Chapter 19 Normal, Log-Normal Distribution, and Option Pricing Model By Cheng Few Lee Joseph Finnerty John Lee Alice C Lee Donald Wort Outline 2 • 19.1 The Normal Distribution • 19.2 The Log-Normal Distribution • 19.3 The Log-Normal Distribution and It’s Relationship to the Normal Distribution • 19.4 Multivariate Normal and Log-Normal Distributions • 19.5 The Normal Distribution as an Application to the Binomial and Poisson Distributions • 19.6 Applications of the Log-Normal Distribution in Option Pricing Outline 3 • 19.7 THE BIVARIATE NORMAL DENSITY FUNCTION • 19.8 AMERICAN CALL OPTIONS • 19.8.1 Price American Call Options by the Bivariate Normal Distribution • 19.8.2 Pricing an American Call Option: An Example • 19.9 PRICING BOUNDS FOR OPTIONS • 19.9.1 Options Written on Nondividend-Paying Stocks • 19.9.2 Option Written on Dividend-Paying Stocks 19.1 The Normal Distribution • A random variable X is said to be normally distributed with mean and variance 2if it has the probability density function (PDF) 1 x ( 1 f ( x) e 2 2 )2 0. (19.1) *Useful in approximation for binomial distribution and studying option pricing. 4 • Standard PDF of Z g ( z) X 1 2 is e z2 2 (19.2) • This is the PDF of the standard normal and is independent of the parameters 2 • and . 5 • Cumulative • • distribution function (CDF) of Z *In many cases, value P(Z z) N ( z) N(z) is provided by (19.3) software. • • CDF P( X x) P( X of X x ) N( x ). (19.4) 6 • When X is normally distributed then the Moment generating function (MGF) of X is M x (t ) e • *Useful 7 t t 2 2 2 (19.5) in deriving the moment of X and moments of log-normal distribution. 19.2 The Log-Normal Distribution • Normally of and distributed log-normality with parameters 2 • *X Y log X (19.6) 8 has to be a • positive random • variable. • *Useful in studying • the behavior of • stock prices. • PDF for log-normal distribution g ( x) 1 2 x e 1 2 2 (log x ) 2 , x 0. (19.7) • • 9 *It is sometimes called the antilog-normal distribution, because it is the distribution of the random variable X. *When applied to economic data, it is often called “CobbDouglas distribution”. • The rth moment of X is r E( X r ) E(e rY ) e r 2 2 r 2 . (19.8) • From equation 19.8 we have: E( X ) e 2 2 , 2 (19.9) 2 Var( X ) e e [e 10 2 1]. (19.10) The CDF of X P( X x) P(log X log x) N ( log x ), (19.11) The distribution of X is unimodal with the mode at mode( X ) e 11 ( 2 ) . (19.12) Log-normal distribution is NOT symmetric. • Let x be the percentile for the log-normal distribution and z be the corresponding percentile for the standard normal, then P( X x ) P( log x log X log x ) N( z implying x e . • Also that median( X ) e , as z 0.5 0. • so z log x ). (19.13) , (19.15) (19.14) • Meaning that median( X ) mode( X ). 12 19.3 The Log-Normal Distribution and Its Relationship to the Normal Distribution • Compare PDF of normal distribution and PDF of log-normal distribution to see that f ( y) f ( x) x • Also from (19.6), we can see that dx xdy 13 (19.16) (19.17) • CDF for the log-normal distribution F (a) P r(X a) P r(logX log a) log X log a P r( ) (19.18) N (d ) • Where d log a (19.19) *N(d) is the CDF of standard normal distribution which can be found from Normal Table; it can also be obtained from S-plus/other software. • 14 • N(d) can alternatively be approximated by the following formula: N (d ) a0 e d2 2 (a1t a2t a3t ) 2 3 (19.20) 1 1 0.33267d a0 0.3989423, a1 0.4361936, a2 0.1201676, a3 0.9372980 • Where • In case we need Pr(X>a), then we have t Pr(X a) 1 Pr(X a) 1 N (d ) N (d ) (19.21) 15 • Since for any h, E( X h ) E(e hY ), the hth moment of X, the following moment generating function of Y, which is normally distributed. 1 t t M Y (t ) e 2 2 2 (19.22) For example, X E( X ) E(eY ) M Y (1) e E ( X ) E (e ) M Y (h) e h • hY E ( X ) ( EX ) e 16 1 2 h t 2 2 (19.23) Hence 2 X • 1 2 t 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 e 2 2 e 2 2 2 (e 1) (19.24) Fractional and negative movement of a log-normal distribution can be obtained from Equation (19.23) • Mean of a log-normal random variable can be defined as 0 2 2 (19.25) If the lower bound a > 0; then the partial mean of x can be shown as • xf ( x)dx e 0 xf ( x)dx log( a ) f ( y)e dy e y 2 2 N (d ) Where (19.26) • 17 This implies that • partial mean of a log-normal • = (mean of x )( N(d)) d log(a) 19.4 Multivariate Normal and LogNormal Distributions The normal distribution with the PDF given in Equation (19.1) can be extended to the p-dimensional case. Let X X 1 , , X p be a p × 1 random vector. Then we say that X ~ N , , if it has the PDF • p p f ( x ) 2 2 1 2 1 exp x 1 x 2 • is the mean vector and (19.27) is the covariance matrix which is symmetric and positive definite. 18 • Moment generating function of X is M x (t ) E e tx e • Where t t1 , , t p 1 t t t 2 (19.28) is a p x 1 vector of real values. • From Equation (19.28), it can be shown that E (X ) and Cov(X ) If C is a q p matrix of rank q p. Then CX ~ Nq C , CC. Thus, linear transformation of a normal random vector is also a multivariate normal random vector. 19 (1) X (1) X ( 2 ) ( 2 ) X Let , and , where X (i ) and (i ) are pi 1 , p1 p2 p , and ij = pi p j The marginal distribution is also a multivariate normal with mean vector and covariance matrix that’s X(i) ~ N p (i) , ii . The conditional distribution of X (1) with givens where 11 12 21 22 i 1 2 (1) 12 22 1 x (2) (2) and 1 11 2 11 12 22 21 That is, 20 X (1) X ( 2 ) x ( 2 ) ~ N p1 1 2 , 11 2 (19.29) (19.30) • Bivariate • version of correlated log-normal distribution. 1 11 Y1 log X 1 ~ N Y log X , 2 2 2 21 12 22 Let • Joint PDF of X 1and X 2 can be obtained from the joint PDF of Y1 andY2by observing that dx1dx2 x1 x2 dy1dy2 (19.31) • (19.31) is an extension of (19.17) to the bivariate case. • Hence, joint PDF of X𝟏 and X𝟐 is g x1 , x2 21 1 1 exp log x1 , log x2 1 log x1 , log x2 2 x1 x2 2 (19.32) • From • Hence, the property of the multivariate normal distribution, we have Yi ~ N i , ii 𝑿𝐢 is log-normal with E( X i ) e Var( X i ) e 2 i i ii ii 2 , e [e (19.33) ii 1]. (19.34) 22 • By the property of the movement generating for the bivariate normal distribution, we have 1 2 Y Y E X 1 X 2 Ee 1 e exp 2 E X 1 E X 2 1 2 2 11 11 22 22 12 (19.35) the covariance between X1 and X2 is Cov X 1 , X 2 E X 1 X 2 E X 1 E X 2 • Thus, E X 1 E X 2 exp 11 22 1 1 exp 1 2 11 22 exp 11 22 1 2 (19.36) 23 • From the property of conditional normality of 𝑌1 given 𝑌2 =𝑦2 , we also see that the conditional distribution of 𝑌1 given 𝑌2 =𝑦2 is log normal. Y Y , , Y • When where Yi log X i . 1 p If Y ~ N p , where μ and ij . The joint PDF of X 1 , , X p can be obtained from Theorem 1. 1 24 p Theorem 1 • Let • the PDF of Y1 ,, Yp be f ( y ,, y ), consider the • p-valued functions 1 p xi xi ( y1,, y p ), i 1,, p. (19.37) • Assume transformation from the y-space to • x-space is one to one with • inverse transformation yi yi ( x1,, xp ), i 1,, p. 25 (19.38) • If we let random variables X1 ,, X pbe defined by X i xi (Y1,,Yp ), i 1,, p. (19.39) Then the PDF of X1 ,, X p is g( x1,, x p ) f y1 ( x1,, x p ),, y p ( x1,, x p )J ( x1,, x p ) • Where J(𝑥1 ,.., 𝑥𝑝 ) is Jacobian of transformations y1 x1 J ( x1 ,, x p ) m od y p x1 • 26 (19.40) y1 x p y p x p “Mod” means modulus or absolute value (19.41) When applying theorem 1 with f ( y1,, y p ) being a p-variate normal and J ( x1 ,, x p ) mod 1 x1 0 0 0 1 x2 0 1 xp 0 g ( x1 ,, x p ) (2 ) p 2 p 2 p ( i 1 We have joint PDF of p 1 i 1 xi (19.42) X1,...,X p *when p=2, Equation (19.43) reduces to the bivariate case given in Equation (19.32) 27 1 1 ) exp log x1 , , log x p 1 log x1 , , log x p xi 2 (19.43) Yjij The first two moments are E( X i ) e i ii 2 , (19.44) Var( X i ) e 2i e ii [e ii 1]. Cor X , X exp i j (19.45) *Where ij is the correlation between Yi and Y j 28 1 ii jj exp ij ii jj 1 i j 2 (19.46) 19.5 The Normal Distribution as an Application to the Binomial and Poisson Distribution • Cumulative normal density function tells us the probability that a random variable Z will be less than x. 29 Figure 19-1 • *P(Z<x) 30 is the area under the normal curve from up to point x. • Applications of the cumulative normal distribution function is in valuing stock options. • A call option gives the option holder the right to purchase, at a specified price known as the exercise price, a specified number of shares of stock during a given time period. • A call 31 option is a function of S, X, T, 2 ,and r • The binomial option pricing model in Equation (19.22) can be written as T T! k T k C S[ p ' (1 p ' ) ] k m k!(T k )! T X T! k T k [ p ( 1 p ) ] T (1 r ) k m k!(T k )! X SB(T , p ' , m) B(T , p, m), T (1 r ) *C= 0 if m>T 32 (19.47) S = Current price of the firm’s common stock T = Term to maturity in years m = minimum number of upward movements in stock price that is necessary for the option to terminate “in the money” Rd uR p and 1 p ud ud X = Exercise price (or strike price) of the option R= 1+r = 1+ risk-free rate of return u = 1 + percentage of price increase d = 1 + percentage of price decrease u p' p R 33 n B(n, p, m) n C k p k (1 p) nk k m • By a form of the central limit theorem, in Section 19.7 you will see T , the option price C converges to C below C SN(d1 ) XRT N (d 2 ) • (19.48) C = Price of the call option d1 S ) t Xr 1 t 2 t log( d 2 d1 t N(d) is the value of the cumulative standard normal distribution • t is the fixed length of calendar time to expiration and h is the elapsed time between successive stock price changes and T=ht. • 34 • If future stock price is constant over time, 2 then 0 It can be shown that both N (d1 ) and N (d 2 ) are equal to 1 and that that Equation (19.48) becomes C S Xe rT (19.49) *Equation (19.48 and 19.49) can also be understood in terms of the following steps 35 Step 1: Future price of the stock is constant over time • Value of the call option: X CS . T (1 r ) (19.50) X= exercise price • C= value of the option (current price of stock – present value of purchase price) • *Equation 19.50 assumes discrete compounding of interest, whereas Equation 19.49 assumes continuous compounding of interest. 36 *We can adjust Equation 19.50 for continuous compounding by changing 1 (1 r) T to e rT And get C S Xe rT (19.51) 37 Step 2: Assume the price of the stock fluctuates over time (St ) • Adjust Equation 19.49 for uncertainty associated with fluctuation by using the cumulative normal distribution function. • • Assume St from Equation 19.48 follows a log- normal distribution (discussed in section 19.3). 38 Adjustment factors N (d1 ) and N (d 2 )in BlackScholes option valuation model are adjustments made to EQ 19.49 to account for uncertainty of the fluctuation of stock price. • Continuous option pricing model (EQ 19.48) vs • binomial option price model (EQ19.47) N (d1 ) and N (d 2 ) are cumulative normal density functions while B(T , p, m) and B(T , p' , m) are complementary binomial distribution functions. • 39 Application Eq. (19.48) Example • Theoretical value: As of November 29, 1991, of one of IBM’s options with maturity on April 1992. In this case we have X = $90, S = $92.50, = 0.2194, r = 0.0435, and T= =0.42 (in years). Armed with this information we can calculate the estimated 𝑑1 and 𝑑2 . x {ln( 92.5 1 ) [(.0435) (.2194) 2 ](.42)} 90 2 0.392, (.2194)(.42) 1 2 1 2 x t x (0.2194)(0.42) 0.25. 40 Probability of Variable Z between 0 and x Figure 19-2 *In Equation 19.45, N (d1 ) and N (d1 )are the probabilities that a random variable with a standard normal distribution takes on a value less than d1 and a value less than d 2, respectively. The values for the probabilities can be found by using the tables in the back of the book for the standard normal distribution. 41 • To find the cumulative normal density function, we add the probability that Z is less than zero to the value given in the standard normal distribution table. Because the standard normal distribution is symmetric around zero, the probability that Z is less than zero is 0.5, so P( Z x) P ( Z 0) P (0 Z x) •= 42 0.5 + value from table • From N (d1 ) P(Z d1 ) P( Z 0) P(0 Z d1 ) P(Z .392) .5 .1517 0.6517 N (d 2 ) P(Z d 2 ) P(Z 0) P(0 Z d 2 ) P(Z .25) .5 .0987 0.5987 • The theoretical value of the option is C (92.5)(.6517) [(90)(.5987)]/ e(.0435 )(.42) 60.282 53.883/ 1.0184 $7.373. • 43 The actual price of the option on November 29,1991, was $7.75. 19.6 Applications of the Log-Normal Distribution in Option Pricing Assumptions of Black-Scholes formula : No transaction costs No margin requirements No taxes All shares are infinitely divisible Continuous trading is possible Economy risk is neutral Stock price follows log-normal distribution 44 Sj S j 1 exp[K j ] *Is a random variable with a log-normal distribution S = current stock price 𝑆𝑗 = end period stock price 𝐾𝑗 = rate of return in period and random variable with normal distribution 45 2 • Let Kt have the expected value k and variance k for each j. Then K1 K 2 ... K t is a normal random 2 variable with expected value t k and variance t k . Thus, we can define the expected value (mean) of St exp[K 1 K 2 ... K t ] as S t 2 S E( t S ) exp[t k k 2 ]. (19.52) Under the assumption of a risk-neutral investor, S the expected return E ( S ) becomes exp(rt ) ( where r is the riskless rate of interest). In other words, t k r 46 k2 2 (19.53) In risk-neutral assumptions, call option price C can be determined by discounting the expected value of terminal option price by the riskless rate of interest: C exp[rt ]E[Max(ST X ,0)] (19.54) T = time of expiration and X = striking price Max( S T X ,0) ( S ( 0 ST X )), for S S for ST X S S ST X S S (19.55) 47 Eq. (19.54) and (19.55) say that the value of the call option today will be either St X or 0, whichever is greater. • If the price of stock at time t is greater than the exercise price, the call option will expire in the money. • In other words, the investor will exercise the call option. The option will be exercised regardless of whether the option holder would like to take physical possession of the stock. • 48 Two Choices For Investor 1.Own Stock St X 49 • Since the price the investor paid (X) is lower that the price he or she can sell the stock for (𝑆𝑡 ), the investor realizes an immediate the profit of St X . • If the price of the stock (𝑆𝑡 ) the exercise price (X), the option expires out of the money. • This occurs because in purchasing shares of the stock the investor will find it cheaper to purchase the stock in the market than to exercise the option. 50 • Let ST S be log-normally distributed with 2 t k 2 2 parameters tr 2 and t k . Then X C exp[rt ]E[ Max( S t X )] X exp[rt ]X S[ x ]g ( x)dx S S exp[rt ]S X S • Where of 51 X xg ( x)dx exp[rt ]S S X S g ( x)dx (19.56) g(x) is the probability density function St Xt S 2 2 2 tr t / 2 , t • By substituting k k and Into eq. (19.18) and (19.26), we get X S xg ( x)dx e N (d1 ) rt (19.57) X S X a S g ( x)dx N (d 2 ) (19.58) where t X S 1 tr k2 log( ) log( ) (r k2 )t 2 S t X 2 d1 k t k t k (19.59) S 1 2 log( ) (r k )t X 2 d2 d1 t k t k 52 (19.60) • Substituting eq. (19.58) into eq. (19.56), we get C SN(d1 ) X exp[rt ]N (d 2 ) (19.61) • This 53 is also Eq.(19.48) defined in Section 19.6 • Put option is a contract conveying the right to sell a designated security at a stipulated price. • The relationship between a call option (C) and a out option (P) can be shown as C Xe rt P S (19.62) • Substituting Eq. (19.33) into Eq. (19.34), the put option formula becomes P Xert N (d 2 ) SN(d1 ) (19.63) *where S, C, r, t, 𝑑1 , 𝑑2 , are identical to those defined in the call option model. 54 19.7 The Bivariate Normal Density Function • A joint distribution of two variables is when in correlation analysis, we assume a population where both X and Y vary jointly. • If both X and Y are normally distributed, then we call this known distribution a bivariate normal distribution. 55 • The PDF of the normally distributed random variables X and Y can be f (X ) f (Y ) 1 X 1 Y ( X X ) exp , X 2 2 2 X (Y Y ) exp , Y 2 2 2 Y (19.64) (19.65) X and Y are population means for X and Y, respectively; X and Y are population standard deviations of X and Y, respectively; 3.1416 ;and exp represents the exponential function. • Where 56 • If represents the population correlation between X and Y, then the PDF of the bivariate normal distribution can be defined as f ( X ,Y ) 1 2 X Y 1 2 exp(q / 2), X , Y (19.66) • Where X 0, Y 0 1 X X q 2 1 X 2 and 1 1, X X 2 X Y Y Y X Y Y 2 (19.67) 57 • It can be shown that the conditional mean of Y, given X, is linear in X and given by Y E (Y | X ) Y X ( X X ) (19.67) This equation can be regarded as describing the population linear regression line. • Accordingly, a linear regression in terms of the bivariate normal distribution variable is treated as though there were a two-way relationship instead of an existing causal relationship. • It should be noted that regression implies a causal relationship only under a “prediction” case. • 58 • It is also clear that given X, we can define the conditional variance of Y as (Y | X ) (1 ) 2 Y 2 (19.68) • Eq. (19.66) represents a joint PDF for X and Y. • If 0 , then Equation (19.66) becomes f ( X , Y ) f ( X ) f (Y ) • This (19.69) implies that the joint PDF of X and Y is equal to the PDF of X times the PDf of Y. We also know that both X and Y are normally distributed. Therefore, X is independent of Y. 59 Example 19.1 Using a Mathematics Aptitude Test to Predict Grade in Statistics • Let X and Y represent scores in a mathematics aptitude test and numerical grade in elementary statistics, respectively. • In addition, we assume that the parameters in Equation (19.66) are X 550 X 40 Y 80 Y 4 60 .7 • Substituting this information into Equations (19.67) and (19.68), respectively, we obtain E (Y | X ) 80 .7(4 / 40)( X 550) 41.5 .07X (19.70) (Y | X ) (16)(1 .49) 8.16 2 (19.71) 61 • If we know nothing about the aptitude test score of a particular student (say, john), we have to use the distribution of Y to predict his elementary statistics grade. 95% interval 80 (1.96)(4) 80 7.84 is, we predict with 95% probability that John’s grade will fall between 87.84 and 72.16. • That 62 • Alternatively, suppose we know that John’s mathematics aptitude score is 650. In this case, we can use Equations (19.70) and (19.71) to predict John’s grade in elementary statistics. E (Y | X 650) 41.5 (.07)(650) 87 And 2 (Y | X ) (16)(1 .49) 8.16 63 • We can now base our interval on a normal probability distribution with a mean of 87 and a standard deviation of 2.86. 95% interval 87 (1.96)(2.86) 87 5.61 is, we predict with 95% probability that John’s grade will fall between 92.61 and 81.39. • That 64 • Two things have happened to this interval. 1. First, the center has shifted upward to take into account the fact that John’s mathematics aptitude score is above average. 2. Second, the width of the interval has been narrowed from 87.84−72.16 = 15.68 grade points to 92.61-81.39 = 11.22 grade points. • In this sense, the information about John’s mathematics aptitude score has made us less uncertain about his grade in statistics. 65 19.8 American Call Options • 19.8.1 Price American Call Options by the Bivariate Normal Distribution • An option contract which can be exercised only on the expiration date is called European call. • If the contract of a call option can be exercised at any time of the option's contract period, then this kind of call option is called American call. 66 • When a stock pays a dividend, the American call is more complex. • The valuation equation for American call option with one known dividend payment can be defined as C(S , T , X ) S x [ N1(b1) N 2(a1,b1; t T )] Xert [ N 1(b2)e r (T t ) N 2(a 2,b2; t T )] Dert N 1(b2) • where S ln X a1 x Sx ln * St b1 67 1 2 r T 2 , a 2 a1 T T 1 2 r t 2 , b 2 b1 t t (19.72a) (19.72b) (19.72c) S x S De rt (19.73) x • S represents the correct stock net price of the present value of the promised dividend per share (D); • t represents the time dividend to be paid. * • St is the exdividend stock price for which C(St* , T t ) St* D X (19.74) X, r, 2, T have been defined previously in this chapter. • S, 68 • Following Equation (19.66), the probability that is less than a and that is less than b for the standardized cumulative bivariate normal distribution '2 ' ' '2 ' ' 2 x 2 x y y ' ' P ( X a, Y b) exp dx dy 2 2 2(1 ) 2 1 1 x ' • 69 x x a ,y ' b y y Where and p is the correlation x y between the random variables x’ and y’. • The first step in the approximation of the bivariate normal probability N 2 (a, b; ) is as follows: 5 5 (a, b; ) .31830989 1 2 wi w j f ( xi' , x 'j ) i 1 j 1 (19.75) where f ( xi' , x 'j ) exp[a1 (2xi' a1 ) b1 (2x 'j b1 ) 2 ( xi' a1 )(x 'j b1 )] 70 • The pairs of weights, (w) and corresponding abscissa values (x ' ) are i, j 1 2 3 4 5 71 w 0.24840615 0.39233107 0.21141819 0.033246660 0.00082485334 x' 0.10024215 0.48281397 1.0609498 1.7797294 2.6697604 • and the coefficients 𝑎1 and 𝑏1 are computed using a1 • The a 2(1 2 ) b1 b 2(1 2 ) second step in the approximation involves computing the product ab𝜌; if ab𝜌 ≤ 0, compute the bivariate normal probability, N 2 (a, b; ) , using certain rules. 72 • Rules: • (1) • then N 2 (a, b; ) (a, b; ) ; • (2) • If a ≥0, b ≤0, and 𝜌 >0, then N 2 (a, b; ) N1 (b) (a, b; ) ; • (4) • If a ≤0, b ≥0, and 𝜌 >0, then N 2 (a, b; ) N1 (a) (a, b; ) ; • (3) • If a ≤0, b ≤0, and 𝜌 ≤0, If a ≥0, b ≥0, and 𝜌 ≤0, Then N 2 (a, b; ) N1 (a) N1 (b) 1 (a, b; ) . (19.76) 73 • If ab𝜌 > 0, compute the bivariate normal probability,N 2 (a, b; ) ,as N 2 (a, b; ) N 2 (a,0; ab ) N 2 (b,0; ab ) (19.77) the values of N 2 () on the right-hand side are computed from the rules, for ab𝜌 ≤ 0 • where ab ( a b)Sgn(a) a 2ab b 2 2 ba 1 Sgn (a ) Sgn (b) 4 • a 2 2ab b 2 1 Sgn( x) 1 N1 (d ) is the cumulative univariate normal probability. 74 ( b a)Sgn(b) x0 x0 19.8.2 Pricing an American Call Option • An American call option whose exercise price is $48 has an expiration time of 90 days. Assume the risk-free rate of interest is 8% annually, the underlying price is $50, the standard deviation of the rate of return of the stock is 20%, and the stock pays a dividend of $2 exactly for 50 days. (a) What is the European call value? (b) Can the early exercise price predicted? (c) What is the value of the American call? 75 (a) The current stock net price of the present value of the promised dividend is S 50 2e x 0.08(50 365 ) 48.0218 The European call value can be calculated as C (48.0218 ) N (d1 ) 48e 0.08 ( 90 365 ) N (d 2 ) where [ln(48.208/ 48) (0.08 0.5(0.20) 2 )(90 / 365)] d1 0.25285 .20 90 / 365 d 2 0.292 0.0993 0.15354. 76 • From standard normal table, we obtain N (0.25285) 0.5 .3438 0.599809 N (0.15354) 0.5 .3186 0.561014. • So 77 the European call value is C = (48.516)(0.599809) − 48(0.980)(0.561014) = 2.40123. (b) The present value of the interest income that would be earned by deferring exercise until expiration is X (1 er (T t ) ) 48(1 e0.08(9050) / 365 ) 48(1 0.991) 0.432. Since d = 2> 0.432, therefore, the early exercise is not precluded. 78 S t*= 46.9641. An Excel program used to calculate this value is presented in Table 19-1. (c) The value of the American call is now calculated as C 48.208[ N1 (b1 ) N 2 (a1 ,b1; 50 90)] 48e 0.08(90 / 365 ) [ N1 (b2 )e 0.08( 40 / 365 ) N 2 (a2 ,b2 ; 50 / 90)] 2e 0.08(50 / 365 ) N1 (b2 ) (19.78) since both and depend on the critical exdividend stock price , which can be determined by C(St* ,40 / 365;48) St* 2 48 using trial and error, we find thatS t* = 46.9641. An Excel program used to calculate this value is presented in Table 19-1. • By 79 S t* Table 19-1 Calculation of St* • St* 80 (Critical ex-dividend stock price) S*(critical exdividend stock price) 46 46.962 46.963 46.9641 46.9 47 X(exercise price of option) 48 48 48 48 48 48 r(risk-free interest rate) 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.08 volalitity of stock 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 T-t(expiration date-exercise date) 0.10959 0.10959 0.10959 0.10959 0.10959 0.10959 d1 −0.4773 −0.1647 −0.1644 −0.164 −0.1846 −0.1525 d2 −0.5435 −0.2309 −0.2306 −0.2302 −0.2508 −0.2187 D(divent) 2 2 2 2 2 2 c(value of European call option to buy one share) 0.60263 0.96319 0.96362 0.9641 0.93649 0.9798 p(value of European put option to sell one share) 2.18365 1.58221 1.58164 1.58102 1.61751 1.56081 C(St*,T−t;X) −St*−D+X 0.60263 0.00119 0.00062 2.3E−06 0.03649 −0.0202 Caculation of St*(critical ex-dividend stock price) Column C* 1* 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 S*(critical ex-dividend 46 stock price) X(exercise price of 48 option) r(risk-free interest 0.08 rate) volatility of stock 0.2 T-t(expiration date=(90-50)/365 exercise date) d1 =(LN(C3/C4)+(C5+C6^2/2)*(C7))/(C6*SQRT(C7)) 9 d2 =(LN(C3/C4)+(C5-C6^2/2)*(C7))/(C6*SQRT(C7)) 10 D(divent) 2 11 c(value of European 12 call option to buy one share) p(value of European 13 put option to sell one share) 14 15 C(St*,T-t;X)-St*-D+X 81 =C3*NORMSDIST(C8)-C4*EXP(-C5*C7)* NORMSDIST(C9) =C4*EXP(-C5*C7)*NORMSDIST(-C9)C3*NORMSDIST(-C8) =C12-C3-C10+C4 Sx = 48.208,X =$48 and St* into Equations (19.72b) and (19.72c), we can calculate a1, a2, b1, and b2: a1 = d1 =0.25285. a2 = d2 =0.15354. • Substituting 48.208 0.2 2 50 ln( ) (0.08 )( ) 46.9641 2 365 0.4859 b1 (.20) 50 365 b2 = 0.485931–0.074023 = 0.4119. 82 • In addition, we also know • From 50 90 0.7454. the above information, we now calculate related normal probability as follows: N1(b1)= N1(0.4859)=0.6865 N1(b2)= N1(0.7454)=0.6598 83 • Following Equation (19.77), we now calculate the value of N2(0.25285,−0.4859; −0.7454)and N2 (0.15354, −0.4119; −0.7454)as follows: abρ > 0 for both cumulative bivariate normal density function, therefore, we can use Equation N2 (a, b;ρ)= N2(a, 0;ρab)+ N2(b, 0;ρba)-δ • Since calculate the value of both N2(a, b;ρ)as follows: • to 84 ab ba [(0.7454)(0.25285) 0.4859](1) (0.25285) 2(0.7454)(0.25285)(0.4859) (0.4859) 2 2 [(0.7454)(0.4859) 0.25285](1) (0.25285) 2(0.7454)(0.25285)(0.4859) (0.4859) 2 2 0.87002 0.31979 δ =(1−(1)(−1))/4 = ½ N2(0.292,−0.4859; −0.7454)=N2(0.292,0.0844)+N2 (−0.5377,0.0656)− 0.5 = N1(0)+ N1(−0.5377)−Φ (−0.292, 0; − 0.0844)−Φ(−0.5377,0; −0.0656)−0.5 = 0.07525 85 • Using a Microsoft Excel programs presented in Appendix 19A, we obtain • N2(0.1927, • Then −0.4119; −0.7454)= 0.06862. substituting the related information into the Equation (19.78), we obtain C=$3.08238 and all related results are presented in Appendix 19B. 86 19.9 Price Bounds for Options 19.9.1 Options Written on Nondividend- Paying Stocks • To derive the lower price bounds and the put–call parity relations for options on nondividend-paying stocks, simply set cost-of-carry rate (b) = risk-less rate of interest (r) • Note that, the only cost of carrying the stock is interest. 87 • The lower price bounds for the European call and put options are c(S , T ; X ) max[0, S XerT ] p(S , T ; X ) max[0, XerT S ] (19.79a) (19.79b) respectively, and the lower price bounds for the American call and put options are rT C(S , T ; X ) max[0, S Xe rT P(S , T ; X ) max[0, Xe respectively. 88 ] (19.80a) S] (19.80b) • The put–call parity relation for nondividend-paying European stock options is c(S , T ; X ) p(S , T ; X ) S XerT (19.81a) and the put–call parity relation for American options on nondividend-paying stocks is S X C(S , T ; X ) P(S , T ; X ) S XerT • For (19.81b) nondividend-paying stock options, the American call option will not rationally be exercised early, while the American put option may be done so. 89 19.9.2 Options Written on DividendPaying Stocks • If dividends are paid during the option's life, the above relations must reflect the stock's drop in value when the dividends are paid. • To manage this modification, we assume that the underlying stock pays a single dividend during the option’s life at a time that is known with certainty. • he dividend amount is D and the time to exdividend is t. 90 • If the amount and the timing of the dividend payment are known, the lower price bound for the European call option on a stock is c(S , T ; X ) max[0, S Dert XerT ] (19.82a) • In this relation, the current stock price is reduced by the present value of the promised dividend. • Because a European-style option cannot be exercised before maturity, the call option holder has no opportunity to exercise the option while the stock is selling cum dividend. 91 • In other words, to the call option holder, the current value of the underlying stock is its observed market price less the amount that the promised dividend contributes to the current stock value, that is, S Dert. • To prove this pricing relation, we use the same arbitrage transactions, except we use the reduced stock price S Dert in place of S. The lower price bound for the European put option on a stock is p(S ,T ; X ) max[0, XerT S Dert ] (19.82b) 92 • In the case of the American call option, for example, it may be optimal to exercise just prior to the dividend payment because the stock price falls by an amount D when the dividend is paid. • The lower price bound of an American call option expiring at the exdividend instant would be 0 or , whichever is greater. • On the other hand, it may be optimal to wait until the call option’s expiration to exercise. 93 • The lower price bound for a call option expiring normally is (19.82a). Combining the two results, we get rt C(S , T ; X ) max[0, S Xe , S De rt rT Xe ] (19.83a) • The last two terms on the right-hand side of (19.83a) provide important guidance in deciding whether to exercise the American call option early, just prior to the exdividend instant. • The second term in the squared brackets is the present value of the early exercise proceeds of the call. 94 • If the amount is less than the lower price bound of the call that expires normally, that is, if S Xe rt S De rT Xe rt (19.84) the American call option will not be exercised just prior to the exdividend instant. • To see why, simply rewrite (19.84) so it reads D X [1 e r (T t ) ] • In (19.85) other words, the American call will not be exercised early if the dividend captured by exercising prior to the exdividend date is less than the interest implicitly earned by deferring exercise until expiration. 95 • Figure 19-3 depicts a case in which early exercise could occur at the exdividend instant, t. Just prior to exdividend, the call option may be exercised yielding proceeds St D X, where 𝑆𝑡 , is the exdividend stock price. • An instant later, the option is left unexercised with value c(𝑆𝑡 ,T –t; X), where c is the European call option formula. Thus, if the exdividend stock price, 𝑆𝑡 is above the critical exdividend stock price where the two functions intersect, 𝑆𝑡∗ , the option holder will choose to exercise his or her option early just prior to the exdividend instant. ∗ • On the other hand, if 𝑆𝑡 ≤ 𝑆𝑡 , the option holder will choose to leave her position open until the option’s expiration. • 96 Figure 19-3 *Early exercise may be optimal. Figure 19-4 *Early exercise will not be optimal. 97 • Figure 19-4 depicts a case in which early exercise will not occur at the exdividend instant, t. • Early exercise will not occur if the functions, 𝑆𝑡 + 𝐷 − 𝑋 and c(𝑆𝑡 ,T-t,X) do not intersect, as is depicted in Figure 19-4. In this case, the lower r (T t ) S Xe boundary condition of the European call, t , lies above the early exercise proceeds, 𝑆𝑡 + 𝐷 − 𝑋 , and hence the call option will not be exercised early. Stated explicitly, early exercise is not rational if r (T t ) St D X St Xe 98 • This condition for no early exercise is the same as (19.84), where 𝑆𝑡 is the exdividend stock price and where the investor is standing at the exdividend instant, t. • In words, if exdividend stock price decline, the dividend is less than present value of the interest income that would be earned by deferring exercise until expiration, early exercise will not occur. • When condition of Eq. (19.85) is met, the value of American call is the value of corresponding European call. 99 • In the absence of a dividend, an American put may be exercised early. • In the presence of a dividend payment, however, there is a period just prior to the exdividend date when early exercise is suboptimal. • In that period, the interest earned on the exercise proceeds of the option is less than the drop in the stock price from the payment of the dividend. • If t 𝑛 represents a time prior to the dividend payment at time t, early exercise is suboptimal, where ( X S )e 100 r ( t tn ) ( X S D) • Rearranging, 𝑡𝑛 and t if early exercise will not occur between D ln(1 ) X S tn t r (19.86) • Early exercise will become a possibility again immediately after the dividend is paid. Overall, the lower price bound of the American put option is P(S , T ; X ) max[o, X (S Dert )] (19.83b) 101 • Put–call parity for European options on dividendpaying stocks also reflects the fact that the current stock price is deflated by the present value of the promised dividend, that is c(S , T ; X ) p(S , T ; X ) S Dert XerT (19.87) • That the presence of the dividend reduces the value of the call and increases the value of the put is again reflected here by the fact that the term on the right-hand side of (19.87) is smaller than it would be if the stock paid no dividend. 102 • Put–call parity for American options on dividendpaying stocks is represented by a pair of inequalities, that is rt rt rT S De X C(S , T ; X ) P(S , T ; X ) S De Xe (19.88) • To prove the put–call parity relation (19.88), we consider each inequality in turn. The left-hand side condition of (19.88) can be derived by considering the values of a portfolio that consists of buying a call, selling a put, selling the stock, and lending X + 𝐷𝑒 −𝑟𝑡 risklessly. Table 19-2 contains these portfolio values 103 • • • • • In Table 19-2, if all of the security positions stay open until expiration, the terminal value of the portfolio will be positive, independent of whether the terminal stock price is above or below the exercise price of the options. If the terminal stock price is above the exercise price, the call option is exercised, and the stock acquired at exercise price X is used to deliver, in part, against the short stock position. If the terminal stock price is below the exercise price, the put is exercised. The stock received in the exercise of the put is used to cover the short stock position established at the outset. In the event the put is exercised early at time T, the investment in the riskless bonds is more than sufficient to cover the payment of the exercise price to the put option holder, and the stock received from the exercise of the put is used to cover the stock sold when the portfolio was formed. In addition, an open call option position that may still have value 104 Table 19-2 Arbitrage Transactions for Establishing Put–Call Parity for American Stock Options S Dert X C(S , T ; X ) P(S , T ; X ) ExDividend Day(t) Position Buy American Call Sell American Put Sell Stock Lend D e rt Lend X Net Portfolio Value 105 Initial Value Put Exercised Early(γ) Intermediate Value Put Exercised normally(T) Terminal Value ~ ST X ~ −C 0 C ~ P S −D Dert −X −C+P+S Dert −X D ~ (X S ) (X ST ) ~ ~ S ~ ST X ~ ST X 0 ~ ST ST XerT XerT X (e rT 1) X (e rT 1) Xer 0 ~ C X (e r 1) • In other words, by forming the portfolio of securities in the proportions noted above, we have formed a portfolio that will never have a negative future value. • If the future value is certain to be non-negative, the initial value must be nonpositive, or the left-hand inequality of (19.88) holds. 106 Summary • In this chapter, we first introduced univariate and multivariate normal distribution and log-normal distribution. • Then we showed how normal distribution can be used to approximate binomial distribution. • Finally, we used the concepts normal and log-normal distributions to derive Black– Scholes formula under the assumption that investors are risk neutral. • • In this chapter, we first reviewed the basic concept of the Bivariate normal density function and present the Bivariate normal CDF. • The theory of American call stock option pricing model for one dividend payment is also presented. • The evaluations of stock option models without dividend payment and with dividend payment are discussed, respectively. • Finally, we provided an excel program for evaluating American option pricing model with one dividend payment. 107