Dr Debbie Pearmain ALIGNING HEALTH LEGISLATION IN PURSUIT OF UNIVERSAL COVERAGE WHAT IS UNIVERSAL COVERAGE? Presenter logo to come here • The goal of universal health coverage is to ensure that all people obtain the health services they need without suffering financial hardship when paying for them. -WHO Oct.2012 • To achieve universal coverage, countries must advance in at least three dimensions. They must expand priority services, include more people and reduce out-of-pocket payments. -WHO Universal Coverage • There is no single path or magic bullet to achieve universal health coverage: each country needs to devise its own route to achieve this goal • There is substantial scope to raise further domestic resources for health care, particularly through innovative approaches to financing. • 20%–40% of health care expenditure is wasted; improved health system efficiency can make a substantial contribution to the achievement of universal health coverage. • All countries, but particularly poorer ones, need to reduce reliance on direct, out-of-pocket payments for health care by increasing risk pooling and prepayment for services. - World Health Report 2010 Progress towards universal health SOME INTERESTING FACTS • In Brazil, China, India, the Russian Federation and South Africa, (BRICS) private financing accounts for 54%, 44%, 69%, 40% and 52% of total health spending, respectively⃰ • In comparison with other countries with similar income levels, government spending on health as a proportion of gross domestic product is relatively low in China (2.9%), India (1.0%) and the Russian Federation (3.7%), but it is higher in Brazil (4.3%) and South Africa (4.1%)⃰ ⃰R ao, Petrosyan, Araujo and McIntyre: “Progress Towards Universal Health Coverage in BRICS” The South African Position • “In South Africa costly private healthcare for the privileged few provides for 16% of the population” • The remaining 84% has to make do with “second rate care” • “National Health Insurance” should be approached as “universal health coverage” • “Unless there is good quality in public healthcare, and unless the costs are brought down in private health care, this whole concept of universal health care will never find leverage in our country” - Motsoaledi, New Age 12-09-2013 The Medical Schemes Act • The Prescribed Minimum Benefits Package favours a high cost, hospicentric approach to health care • The emphasis on severity in PMBs means that the regulations are in direct contrast to the government’s primary health care approach and ensures high cost curative medical care rather than preventive health care • The use of DTPs in the PMB regulations means that some who are sick are arbitrarily excluded from so-called “basic cover” by medical schemes Medical Schemes Act • PMBs should be service oriented not diagnosis based • PMBs should make provision for primary health care services and not catastrophic cover • PMBs should be structured in such a way as to emphasise health outcomes based on recognised health indicators amongst medical scheme population Medical Schemes Act • Allows too much complexity in benefit packages. The result is that beneficiaries do not know what they are entitled to in terms of health care. • Example: a benefit package was developed by the Mexican Ministry of Health, which selected procedures on the basis of cost-effectiveness, affordability, financial protection, opinion of the scientific community, demand and supply, and social acceptance - Kumar, et al ‘Pricing and Competition in Specialist Medical Services: An Overview for South Africa’, May 2014 OECD Medical Schemes Act • Membership of a medical scheme is voluntary • No provision for mandatory membership that would bring the young and healthy into the system • Members can resign once they have received anticipated benefits e.g. confinement or elective surgery • No limit on what medical schemes must pay for PMBs – unfunded liability National Health Act • S3(1)(d) obliges the Minister to ensure the provision of essential health care services which at least include primary health care services yet there is no legislation that ensures the provision of primary health care to beneficiaries of medical schemes • S4(3)(a)) recognises that every child has the right to basic health care services but expressly excludes children under the age of 6 who are beneficiaries of medical schemes from free health care services at public health establishments • S4(3)(b) excludes all persons, including children, who are beneficiaries of medical schemes from free primary health care services at public health establishments National Health Act • S4(3)(b) does require the State to provide all women with free termination of pregnancy services – even medical scheme beneficiaries • S74(1) The national department must facilitate and co-ordinate the establishment, implementation and maintenance by …the private health sector of health information systems… No regulations have been made. eg coding • S90(1)(u) the processes and procedures to be implemented by the Director-General to obtain prescribed information from stakeholders relating to health financing, the pricing of health services, business practices within or involving health establishments, and health care providers, and the formats and extent of publication of various types of information in the public interest and for the purpose of improving access to and the effective and efficient utilisation of health services; No regulations have been made eg coding Competition Law • S3(1)(e)- Competition Act does not apply to concerted conduct designed to achieve a non-commercial socioeconomic objective or similar purpose. • No collective bargaining within the private sector is allowed under the Competition Act. • Minister of Health has not used the provisions in the NHA s90(1)(v) to make regulations permitting the publication by the Director-General of benchmark pricing (reference price list) Competition Law • In most OECD countries the public sector tends to have some form of price setting for specialist medical services, this is used to purchase services from the private sector and can provide benchmarks for private insurers as well. • Regulation in OECD countries generally enables collective bargaining on hospital prices. Competition policy distinguishes between public insurers with a social purpose and private insurers, and allows co-ordination among providers under specific circumstances. • Developing credible prices and large increases in public spending have been common to OECD countries that have used private sector facilities to expand access to hospitals in recent years. - Kumar, et al ‘Pricing and Competition in Specialist Medical Services: An Overview for South Africa’, May 2014 OECD Competition Law • One of the means by which OECD countries have sought to address the difficult exercise of pricing medical services is by establishing independent technical agencies. These agencies are charged with developing a credible price schedule which seeks to group and then order services according to their complexity in a way that reflects a country‘s resource costs, clinical practices and patient needs - Kumar, et al ‘Pricing and Competition in Specialist Medical Services: An Overview for South Africa’, May 2014 OECD Medicines Pricing • SEP applies only in private sector • No regulation on how SEP is set and no official interrogation of SEP by independent experts • Vast differences in price between public and private sector on medicines pricing • Private funding sector is subsidizing public sector on medicines? Health Professions Council Rulings • Medical practitioners may not be employed in the private sector. Does not allow for the creation of HMO type organisations by medical schemes. • No mandatory referral system and gatekeepers within the private sector. Patients can see a medical specialist without first consulting a general practitioner • Discontinuity of care means inefficient care in private health sector Regulatory Failure • No independent, expert scrutiny of prices in the private health sector • No independent publication of information for the benefit of the consumer, medical schemes or private health care providers on pricing and quality issues. • No regulatory machinery for processes for determination of pricing by private providers • No transparency on pricing mechanisms and levels within private sector • No regulatory mechanisms to address information asymmetry Regulatory Failure • No attempt to address risk pooling issues eg Risk Equalisation • No attempt to address inefficiencies and duplication e.g. COIDA vs RAF vs CCOD vs public sector vs medical schemes. • No regulation on quality measurement in private health sector or that associates quality and price. Office of Health Standards Compliance likely to be of small effect in private sector. Dr D L Pearmain THANK YOU