Ch 10 International trade

advertisement

Chapter 10

International Trade I ---

The Law of Comparative

Advantage

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Contents:

The law of comparative advantage

Distribution of gains from trade

Graphical illustration of international trade

International trade – Reasons and hindrance

Advanced Materials 10.1 : Graphical illustration of international trade –

Increasing production cost

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

The Law of Comparative

Advantage

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Necessary conditions for international trade

Factors of production cannot be moved across national boundaries but goods can. Why?

Production costs of the trading parties are different.

Why?

The transportation and the transaction costs involved do not exhaust the gains from trade. Why?

Protectionist measures are not prohibitive. Why?

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Absolute advantage

A country is said to have an absolute advantage over another country in the production of a good if it can produce a larger amount of the good than the other country with the same amount of resources .

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Reciprocal absolute advantage

Two countries are said to have a reciprocal absolute advantage over each other if each country has an absolute advantage over the other in producing one of the two goods.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

The principle

Given that two countries have a reciprocal absolute advantage over each other, if each specializes in producing the good in which it has an absolute advantage, then the world’s total output will increase

.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Case I Food Clothing

Output of 1 unit of resources*

Country A 10 8

Country B 3 10

*1 unit of resources (a combination of labour, capital, and land)

Which country has an absolute advantage in the production of food ?

Country A

Which country has an absolute advantage in the production of clothing ?

Country B

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Specialization leads to increase in world’s output

If now country A shifts 1 unit of resources from the production of clothing to the production of food .

And country B shifts 1 unit of resources from the production of food to the production of clothing .

Food Clothing

Country A

Country B

World’s total output

10

8

3

10

+7 +2

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Case II Food Clothing

Output of 1 unit of resources*

Country A 100 80

Country B 3 10

*1 unit of resources ( a combination of labour, capital, and land)

Which country has an absolute advantage in the production of food ?

Country A

Which country has an absolute advantage in the production of clothing ?

Country A

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Comparative advantage

A country is said to have a comparative advantage over another country in the production of a good if it can produce the good at a lower opportunity cost than the other country.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

The law of comparative advantage

The law of comparative advantage or the law of comparative cost states that if each country specializes in the production of the good in which it has a comparative adv.

(or a lower production cost) , the world’s total output will increase

.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Country A

Country B

Output of 1 unit of resources

100F

3F

80C

10C

Country A

Country B

Production cost of 1F Production cost of 1C

80C

0.80C

100

10 C

3 .

33 C

3

100 F

1 .

25 F

80

3 F

0 .

30 F

10

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Specialization leads to an increase in world’s output

If country A produces one more unit of food while country B produces one more unit of clothing

Food Clothing

Country A +1.0F

-0.8C

Country B

World’s total output

-0.3F

+0.7F

+1.0C

+0.2C

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Absolute advantage versus comparative advantage

1. Abs. adv. and comp. adv. are unrelated .

Abs. adv. compares productivity of the two countries

(the amount of output obtained per unit of resources) .

Comp. adv. compares production costs of the two countries

(the amount of another good forgone per unit of output).

However, if two countries have a reciprocal absolute advantage over each other, each will have a comparative advantage in the production of the good that it has an absolute advantage.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

2. It is possible for a country to have an absolute advantage in the production of all goods , but it is impossible for the country to have a comparative advantage in all production .

3. It is the comparative advantage (not the absolute advantage) that determines the allocation of resources and the direction of trade .

However, comparative advantage does not determine the volume of trade , the terms of trade or the balance of trade .

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Q10.4:

For each of the following typical cases, determine

(a) which country has an absolute advantage in the production of

(i) food (ii) clothing

(b) which country has a comparative advantage in the production of

(i) food (ii) clothing

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Case 1:

Food

Clothing

Case 2:

Country A

Country B

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Output of 1 unit of resources

Country A Country B

8 10

2 6

Output of 1 unit of resources

Food Clothing

8 10

2 6

Case 3:

Country A

Country B

Case 4:

Country A

Country B

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Amount of resources for producing

1 unit of output

Food Clothing

8 10

2 6

Production cost of 1 unit of output

Food Clothing

$8

£2

$10

£6

Calculation of production costs

1. Given the amount of good X and good Y produced per unit of resources (marginal products), i.e., MP

X and MP

Y

:

Production cost of 1X is 

MP

Y

MP

X units of good Y

Production cost of 1Y is 

MP

X

MP

Y units of good X

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Calculation of production costs

2. Given the amount of resources required to produce one unit of good X and good Y (real marginal costs in terms of resources), i.e., MC

X and MC

Y

:

Production cost of 1X is 

MC

X

MC

Y units of good Y

Production cost of 1Y is

MC

Y

MC

X units of good X

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Calculation of production costs

3. Given the amount of money required to produce one unit of good X and good Y (nominal marginal costs in terms of money), i.e., MC

X and MC

Y

:

Production cost of 1X is 

MC

X

MC

Y units of good Y

Production cost of 1Y is

MC

Y

MC

X units of good X

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Distribution of

Gains from Trade

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Principle

Specialization raises the world’s total output, while trade distributes the output among trading parties .

The world price (or exchange ratio or terms of trade) of a good is determined by its D & S in the world market.

From the trading of a good, a country gains the difference between its production cost of the good and the good’s world price.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Illustration

Amount of labour required to produce a unit of food and clothing in country A and country B

Food Clothing

Country A

Country B

8 lab

10 lab

10 lab

3 lab

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Calculation of gains from trade

Production cost of 1F Production cost of 1C

Country A

Country B

8 lab

10 lab

10 lab

3.33C

3 lab

0.80C

10 lab

1.25F

8 lab

3 lab

0.30F

10 lab

Given exchange ratio: 1F=1C

World price of 1F ( =1C ) >

Country A’s production cost of 1F ( =0.8C

)

Country A exports food

From each unit of food exported, country A gains

0.2C

( =1C-0.8C

).

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Calculation of gains from trade

Production cost of 1F Production cost of 1C

Country A

Country B

8 lab

10 lab

10 lab

3.33C

3 lab

0.80C

10 lab

1.25F

8 lab

3 lab

0.30F

10 lab

Given exchange ratio: 1F=1C

World price of 1F ( =1C ) <

Country B’s production cost of 1F ( =3.33C

)

Country B imports food

From each unit of food imported, country B gains

2.33C

( =3.33C-1C ).

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Terms of trade

Terms of trade ( TOT ) is the ratio of a country’s export price (P

X

) to its import price

(P

M

).

P

X

TOT=

P

M

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Implications of the terms of trade

TOT

It measures the amount of import that a country can exchange with a unit of its export

An improvement (or deterioration) in the terms of trade reflects an increase (decrease) in the gain from trade per unit of export .

A change in the terms of trade has no implication on the amount of trade, the total gain from trade or the balance of trade . Why?

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Terms of trade index

The terms of trade index

= the unit value index for total exports the unit value index for imports measured in the same base period

The unit value index for total exports (or imports )

 is the weighted average of the export prices

(or the import prices).

 where the weight of a good is equal to the proportion of its value in the total value of exports (or the total value of imports).

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Q10.6

How will the terms of trade of Hong Kong be affected under the following situations?

(a) A rise in the price of foodstuff imported from the mainland.

(b) An improvement in the labour productivity in

Hong Kong.

(c) A rise in the exchange value of Japanese yen.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Graphical Illustration of

International Trade

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

A. Illustration with two separate diagrams – constant production cost

Given information:

Production possibility curves of countries A & B

Indifference maps of countries A & B

A price line with its slope representing the world price

(or the exchange ratio or the terms of trade) of good X in terms of good Y

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

1. The situation without trade (the autarkic situation)

- Without trade, a country is self-sufficient. It can consume what it can produce only, i.e., its production possibility curve

(PPC) = its consumption possibility curve (CPC).

- To maximize social welfare, the country’s consumption optimum ( CO ) is the tangency point of its PPC and the highest indifference curve achievable, which is also its production optimum ( PO ) under self-sufficiency.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Country A: The situation without trade

Clothing

1F

1 600

Slope = Cost of 1F

= 1 600C/2 000 = 0.8C

CO

A0

PO

A0

0

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

PPC

A0

= CPC

A0

Food

2 000

Country B

Clothing

1 500

1F

Slope = Cost of 1F

= 1 500C/450 = 3.33C

PO

B0

CO

B0

0

PPC

B0

= CPC

B0

450

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Food

2. The situation with trade

 From the PPCs, the amount of output of the two countries can be compared. However, without information on their amount of resources endowed, absolute advantage cannot be determined.

The slope of a PPC shows the marginal production cost of good

X in terms of good Y. On the other hand, its inverse shows the marginal production cost of good Y in terms of good X.

As PPC

A has a gentler slope than PPC

B

, country A has a lower cost in producing good X (food) while country B has a comparative advantage in producing good Y (clothing).

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

The world price is determined by demand & supply at which Q d of the importing country equals Q s of the exporting country.

With the existence of international market, a country can sell what it produces to buy what it wants to consume. This can be represented by a movement along the price line passing through the

PO.

To maximize wealth , the new PO is the point through which the outermost price line passes.

The outermost price line is the new CPC.

 To maximize social welfare , the CO is the point at which the new CPC touches the highest indifference curve achievable.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Clothing

2 000

1 600 

PPC

A 

0

Country A

---- Possible consumption possibility curves

---- Outermost consumption possibility curve

Complete specialization

PO

A

2 000

Food

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Country B

Clothing

1 500

PO

B

Complete specialization

---- Possible consumption

PPC

B possibility curves

---- Outermost consumption possibility curve

0

450

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

1 500

Food

Amount of trade

If PO > CO, the excess amount of the good is exported.

On the other hand, if PO < CO, the insufficient amount is imported.

 Country A’s export is country B’s import and vice versa.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Graphical illustration

Clothing

2 000

CPC

A

1 600

1 000

PPC

A

 CO

A

Country A

0

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Export

1 000 2 000

PO

A

Food

Graphical illustration

Clothing

1 500

PO

B

Country B

500

0

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Import

CO

B

450 1 000

CPC

B

Food

1 500

Illustration with a composite diagram –

Constant production cost

Clothing

F : Export of country A

= Import of country B

= 1 000 units of food

2 000

Countries A & B

CO

A

=CO

B

1 600

1 000

PPC

A

PPC

B

0 C : Export of country B

= Import of country A

= 1 000 units of clothing

C

0 1 000

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

F

2 000

PO

A

= PO

B

Food

Advanced Material 10.1

Graphical Illustration of

International Trade

– Increasing Production Cost

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

By production possibility curve and indifference curve

Without trade (the autarkic situation)

Clothing

Clothing

CO

A0

PO

A0

Country A Country B

MC

B0

MC

A0

CO

B0

PO

B0

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

With trade

Clothing

CO

A1

Import of country A

Export of country A

PO

A1

Country A

IC

A1

> IC

A0

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Clothing

Country B

Export of

PO

B1 country B

CO

B1

Import of country B

IC

B1

> IC

B0

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

International Trade

--- Reasons and Hindrance

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Reasons for international trade

1. Incapable of being self-sufficient

2. Difference in production costs

3. Economies of scale and learning by doing

4. A wider range of goods and services

5. Improvement in technology and productivity

6. Suppression of domestic monopoly

7. Price stability

8. Intangible benefits

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Hindrance to international trade

1. Transportation cost

2. Protectionism

3. Lack of a mutually acceptable exchange ratio

4. International tension

5. Internal instability

6. Fluctuations in exchange rate

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Correcting Misconceptions:

1. If a country has an absolute advantage in the production of good X, it will also have a comparative advantage in its production.

2. It is possible for a developed country to have an absolute advantage as well as a comparative advantage over a developing country in the production of all goods.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Correcting Misconceptions:

3. Comparative advantage determines the direction of trade, the terms of trade, the amount of trade as well as the balance of trade.

4. The terms of trade is the ratio of a country’s amount of import to its amount of export.

5. The terms of trade determines the gain from trade, the amount of trade as well as the balance of trade.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Correcting Misconceptions:

6. If the terms of trade of a country becomes more favourable, the country will be better off.

7. Trade enables a country to produce and consume beyond its production possibility curve.

8. Difference in opportunity cost is both the necessary and sufficient conditions for international trade.

© Pilot Publishing Company Ltd. 2005

Download