On the Determinants of Global Bilateral Migration Flows Jesus Crespo Cuaresma∗+ , Mathias Moser∗ , Anna Raggl∗+ ∗ + WU - Vienna University of Economics and Business WiC - Wittgenstein Centre for Demography and Global Human Capital Antwerp, June 27th, 2013 1 / 26 Introduction Introduction Little is known about the determinants of global bilateral migration flows, as no complete database exists We aim at assessing the determinants of global bilateral migration flows I I We use the fact that net migration flows are the difference between aggregated immigration and aggregated emigration flows We construct a statistical model that relates the determinants of bilateral flows to net migration flows As common in the literature, an (extended) gravity model is used to model the (non-extisting) migration flows 2 / 26 Gravity The Gravity Model I Relates the flows of goods or factors between two countries to their attractive mass and to the distance between them Origins in Ravenstein (1885, 1889) I I “. . . the bulk of migrants ought to travel short distances only . . . ” “. . . increase in the means of locomotion and a development of manufactures and commerce have led to an increase of migration . . . ” Tinbergen (1962): first application to model trade flows between 2 countries i and j, tij GDPi GDPj tij = f dij where GDPi GDPj represents the gravitational mass and dij the distance between the two countries 3 / 26 Gravity The Gravity Model II Most general form for application to migration flows (Vanderkamp, 1977) αPOPiβ1 POPjβ2 mij = dijβ3 in logs log mij = α + β1 log POPi + β2 log POPj + β3 log dij In most applications, income per capita, common language, colonial history and other covariates are included in the estimation 4 / 26 Literature Literature - Determinants of Migration Flows/Stocks I Gravity models for limited samples Gravity model for immigration to US (Clark, Hatton, and Williamson, 2007) Assessment of bilateral migration flows to US and Canada (Karemera, Oguledo, and Davis, 2000) Determinants of flows to OECD countries (Pedersen, Pytlikova, and Smith, 2008; Kim and Cohen, 2010; Mayda, 2010; Beine, Docquier, and Ozden, 2011; Ortega and Peri, 2013) Determinants of stocks in OECD countries (Peri, 2005; Grogger and Hanson, 2011) 5 / 26 Literature Literature - Determinants of Migration Flows/Stocks II Lessons learned: Standard gravity variables have expected effects Policy changes influence level and source country composition of migrants Income relative to education Political stability and individual freedom in source countries increase immigration to US Network effects of particular importance Non-linearities in source country income Evidence for positive selection and positive sorting 6 / 26 Literature Literature - Determinants of Net Migration I Explaining net migration rates (Hatton and Williamson, 2003b,a) Age distribution appears to matter Wage differentials are important, negative effect of GDP growth in home country on emigration rates Stock of migrants increases immigration Reaction to civil wars visible Poverty constraint 7 / 26 Literature Literature “South-south” migration is ignored in all previous papers Direction of migration (% of global migrant stock) Definition S-S N-S N-N S-N Development Status Income Level UNDP HDI 33% 42% 45% 7% 4% 4% 26% 16% 14% 34% 39% 37% Table: Proportion of global migration across “South” and “North” (Bakewell, 2009) 8 / 26 Literature Literature - Estimating Bilateral Migration Flows Abel (2013) derives bilateral migration flows between 191 countries from sequential stock tables Bayesian methods based on Poisson specifications Sparsely specified models, based on distance 9 / 26 Methodology From Bilateral Flows to Net Migration: Specification I Assume that (log) bilateral migration flows between country i and country j are given by mij = log Mij = Xij β + uij (1) Bilateral flows are not observed, but data exist on net migration (Ni ), which is given by the difference of migration flows to country i from all other countries and migration out of country i to all other countries, X X X X Ni = Mi∗ − M∗i = Mij − Mji = exp mij − exp mji . (2) j6=i j6=i j6=i j6=i 10 / 26 Methodology From Bilateral Flows to Net Migration: Specification II In matrix form, N = f (m) = (In ⊗ ιn ) exp [Xβ + u] − B exp [Xβ + u] = S exp [Xβ + u] , {z } | {z } | sum of immigrants sum of emigrants (3) where S = (In ⊗ ιn ) − B Approximating S exp [Xβ + u] by S exp [Xβ] + u, (pseudo-)maximum likelihood estimation can be used to estimate the parameters of the model 11 / 26 Results Results - Simulation I A Monte Carlo exercise Simulate bilateral matrices Xij and add white noise for different levels of e.g. R 2 Generate the (unknown) bilateral migration flows Mij from a model and calculate net migration flows Ni Estimate M using N and X as regressors by Maximum Likelihood Simulation of 3 regressors + intercept, 100 countries and 6 levels of noise y = α + 0.1X1 + 0.5X2 − 0.5X3 + u where u ∼ N(0, σ 2 ) and X ∼ N(0, 1) for different values of σ 2 corresponding to alternative noise-to-signal ratios 12 / 26 Results Results - Simulation II Table: ML results for simulated migration data, 1000 replicates R2 = 0.95 0.90 0.85 0.80 0.75 0.70 β0 (1.0) RMSE Mean 0.082 1.01 0.121 1.02 0.156 1.02 0.215 1.04 8.922 0.65 12.748 0.11 β1 (0.1) RMSE Mean 0.017 0.10 0.027 0.10 0.036 0.10 0.041 0.10 0.083 0.10 0.970 0.06 β2 (−0.5) RMSE Mean 0.027 -0.50 0.039 -0.50 0.050 -0.50 0.067 -0.51 0.863 -0.55 1.970 -0.63 β3 (0.5) RMSE Mean 0.026 0.50 0.039 0.50 0.050 0.51 0.066 0.51 1.659 0.57 2.180 0.64 13 / 26 Results Results - Empirics I Net migration for 172 countries (29929 obs) Covariates I I I log per capita GDP and log population of source and destination countries distance, common border, colonial history and common language dummies migration stocks in destination countries Origin and destination dummies for 21 regions Estimated using Maximum Likelihood 14 / 26 Results Results - Empirics II ln(distance) × Origin North × Origin South ln(gdp pc destination) × Origin North × Origin South ln(gdp pc origin) × Origin North × Origin South ln(pop destination) × Origin North × Origin South ln(pop origin) × Origin North × Origin South contiguity colony × Origin North × Origin South common language share migration stock × Origin North × Origin South South Origin log likelihood -0.7271∗∗∗ 0.4335∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ -0.3332 0.6433 ∗∗∗ 0.5544∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ 1.1478 2.6209∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ 0.3484 0.0969∗∗∗ -144381.1 [0.0765] [0.0922] [0.0399] [0.0443] [0.0307] [0.2325] [0.1309] [0.0652] [0.0023] -0.3809∗∗∗ -0.6495∗∗∗ [0.0520] [0.0465] 1.5736∗∗∗ 0.6241∗∗∗ [0.2583] [0.0718] 0.6749∗∗∗ -0.0414 [0.1166] [0.0771] 1.0799∗∗∗ 0.8178∗∗∗ [0.0962] [0.0457] 0.7322∗∗∗ 0.6451∗∗∗ 1.7603∗∗∗ [0.0618] [0.0232] [0.1493] 3.5571∗∗∗ 0.8475∗∗∗ 0.2949∗∗∗ [0.2153] [0.1670] [0.0984] 0.0040 0.0950∗∗∗ 0.8562∗∗∗ [0.0115] [0.0027] [0.2995] -137685.2821 15 / 26 Results Results - Empirics III (1) ln(distance) × Origin North × Origin South × North-North × North-South × South-North × South-South ln(gdp pc destination) × Origin North × Origin South × North-North × North-South × South-North × South-South ln(gdp pc × Origin) × Origin North × Origin South × North-North × North-South × South-North × South-South ... -0.7271∗∗∗ 0.4335∗∗∗ -0.3332∗∗∗ (2) [0.0765] [0.0922] [0.0399] -0.3809∗∗∗ -0.6495∗∗∗ 1.5736∗∗∗ 0.6241∗∗∗ 0.6749∗∗∗ -0.0414 (3) [0.0520] [0.0465] [0.2583] [0.0718] [0.1166] [0.0771] -0.5469∗∗∗ -0.2397∗∗ -0.7564∗∗∗ -0.6625∗∗∗ [0.0916] [0.1150] [0.0883] [0.0950] 0.7552∗∗∗ -1.6009∗∗∗ 0.4820∗∗ 1.7540∗∗∗ [0.1653] [0.2442] [0.2014] [0.3417] 1.1179∗∗∗ -5.6341∗∗∗ -0.3907∗∗ -0.1738 [0.1427] [1.2347] [0.1588] [0.3713] 16 / 26 Results Results - Empirics IV (1) ... contiguity colony × Origin North × Origin South × North-North × North-South × South-North × South-South common language share migration stock × Origin North × Origin South × North-North × North-South × South-North × South-South 1.1478∗∗∗ 2.6209∗∗∗ 0.3484∗∗∗ 0.0969∗∗∗ (2) [0.2325] [0.1309] [0.0652] [0.0023] (3) 1.7603∗∗∗ [0.1493] 3.5571∗∗∗ 0.8475∗∗∗ [0.2153] [0.1670] 0.2949∗∗∗ [0.0984] 0.0040 0.0950∗∗∗ [0.0115] [0.0027] 1.2658∗∗∗ [0.2550] 3.5113∗∗∗ -11.6176 2.8741∗∗∗ 0.1576 0.3125∗ [0.2718] [610912] [0.2608] [0.4067] [0.1808] 0.0307∗∗∗ 0.0356 0.1000∗∗∗ -0.3835 [0.0078] [0.0916] [0.0055] [0.2967] 17 / 26 Results 600 800 Results - Empirics V predicted net migration 400 200 USA ESP 0 -200 ITA RUS THA CAN GBR FRA ARE DEU AUS ZAF PRT MYS TUR HKG GRC SGP SVN BDI HRV MDV NZL TMP BWA IRN BTN NLD AUT SAU BIH ROM HUN BEL MKD LSO ALB SWZ JPN OMN COM ISR MLT LBR LBY SWE BLR SLE EST KOR LVA KWT CHE QAT GUY DNK LTU NOR LBN IRQ BHR SYR BGR DJI CYP YEM ARM JOR IRL MNG ISL S SUR UR GEO FIN SVK VUT SLB TON LUX COG FJI ARG CPV GMB GNB GNQ MUS VCT GRD CAF GAB RWA LCA AGO ERI WSM CMR MDA BLZ CZE FSM TCD SLV MWI MRT ECU TGO PNG BRB ZAR LKA MDG CRI BEN JAM GIN MOZ HTI TTO PRY ZMB MLI CHL SEN BHS AZE URY BOL NAM NER CIV BFA VEN GHA U UGA GA BRN KEN TZA HND LAO DOM GTM POL TUN ETH PAN DZA KAZ UKR COL NGA KGZ TJK EGY NIC TKM TKM PER KHM SDN NPL BRA VNM MAR UZB MMR PHL IDN BGD MAC CHN PAK IND MEX -200 0 200 400 actual net migration 600 800 18 / 26 Results 400 Results - Empirics VI predicted net migration -200 0 200 ESP ITA RUS MAC THA CAN GBR FRA ARE DEU AUS ZAF PRT MYS TUR HKG GRC SGP SVN BDISLE HRV MDV NZL TMP BWA IRN BTN NLD AUT BIH ROM HUN BEL MKD LSO ALB SWZ JPN OMN ISR COM MLT LBR LBY SWE BLR EST KOR LVA KWT CHE QAT GUY DNK LTU LBN NOR IRQ BHR BGR DJI CYP YEM JOR ARM IRL MNG ISL SUR GEO FIN SVK VUT SLB TON LUX COG FJI ARG CPV GMB GNB GNQ MUS VCT GRD CAF GAB RWA LCA AGO ERISYR WSM CMR MDA BLZ CZE FSM TCD SLV MWI MRT ECU TGO PNG BRB ZAR LKA MDG CRI BEN JAM GIN MOZ TTO HTI PRY ZMB MLI CHL SEN BHS AZE URY BOL NER NAM CIV BFA VEN GHA UGA BRN KEN TZA HND LAO DOM GTM POL TUN ETH PAN DZA KAZ UKR COL NGA KGZ TJK EGY NIC TKM PER KHM SDN NPL BRA VNM MAR UZB MMR PHL BGDIDN CHN SAU PAK IND -400 MEX -400 -200 0 actual net migration 200 400 19 / 26 Projections Projecting Migration Flows I Lutz and KC (2013) and Crespo Cuaresma (2013) provide internally consistent projections of population and GDP for 150 countries up to the year 2100 We use median scenario projections to obtain estimates of the migration flows for the coming decades How is the distribution of migration flows to Europe expected to change? 20 / 26 Projections 1 Projecting Migration Flows II -.5 Change in immigration to EU 0 .5 BRN KWT BHR ISR SAU NER BFA TGO BEN GAB OMN MDG UGA TZA SEN MWI IRL DJI LBY CIV BHS TCD COM USA GNB MRT SGP CAF GHA CAN MYS COG CYPAUS GNQ MUS CMR MDV PRY CRI SYR NZL SLB BRB RWA NOR SWZ TUR BDI LBR HKG MLI PAK GMB JOR GTM DZA FIN HNDBOL ETHERI GIN PAN BLZ VENMEX ZMBKEN COL NGA PHL CHE IRQ EGY DNK LUX DEU CHL TTO ISL GRD BWA AUT NPLLSOSDN NIC LKAVUT ECU ZAF SLE LCA NLD KOR ESP ARG IRN FRA JPN MAR TUNBRA GBR DOM MOZ BGD MLT SVN PER LBN PRT SWE SLV BEL NAM URY MNG EST ITA CPV VCT LAO CZE YEMBTN FJI PNG HTI GRC MKD JAM HUN GUY TON THA HRV KAZ SUR LTU SVK BGR RUS LVA IND ROM ZAR IDN BLR KHM VNM POL TKMWSM BIH AZE UKR UZB CHN KGZ ARM GEO TJK MDA 6 7 8 9 log(GDP per capita) in 2000 10 11 21 / 26 Projections Projecting Migration Flows III The expected demographic and economic long-term developments imply, ceteris paribus, an increase of migration flows to Europe in the coming decades a significant relative increase of migration flows from lower income countries a stabilization of international migration flows within European economies 22 / 26 Conclusions Conclusions On a global level: no bilateral migration flows available Bilateral migration data can be reconstructed from net migration using a non-linear model Extended gravity model applies using distance, GDP per capita, population, common language and borders, colonial history I I I Distance seems to be greatest obstacle for migrants originating in the south GDP per capita in destination country acts as important pull-factor, effect highest for south-north migration Network effects visible, in particular for south-north migration Projections of immigration flows to the EU suggest that overall immigration flow will increase 23 / 26 References References I Abel, G. J. (2013): “Estimating Global Migration Flow Tables Using Place of Birth Data,” Demographic Research, 28(18), 505–546. Bakewell, O. (2009): “South-South Migration and Human Development: Reflections on African Experiences,” Human Development Reports Research Paper 2009/07, United Nations Development Programme. Beine, M., F. Docquier, and C. Ozden (2011): “Diasporas,” Journal of Development Economics, 95(1), 30–41. Clark, X., T. J. Hatton, and J. G. Williamson (2007): “Explaining U.S. Immigration, 1971-1998,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(2), 359–373. Grogger, J., and G. H. Hanson (2011): “Income maximization and the selection and sorting of international migrants,” Journal of Development Economics, 95(1), 42–57. Hatton, T. J., and J. G. Williamson (2003a): “Demographic and Economic Pressure on Emigration out of Africa*,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 105(3), 465–486. 24 / 26 References References II (2003b): “What Fundamentals Drive World Migration?,” Working Papers UNU-WIDER Research Paper 23, World Institute for Development Economic Research (UNU-WIDER). Karemera, D., V. I. Oguledo, and B. Davis (2000): “A gravity model analysis of international migration to North America,” Applied Economics, 32(13), 1745–1755. Kim, K., and J. E. Cohen (2010): “Determinants of International Migration Flows to and from Industrialized Countries: A Panel Data Approach Beyond Gravity1,” International Migration Review, 44(4), 899–932. Mayda, A. M. (2010): “International migration: a panel data analysis of the determinants of bilateral flows,” Journal of Population Economics, 23, 1249–1274. Ortega, F., and G. Peri (2013): “The Effect of Income and Immigration Policies on International Migration,” Migration Studies, 1(1), 47–74. Pedersen, P. J., M. Pytlikova, and N. Smith (2008): “Selection and Network Effects. Migration flows into OECD countries 1990–2000,” European Economic Review, 52(7), 1160 – 1186. 25 / 26 References References III Peri, G. (2005): “International Migrations: Some Comparisons and Lessons for the European Union,” Working Papers 06-36, University of California at Davis, Department of Economics. Ravenstein, E. G. (1885): “The Laws of Migration,” Journal of the Statistical Society of London, 48(2), pp. 167–235. (1889): “The Laws of Migration,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 52(2), pp. 241–305. Tinbergen, J. (1962): Shaping the World Economy; Suggestions for an International Economic Policy. Twentieth Century Fund, New York. Vanderkamp, J. (1977): “The Gravity Model and Migration Behaviour: An Economic Interpretation,” Journal of Economic Studies, 4(2), 89–102. 26 / 26