The Black-ScholesMerton Model Chapter 13 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.1 The Stock Price Assumption Consider a stock whose price is S In a short period of time of length Dt, the return on the stock is normally distributed: DS mDt , s Dt S where m is expected return and s is volatility Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.2 The Lognormal Property (Equations 13.2 and 13.3, page 282) It follows from this assumption that s2 ln ST ln S0 m T , s T 2 or s2 ln ST ln S0 m T , s T 2 Since the logarithm of ST is normal, ST is lognormally distributed Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.3 The Lognormal Distribution E ( ST ) S0 e mT 2 2 mT var ( ST ) S0 e (e s2T 1) Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 Continuously Compounded Return, x Equations 13.6 and 13.7), page 283) ST S 0 e xT or 1 ST x = ln T S0 or s2 s x m , 2 T Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.5 The Expected Return The expected value of the stock price is S0emT The expected return on the stock is m – s2/2 not m This is because ln[E(ST / S0 )] and E[ln(ST / S0 )] are not the same Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.6 m and m−s2/2 Suppose we have daily data for a period of several months m is the average of the returns in each day [=E(DS/S)] m−s2/2 is the expected return over the whole period covered by the data measured with continuous compounding (or daily compounding, which is almost the same) Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.7 Mutual Fund Returns (See Business Snapshot 13.1 on page 285) Suppose that returns in successive years are 15%, 20%, 30%, -20% and 25% The arithmetic mean of the returns is 14% The returned that would actually be earned over the five years (the geometric mean) is 12.4% Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.8 The Volatility The volatility is the standard deviation of the continuously compounded rate of return in 1 year The standard deviation of the return in time Dt is s Dt If a stock price is $50 and its volatility is 30% per year what is the standard deviation of the price change in one week? 1 30 4.16% 52 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.9 Estimating Volatility from Historical Data (page 286-88) 1. 2. Take observations S0, S1, . . . , Sn at intervals of t years Calculate the continuously compounded return in each interval as: Si ui ln Si 1 3. 4. Calculate the standard deviation, s , of the ui´s The historical volatility estimate is: sˆ Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 s t 13.10 Nature of Volatility Volatility is usually much greater when the market is open (i.e. the asset is trading) than when it is closed For this reason time is usually measured in “trading days” not calendar days when options are valued Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.11 The Concepts Underlying BlackScholes The option price and the stock price depend on the same underlying source of uncertainty We can form a portfolio consisting of the stock and the option which eliminates this source of uncertainty The portfolio is instantaneously riskless and must instantaneously earn the risk-free rate This leads to the Black-Scholes differential equation Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.12 The Derivation of the Black-Scholes Differential Equation DS mS Dt sS Dz ƒ ƒ 2 ƒ 2 2 ƒ D ƒ mS ½ 2 s S Dt sS Dz t S S S We set up a portfolio consisting of 1 : derivative ƒ + : shares S Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.13 The Derivation of the Black-Scholes Differential Equation continued The value of the portfolio is given by ƒ ƒ S S The change in its value in time Dt is given by ƒ D D ƒ DS S Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.14 The Derivation of the Black-Scholes Differential Equation continued The return on the portfolio must be the risk - free rate. Hence D r Dt We substitute for D ƒ and DS in these equations to get the Black - Scholes differenti al equation : 2 ƒ ƒ ƒ 2 2 rS ½ s S rƒ 2 t S S Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.15 The Differential Equation Any security whose price is dependent on the stock price satisfies the differential equation The particular security being valued is determined by the boundary conditions of the differential equation In a forward contract the boundary condition is ƒ = S – K when t =T The solution to the equation is ƒ = S – K e–r (T –t) Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.16 In case of options Boundary conditions for European call: ƒ = max (S – K, 0) when t =T Boundary conditions for European put: ƒ = max (K – S , 0) when t =T Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.17 The Black-Scholes Formulas (See pages 295-297) c S 0 N (d1 ) K e pKe rT rT N (d 2 ) N (d 2 ) S 0 N (d1 ) 2 ln( S 0 / K ) (r s / 2)T where d1 s T 2 ln( S 0 / K ) (r s / 2)T d1 s T d2 s T Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.18 The N(x) Function N(x) is the probability that a normally distributed variable with a mean of zero and a standard deviation of 1 is less than x See tables at the end of the book Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.19 Properties of Black-Scholes Formula As S0 becomes very large c tends to S – Ke-rT and p tends to zero As S0 becomes very small c tends to zero and p tends to Ke-rT – S Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.20 Risk-Neutral Valuation The variable m does not appear in the BlackScholes equation The equation is independent of all variables affected by risk preference The solution to the differential equation is therefore the same in a risk-free world as it is in the real world This leads to the principle of risk-neutral valuation Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.21 Applying Risk-Neutral Valuation (See appendix at the end of Chapter 13) 1. Assume that the expected return from the stock price is the risk-free rate 2. Calculate the expected payoff from the option 3. Discount at the risk-free rate Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.22 Valuing a Forward Contract with Risk-Neutral Valuation Payoff is ST – K Expected payoff in a risk-neutral world is SerT – K Present value of expected payoff is e-rT[SerT – K]=S – Ke-rT Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.23 Implied Volatility The implied volatility of an option is the volatility for which the Black-Scholes price equals the market price The is a one-to-one correspondence between prices and implied volatilities Traders and brokers often quote implied volatilities rather than dollar prices Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.24 An Issue of Warrants & Executive Stock Options When a regular call option is exercised the stock that is delivered must be purchased in the open market When a warrant or executive stock option is exercised new Treasury stock is issued by the company If little or no benefits are foreseen by the market the stock price will reduce at the time the issue of is announced. There is no further dilution (See Business Snapshot 13.3.) Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.25 The Impact of Dilution After the options have been issued it is not necessary to take account of dilution when they are valued Before they are issued we can calculate the cost of each option as N/(N+M) times the price of a regular option with the same terms where N is the number of existing shares and M is the number of new shares that will be created if exercise takes place Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.26 Dividends European options on dividend-paying stocks are valued by substituting the stock price less the present value of dividends into Black-Scholes Only dividends with ex-dividend dates during life of option should be included The “dividend” should be the expected reduction in the stock price expected Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.27 American Calls An American call on a non-dividend-paying stock should never be exercised early An American call on a dividend-paying stock should only ever be exercised immediately prior to an ex-dividend date Suppose dividend dates are at times t1, t2, …tn. Early exercise is sometimes optimal at time ti if the dividend at that time is greater than r (t t ) K[1 e i1 i ] Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.28 Black’s Approximation for Dealing with Dividends in American Call Options Set the American price equal to the maximum of two European prices: 1. The 1st European price is for an option maturing at the same time as the American option 2. The 2nd European price is for an option maturing just before the final exdividend date Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2005 13.29