Today: Determining what a public good is; Efficient provision; Public versus private provision; Defining externalities
Beginning Unit 2
Last time
We concluded our “tools” chapters
End of Unit 1
Today
Begin Unit 2
Public goods (Chapter 4)
What is a public good?
Efficient provision
Public versus private provision
An introduction to externalities (Chapter 5)
Public goods
Public goods are goods that have some degree of two characteristics
Nonrival
Nonexcludable
These two characteristics lead to suboptimal consumption when public goods are privately purchased
Externalities involved, to be defined later
Definitions
Nonrival good (R/G p. 52)
“Once it is provided, the additional resource cost of another person consuming the good is zero”
Nonexcludable good (R/G p.
52)
“To prevent anyone from consuming the good is either very expensive or impossible”
Pure public good
(R/G p. 52)
“A commodity that is nonrival and nonexcludable in consumption”
Categories of goods
Nonrival
Low High
High
Low
Commons good
(oxygen that you breathe)
Private good
(pens)
Public good
(lighthouses)
Collective good
(copyrighted books)
Categories of goods
Nonrival
Low High
High
Low
Commons good
(oxygen that you breathe)
Private good
(pens)
Public good
(lighthouses)
Collective good
(copyrighted books)
Covered in Econ 1; uses basic supply/demand theory
Categories of goods
Nonrival
Low High
High
Low
Commons good
(oxygen that you breathe)
Private good
(pens)
Public good
(lighthouses)
Collective good
(copyrighted books)
Often covered in Econ 1 or Econ 100B
Categories of goods
Nonrival
Low High
High
Low
Commons good
(oxygen that you breathe)
Private good
(pens)
Public good
(lighthouses)
Collective good
(copyrighted books)
Goods with copyright or patent protection have some level of market power
Other examples of public goods
Basic research
Programs to fight poverty
Uncongested nontoll roads
Fireworks display
Noteworthy aspects of public goods
Even though everyone consumes the same quantity of the good, it need not be valued equally by all
Surfers generally value ocean quality more than people living in Utah
Classification as a public good is not absolute; it depends on market conditions and the state of technology
Impure public goods are “rival and/or excludable to some extent” (R/G p. 53)
Noteworthy aspects of public goods
Some things that are not conventionally thought of as commodities have public good characteristics
Restaurant ratings
Consistent within a city
Often different standards between cities
Example: It appears harder to get an “A” rating in Los
Angeles County restaurants than in San Diego County
Noteworthy aspects of public goods
Private goods are not necessarily provided exclusively by the private sector
Publicly provided private goods
Example: Government-provided food for the poor
Public provision of a good does not necessarily mean that it is also produced by the public sector
Many publicly-provided services are contracted to private firms
Example: Defense-related goods
Demand of private goods
Demand of private goods are summed horizontally
Add the quantity demanded for each person at a given price
Efficient Provision of Private Goods
Price Adam
(D f
A )
$11 5
$9 7
$7
$5
$3
$1
9
11
13
15
5
7
9
11
Eve
(D f
A )
1
3
Market
(D f
A+E )
6
10
14
18
22
26
$
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
S f
5
4
3
D f
A+E
2
0
1
D f
E
D f
A
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26
Quantity of Pizza
Equilibrium and efficiency, private goods
Privately-provided goods have optimal levels produced if the following conditions are met:
The goods are private
Rival and excludable
Competitive markets
No market power exists
Price and quantity are where demand and supply curves meet
Recall First Welfare Theorem
MRS fa
Adam = MRS fa
Eve = MRT fa
Public goods
We will examine pure public goods
Highly nonrival
Highly nonexcludable
Marginal analysis is used to find the optimal quantity
Optimal quantity is where PUBLIC MB equals MC
Units of Fireworks
1 2 3 4
Adam (D f
A ) $300 $250 $200 $150
Eve (D f
E )
Market
(D f
A+E )
250
$550
200
$450
150
$350
100
$250
650
600
550
500
450
$
800
750
700
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
1 2
S f
D f
A+E
D f
A
D f
E
3
Quantity of Fireworks
4
Pareto efficiency: Public goods case
MRS fa
Set P a
= P f
/ P a
= $1 MRS fa
= P f
/ 1 MRS fa
= P f
D f
A shows MRS fa for Adam
D f
E shows MRS fa for Eve
S f shows MRT fa
Necessary condition for Pareto efficiency:
MRS fa
Adam + MRS fa
Eve = MRT fa
Another example
Fireworks show off of a tiny coastal community
25 people live here
Each person has the same private demand for fireworks
P = 2 – 0.08 Q
MC for fireworks is 10
Notice that if fireworks were privately purchased, nobody would buy them ( 10 > 2 )
Fireworks show as a public good
Since one person’s enjoyment of fireworks does not take away from the enjoyment from others, PUBLIC MB is the sum of PRIVATE
MBs
PUBLIC MB is the vertical summation of all
25 PRIVATE MBs
P = 25 ( 2 – 0.08 Q) = 50 – 2Q
Vertical summation
Vertical summation of
25 PRIVATE
MB lines produces
PUBLIC MB line
Vertical intercept is 50
PUBLIC
MB
PRIVATE MB
MC
Marginal analysis
To find efficient level of fireworks, set PUBLIC
MB = MC
50 – 2Q = 10
Q = 20
Free rider problem
When public goods are provided privately, some people let others buy the good for their own enjoyment
These people are known as free riders
Perfect price discrimination can solve the free rider problem
Usually cannot be done, since it requires knowledge of each person’s demand curve for the public good
Do people free ride?
Public goods games
Inefficient results predicted
Experimental economics tests free rider theories
A public goods game
You can decide whether or not you want to contribute to a new flower garden at a local park
If you decide Yes, you will lose $200, but every person in the city you live in will gain $10 in benefits from the park
If you decide No, you will cause no change to the outcome of you or other people
A public goods game
What is each person’s best response, given the decision of others?
We need to look at each person’s marginal gain and loss (if any)
Choose yes Gain $10, lose $200
Choose no Gain $0, lose $0
A public goods game
Which is the better choice?
Choose no (Gain nothing vs. net loss of $190)
Nash equilibrium has everybody choosing no
Efficient outcome has everybody choosing yes
Why the difference?
Each person does not account for others’ benefits when making their own decision
Experimental economics
Experiments are conducted approximately as follows
A group of people meet in a classroom
Each person is offered money (or the equivalent of money)
Each person has the opportunity to donate money to a fund
There is a “money multiplier”
Money (after multiplied) gets distributed equally to everyone in the classroom
Public goods experiments
Typical results of public goods experiments
People contribute about 50% of resources to provision of public good
Contributions fall the more often the game is repeated
More cooperation with prior communication
Contribution rates decline when opportunity cost of giving goes up
“Warm-glow” giving
Some people may feel good by improving social welfare
Public versus private provision of a good
Although public goods are often publicly financed, there is often debate as to whether or not the public sector should also provide the good
There are a few criteria that help to determine provision
Relative wage and materials costs
Administrative costs
Diversity of tastes
Commodity egalitarianism
Provision criteria
Relative wage and materials costs
Public sector workers are often unionized more, leading to higher costs in the private sector
Administrative costs
Often lower if service provided by public sector
Provision criteria
Diversity of tastes
Private provision often means more options to the consumer
Distributional issues
Is there a minimum amount of schooling and health care that should be provided to everyone?
Up to personal preference and debate
Public/private provision debate
Change of provision between public and private sectors
Heavily debated in some cases
Some issues
Uncertainty
Responsibility of fulfilling services
Quality of good or service
Incomplete contracts in some private sector services
Example: All contingencies for security
Consumer satisfaction within a market
Private provision of national defense
Example: Substantial amounts of money are spent on national defense
9.3% of GDP in 1962 (Cold War era)
3.4% of GDP in 1997
Many goods and services related to national defense are privately provided
The type of contract could lead to substantial changes in cost to government
Private provision of national defense
Big private contracts to provide national defense involve substantial risk
Cost of cutting-edge technology is very uncertain
Fixed price contracts leave all the risk on the firm
Winner’s curse
Cost-plus contracts often lead to substantial cost overruns
No incentives to keep costs down
What else can be used?
Incentive contracts
Incentive contracts
Incentive contracts incorporate aspects of fixed price and cost-plus contracts
Department of Defense pays a fixed fee plus a fraction of production costs
TC = F + λ C
When 0 < λ < 1…
There is an economic incentive to the firm to prevent cost overruns
The firm bears less risk than with fixed price contracts
Special cases
λ = 0 Fixed price contract
λ = 1 and F = 0 Cost-plus contract
Who decides how much to provide?
Somebody in government must make decisions about public goods
More on decision making in Chapter 6
Political economy
Summary: Public goods
Public goods are nonrival and nonexcludable in consumption
Demand of public goods uses vertical summation
Free rider problem predicts suboptimal quantities purchased
Mixed evidence from experimental economics
Ongoing debate between public and private provision of public goods
An introduction to externalities
Markets are well functioning for most private goods
Many buyers and sellers
Little or no market power by anybody
Example: When demand shifts right for a good, new equilibrium will have higher price and quantity
Some markets do not have good mechanisms to account for everything in a market
Example: Talking on a cell phone in an airplane
Externalities
Externalities are effects that are not incorporated into market quantities and prices
R/G (p.71) define an externality as “an activity of one entity that affects the welfare of another entity in a way that is outside the market mechanism”
When markets have externalities, they are typically not efficient
This is the topic of Chapter 5
Public good versus externality
Although public goods are often looked at as goods with externalities, we study the two topics separately
Know which analysis applies when you solve a problem
Negative externalities
Some examples of negative externalities
Air pollution
Water pollution
Sometimes you do not even think about polluting the water: Washing a car in your driveway
Noise pollution
Highway congestion
Standing at a concert or sporting event
Positive externalities
Some externalities are benefits
Planting flowers in your front lawn
Scientific research
Vaccination
Prevents others from getting a disease from you
Exercise?
Yes, if it leads to lower health care insurance premiums for others
More on the private health care market in Chapter 9
More externalities: Benefit or cost?
Christmas decorations
Enjoyment or nuisance?
A fan blowing in a warm office building
Cooling breeze or blowing your important papers?
Use of perfume or cologne
Nice smell or allergen?
A simple example with externalities
Suppose private MC equals quantity
MPC = Q
Let demand be denoted by P = 100 – Q
Let marginal damage be $10 per unit
A simple example with externalities
MSC = Q + 10
MPC = Q marginal damage per unit of $10
P = 100 – Q
Translate equations and external cost to our graphical example
A simple example: Private equilibrium
MPC = Q
P = 100 – Q
Inefficient equilibrium w/o controls:
Set Q = 100 – Q Q = 50 (quantity F )
A simple example: Optimal equilibrium
MSC = Q + 10
Socially optimal quantity
Q + 10 = 100 – Q Q = 45 (quantity E )
P = 100 – Q
An algebraic example: Price
MSC = Q + 10
MPC = Q
Price B = 55
Price C = 50 marginal damage per unit of $10
Recall E = 45 and F = 50
P = 100 – Q
Inefficient equilibrium, P = Q P = 50
Socially optimal quantity, P = Q + 10 P = 55
Summary: An introduction to externalities
Externalities can be positive or negative
Sometimes, an action could lead to positive externalities for some people and negative externalities for others
With external damages, an equilibrium occurs that has too much produced and price too low
(relative to the optimal quantity)