drugs relative to other drugs and treatments for the same disease or condition.”18 This proposal found its way into law later in the year (most likely a compromise between the two U.S. political parties) as the Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement and Modernization Act (MMA).19 (See Section 2.4.3). 2.4.3 Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act (MMA) This law (Pub. L. No. 108-173, § 1013, (2003)) was passed in late 2003. As we have mentioned, controlled multi-centered clinical trials that sponsors conduct for FDA approval purposes often do not generate the comparative data needed to judge whether the new item or service is medically necessary to treat the Medicare population in a clinical setting. Under the MMA, $50 million is authorized in 2004 for the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (AHRQ) to “… conduct and support research with a focus on outcomes, comparative clinical effectiveness and appropriateness of health care items and services (including pharmaceutical drugs), including strategies for how these items and services are organized, managed and delivered.” 18 (emphasis added) This provision seems to imply that there is a lack of relevant data in this regard. It thus seems inevitable that the AHRQ will be asked to conduct and support comparative clinical effectiveness research. Whether this means actual head-to-head clinical trials remains to be seen. The MMA is not explicit in requiring head-to-head comparative trials but one could easily read into the language such an implication. 3. Comparative Effectiveness and the Need for Head-to-Head Clinical Trials In principle, comparative effectiveness of drugs and other interventions can help to build government capability to understand and evaluate marginal “value” by acting as a precursor for cost effectiveness studies. In this view, which is not universally shared but which is of public health importance, the industry, government and purchasers act as the arbiters of value. The industry provides medical evidence – clinical trials, head-to-head trials. The government compares the evidence, validating conclusions on comparative outcomes. The purchasers pay for therapeutic “value”. 8.4-8 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials 3.1 The Value of Comparative Clinical Trials Many would take the position that head-to-head studies should be mandatory. A good recent example is the “antihypertensive and lipid lowering to prevent heart attack” trial (ALLHAT) of different antihypertensive drugs.20 See Textbox. ALLHAT tested an inexpensive diuretic versus an angiotensin-converting enzyme (ACE) inhibitor and a dihydropyridine calcium-channel blocker (DHP-CCB), both of which are much more expensive than diuretics. ALLHAT recommended that diuretics be prescribed first, rather than the more expensive drugs. The authors estimated that the USA health care system would have saved US$3.1 billion dollars between 1982 and 1992, had this recommendation been followed.20 No similar analysis has been done for the EU. It is almost certainly true that drug comparisons will grow in importance. Biotech companies have been developing expensive new drugs that cost many thousands of dollars a year and such price pressure is likely to increase the call for comparative trials against the best available treatment(s). In short, the typical argument is that more and better information about how well a medication works compared to existing treatments and other medications will promote more rational adoption of medicines and help to control health care costs. Some patients will respond better to drug A than drug B and vice versa. Research to be better able to identify which patients are more likely to benefit would have considerable value. 3.2 Criticism of Comparative Clinical Trials The reluctance of companies to perform comparative trials during drug development is easily explained. Traditionally, there has been little pressure from regulators to compare their products with those of their competitors. Trials of active treatments have to be large to detect small differences, which will add to the costs and time of conducting clinical trials. From a commercial standpoint, the discovery that a new product which has yet to establish a market, is no better than an older and cheaper one could be disastrous , and companies may try to avoid this by not selecting candidates at early phases of development that they deem are unlikely to have worthwhile clinical benefit. The reluctance could also be based on lack of guidance as to the comparator (i.e., what is and what is not a clinical “benefit” and who makes this decision) That is, since different products are in use in the markets of the world, it may often be very difficult to define one or two “gold standard” medications that would be accepted as such across a range of markets. We note that this reluctance does not extend beyond approval, when marketing departments make claims about the superiority of their products. Companies make claims based on indications agreed to by regulators and on the balance of the evidence, but often there is minimal data.3 As we alluded to above, comparative effectiveness reviews (whether by clinical trials, literature review or other method) serve as the empirical underpinning for cost effectiveness analyses. The pharmaceutical industry in particular, appreciates that such a distinction may be more apparent than real and that mandating comparative trials is essentially creating a de facto basis for cost 8.4-9 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials effectiveness. To be sure, the goal is improved patient care and efficiency, not just budget cutting21 An additional argument, based on the logic that comparative effectiveness is de facto cost effectiveness, is that comparative effectiveness studies will make the role of drug regulatory authories (e.g., the EMEA) more ambiguous as the EMEA would now be performing economic studies. Conversely, it can be argued that administrative agencies outside the EMEA should not do cost effectiveness studies as they are merely “second-guessing” the regulators with regard to efficacy and will end up becoming medical decision makers. Another criticism is that the ability accurately to assess the full value of a treatment takes many years. This is particularly so in relation to the treatment of chronic illness where surrogate endpoints often have to be used. For instance, by its very nature, long-term survival data for new cancer treatments will initially be lacking. A fundamental issue is whether available data could reasonably be extrapolated for a 10-year, 20-year or longer period.20 A further argument is that comparative efficacy data, are only valid when the most recent study is published, and never provide an up-to-date overview of the most recent clinical experience. It seems clear that requiring the industry to conduct head-to-head trials before or even after market approval is going to be quite expensive. The latest estimate for the average cost of researching and developing a new prescription drug is US$802 million, spread over 10 to 15 years.22 The Antihypertensive and Lipid-Lowering Treatment to Prevent Heart Attack Trial (ALLHAT) trial cost US$125 million23 and studied only one calcium channel blocker and one ACE inhibitor. See Textbox 1. For example British Columbia’s provincial Pharmacare lists 8 ACE inhibitors and 5 DHP-CCBs on its list of drugs reimbursed. 24 Given the costs of ALLHAT, head-to-head trials for each of them and one diuretic would cost an additional $800 million. 8.4-10 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials Textbox 1. The ALLHAT and ANBP2 Trials The ALLHAT trial enrolled more than 40,000 older Americans. The results showed that generic diuretics, previously introduced in the 1950s, were slightly superior to the more expensive calcium channel blockers and angiotensin converting enzyme (ACE) inhibitors. The participants in the trials who took diuretics suffered slightly fewer heart attacks and strokes than comparable groups on the other medicines. Specifically, the overall findings of the trial, showed that coronary heart disease (CHD) risk was not improved for any of the newer agents compared with the diuretic (represented by chlorthalidone) and that total mortality was similar for ALL groups. However, diuretic-based therapy was superior to alpha-blocker– based, ACE inhibitor– based, and calcium-channel blocker– based therapy in preventing 1 or more major forms of cardiovascular disease (CVD), including stroke and heart failure. Results were consistent for all outcomes by age, sex, diabetic status, and ethnicity, except for stroke and combined CVD. See Davis, BR et al. 2004. ALLHAT: Setting the Record Straight. Ann Intern Med. 141:39-46. The developers of this trial recommended that first line treatment of hypertension should be the thiazide-type diuretics, rather than the more expensive treatments. The second Australian National Blood Pressure Study (ANBP2) (Wing LM et al., 2003. A comparison of outcomes with angiotensin-converting-enzyme inhibitors and diuretics for hypertension in the elderly. NEJM 348: 583-592) seemingly contradicted the ALLHAT results in that the ANBP2 trial suggested that ACE-inhibitor regimens were actually superior to diuretics. The differences between the results were likely due to design differences and conduct of the trials. See Turnbull F. & Neal B. 2004. Resolving the differences between ACE inhibitors and diuretics- ALLHAT and ANBP2, Aust. Prescr. 27: 98-101. The lesson of ALLHAT is not that one drug worked "better" than another but that several classes of medicines worked just about the same. The lesson from a comparison of ALLHAT and ANBP2 is actually a clinical one, i.e., regardless of which medicine one uses, good blood pressure control is important. The ALLHAT results emphasize that pharmaceutical "innovation" should be judged based on head-to-head trials and not just on placebo-controlled trials. Head-to-head trials are more expensive than placebo trials because they require many more subjects. This gives the trial more statistical power, which is required to observe the small differences when the two drugs may have similar effects. According to US Food and Drug Administration regulations, Phase III trials (the final stage before approval) must have at least 1,000 to 3,000 people. ALLHAT had over 33,000 people. ALLHAT started recruiting in February 1994 and closed on March 31, 2002. Adding another 8 years to the time required to approve a drug for sale, or determine if components of a drug class are cost effective post marketing, is not good policy. 8.4-11 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials 4. Sponsoring Comparative Trials 4.1 Industry Sponsored Trials From the industries’ point of view, postmarketing clinical trials designed to show product cost effectiveness as well as clearly improve therapeutic outcomes will be needed to win preferred status among formularies and to motivate consumer loyalty even when the patients have to cover out-of pocket charges. Head-to-head clinical trials may be too expensive for individual European private companies to undertake as the level of pharmaceutical industry investment is generally less than that of the United States.8 Some classes of drugs cost the healthcare system tens or hundreds of millions of dollars annually.20 Having the industry spend some fraction of these costs in a trial could provide invaluable information on which to base policies, although one would have to find an equitable base (i.e., some fixed percentage of their net profit or sales or R&D allocation for that year) and other incentives to participate. Certainly, the industry would have to counter the obvious conflict-of-interest such sponsorship entails. 4.2 Government-Sponsored Trials Government-subsidized sponsorship of comparative trials is an option and governments could support postmarketing randomized trials to answer unresolved questions regarding the clinical and economic performance of new drugs. 3 However, governments will likely value some clinical outcomes differently than will firms responding to consumer needs. Governments may not share the preferences of consumers for certain aspcts of medication (e.g., convenience of use or increased quality of life may be valued more by consumers than by the government). 3 Generally, private firms will be better informed about the potential value of innovations to consumers and providers. Further, under a centralized system of comparative clinical research expenditures, lobbying by those groups that are better organized politically can distort the direction of research to better suit their particular needs. 5. Alternatives 5.1 Partnerships Between Public and Private Sectors to Conduct Post Marketing Studies Professor Uwe Reinhardt of Princeton University has called for private insurers and the government to set aside 1 percent of their annual drug spending to endow a new research institute to provide an “authoritative, independent source of reputable research into whether new, improved drugs are, indeed, significantly new and improved.”25, 26 At least in the U.S, this formula would generate about $1 billion for research, an amount roughly one-third of the $3.4 billion in total U.S. philanthropic spending on health in 2001.27, 28 Non-profit foundations cannot easily reach the $1 billion amount. A European counterpart to this may be a useful 8.4-12 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials approach, although it would likely generate less money and be difficult to do on a European wide basis as comparators and doses differ as do medical practice, e.g., treatment as a day case or in patient, length of hospital stay, doctors and nursing costs and the like 5.2 Electronic Prescribing and Comparative Effectiveness: The Future? Linking data on prescriptions and diagnoses from large administrative databases is invaluable in quantifying adverse effects. Arguably, using administrative databases will be useful for evaluating the comparative effectiveness of drugs. Commentators have mentioned that small genuine differences between active treatments are likely to be swamped by the confounding effects of differing indications, the characteristics of patients, and choices by doctors.3 Thus, very large databases will be required. With these caveats in mind, information could be potentially available in electronic prescription and medical databases to conduct Phase IV and/or pharmacoepidemiologic studies to take the place of, or supplement, randomized, controlled, comparative clinical trials. With electronic prescribing linked to medical records databases, it will in principle be possible to conduct cohort, case control and other observational, post marketing studies. Electronic prescribing linked to medical records can give physicians, patients, payers and regulators objective, comparative information about the efficacy of treatment alternatives and about the tradeoffs between cost, efficacy and adverse effects.29 Insurers and employers are shifting more and more of the out-of-pocket burden to patients, particularly for newer, more expensive, brand name prescriptions. Asked for higher copays for brand name products, consumers will want to know if the product is three times as effective as the $5 or $10 choices. E-prescribing tools, supported by patient-specific formulary information, plus up-to-date information about clinical results and therapeutic indications, can benefit physicians and shape the set of prescribing options they consider.29 The goal is to help make evidence about the comparative effectiveness and ineffectiveness of medical technologies and interventions available. The adoption of such electronic systems in the United States has been slow because of the fragmentation of service payment systems across federal and state governments as well as the many private insurers and large corporate self-insurers.30 Without a central payer, such as the UK's National Health Service, to drive use and to set data and workflow standards, US adoption has been limited to larger group practices and hospital-focused delivery communities.29 There is enormous potential for a comparative advantage over the U.S. in terms of expansion of electronic prescribing systems within the EU, although some of the more 8.4-13 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials obvious restraints to introducing electronic process include significant investment in hardware, software, implementation, and concerns about confidentiality. In April 2004, the European Commission made a strong policy statement that better use of IT and e-Health and e-Government technology will be necessary – and interoperable across EU member states.31 The package proposed by the Commission comprises three elements, the most relevant for the present discussion being an action plan on e-Health addressing the crucial role of new technologies and new ways of delivering health care in improving access to, quality and effectiveness of care. The action-plan takes a twin track approach: making the most of new information and communication technologies in the health sector and better integrating a range of e-Health policies and activities. In practice, this means making a reality of interoperable health care information systems, on-line and digital patient records; and new services such as teleconsultation and eprescribing.30 6. Conclusions Comparative clinical trials are important to determine whether two medicines are similar in their clinical effectiveness, supplementing the basic definition of efficacy from placebo studies. Although such trials demand many participants, can take a long time, and can be very expensive if there are many medicines to compare. From a commercial viewpoint, the pharmaceutical industry is acting rationally by being reluctant to place their products at risk by conducting head-to-head comparisons. In a practical sense, head-to-head trials can delay approval. The government may not be the best entity to perform these tests either. One proposal has the government and private sector insurers contributing to fund a research institute that would study clinical effectiveness and cost effectiveness. In the United States, the agency that is responsible for the Medicaid program does have such a research organization, although it is not a truly independent entity. The European Commission supports use of an action plan on electronic Health addressing the crucial role of new technologies and new ways of delivering health care in improving access to, quality and effectiveness of care. This plan would better integrate health care information systems, on-line and digital patient records; and new services such as teleconsultation and eprescribing. We propose to use this action plan as a way of creating post-marketing pharmacoepidemiologic studies to better understand comparative effectiveness and cost effectiveness. In the long run, it will be much less expensive than creating new comparative clinical trials de novo. 8.4-14 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials References Donald J. Birkett, Andrew S. Mitchell, and Peter McManus, 2001. A Cost-Effectiveness Approach To Drug Subsidy And Pricing In Australia Health Affairs 20 :104-114. 1 2 KJ Rothman . 1996, Editorial : Placebo mania BMJ 313:3-4 3 Henry D, Hill S. 1995, Comparing treatments. BMJ 310:1279. 4 Collier J., 1995, Editorial: Confusion over use of placebos in clinical trials BMJ 311:821-822. HC Bucher et al. , 1997. The results of direct and indirect treatment comparisons in meta-analysis of randomized controlled trials. J Clin Epidemiol. 50: 683-691. 5 L Sauriol et al. 2001, Meta-analysis comparing newer antipsychotic drugs for the treatment of schizophrenia: evaluating the indirect approach. Clinical therapeutics 23: 942-956. 6 Ian Dodds-Smith and Grant Bagley, Arnold & Porter , 2001. Cost effectiveness - the fourth hurdle to market entry, available at www.practicallaw.com/A27967, last accessed 2 July 2004. 7 John F. Hoadley, 2004, The Continued Need For Independent Research On Prescription Drugs, Health Affairs, 23: 244-249. 8 J. Lexchin et al., 2003, Pharmaceutical Industry Sponsorship and Research Outcome and Quality: Systematic Review,, British Medical Journal ? 1–10. 9 J. Bekelman et al., 2003, Scope and Impact of Financial Conflicts of Interest in Biomedical Research,” Journal of the American Medical Association ??: 454–465. 10 REGULATION (EC) No 726/2004 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 31 March 2004, In laying down Community procedures for the authorisation and supervision of medicinal products for human and veterinary use and establishing a European Medicines Agency: Section 34]. 11 Grubert, N. 2003. The National Institute for Clinical Excellence (NICE): A Review of Its Performance and Its Significance for the Pharmaceutical Industry, Decision Resources, Waltham, MA. www.dresources.com/stellentgroups/public/documents/pdf/dr_004637.pdf, last accessed 12 July 2004. 12 J. Santa, 2002, The Evidence Based Process Applied to Prescription Drugs in Oregon, available at www.statecoverage.net/pdf/santa2.pdf , last accessed 2 Juy 2004. 13 Veenstra DL, Ramsey SD, Sullivan SD, 2002. A guideline for the use of pharmacoeconomic models of diabetes in the US managed care environment. Pharmacoeconomics. 20 Suppl 1:21-30. 14 M. Giffin and R. Awwaad, 2001. The Impact of Studies Funded underOutcomes of Pharmaceutical Outcomes Research: Final Report, Pub. no. 02-R201, available at www.ahrq.gov/clinic/pharmimp. 15 8.4-15 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials Criteria and Procedures for making Medical Service Coverage Decisions that relate to Health Care Technology, 54 Fed. Reg. 4302 (30th January, 1989). 16 Notice of Rulemaking: Procedures for Making National Coverage Decisions, 64 Fed. Reg. 22619 (27th April,1999). 17 18 HR 2356 IH 108th CONGRESS 1st Session H. R. 2356 19 Medicaire Prescription Drug Modernization and Improvement Act, Pub. L. No. 108-173, § 1013, (2003). ALLHAT Officers and Coordinators for the ALLHAT Collaborative Research Group 2002. Major Outcomes in High-Risk Hypertensive Patients Randomized to Angiotensin-Converting Enzyme Inhibitor or Calcium Channel Blocker vs Diuretic: The Antihypertensive and Lipid-Lowering Treatment to Prevent Health Attack Trial (ALLHAT). Journal of the American Medical Association 288: 2981-2997. 20 Cookson, R., The Role of Industry in Evaluation of Health Interventions, ASTEC Report, Chapter 3, : 120, available at 21 Tufts CSDD, 2001. Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development Pegs Cost of a New Prescription Medicine at $802 Million. Press Release Boston, MA: Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development. 22 Hensley, Scott, 2003. More Drug-Comparison Studies Could Aid Patients’ Pocketbooks. Wall Street Journal Online (January 8). See also 23 Graham, John R. 2002. The Fantasy of Reference Pricing and the Promise of Choice in BC’s Pharmacare. Public Policy Source No.66. Vancouver, BC: The Fraser Institute 24 U.E. Reinhardt, 2004, An Information Infrastructure for the Pharmaceutical Market, Health Affairs (Jan/Feb 2004): 107–112. 25 U.E. Reinhardt, 2001, Perspectives on the Pharmaceutical Industry, Health Affairs (Sep/Oct 2001): 136– 149. 26 Coalition for Health Services Research, 2003, Federal Funding for Health Services Research Programs, available at www.chsr.org/fundingchart.htm, last accessed 1 July 2004. 27 Foundation Center Statistical Services, 2003, Distribution of Foundation Grants by Subject Categories, circa 2001,available at fdncenter. org/fc_stats/pdf/04_fund_sub/2001/10_01.pdf. 28 Electronic Prescribing: Towards Maximum Value and Rapid Adoption,, 2004, eHealth Initiative, report at http://www.ehealthinitiative.org/initiatives/erx/document.aspx, last accessed 2 July 2004. 29 Turner, MJ. 2002. Tipping the Balance of Power With Digital Patient Information, PharmaExec, at http://www.pharmexec.com/pharmexec/article, last accessed 3 July 2004. 30 COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE 31 8.4-16 Chapter 8.4: Comparative Effectiveness of Medicines and Use of Head-toHead Comparative Trials REGIONS, eEurope 2005: An information society for all, available at http://europa.eu.int/information_society/eeurope/2002/news_library/documents/eeurope2005/eeurope200 5_en.pdf, last accessed 2 July 2004. 8.4-17