Labour Market Regulations and Economic Outcomes: Some Capital Lessons and Minor Messages Praveen Jha, Sakti Goldar and Swayamsiddha Panda Jawaharlal Nehru University Introduction Two Distinct and Contending Perspectives: 1. The ‘Distortionists’ Strong advocacy for labour market flexibility Labour institutions disrupt free market functioning, pose hindrance to growth and employment (Burki and Perry, 1997; Blanchard and Wolfers, 2000; Heckman et al, 2004; etc.). Regulations cause impediments to labour market adjustments to economic changes Redistribute ‘rents’ from capital to labour, reducing profitability, dampening investment (Cesar and Chong, 2003) 2. The ‘Institutionalists’ Institutions have a wide range of positive effects on economic outcomes (Baker et al, 2003, 2004, 2006; Freeman 1993; Howell 2006; etc.) Fulfill important redistributive roles Provides insurance against adverse outcomes to vulnerable categories of workers (Standing and Tokman, 1991) Significant for Keynesian reasons- Boost effective demand Enhancement of labour productivity through training or technical innovations (Freeman, 1993) Ameliorate moral hazard issues Cross-country Evidences Presumed Support for the ‘Distortionists’ Persuasion: Botero et al (2003) Cesar and Chong (2003) Nickell (1997) Elmeskov, Martin, Scarpetta (1998) Belot and van ours (2002) Bassanini and Duval (2006) Studies examining interactions between macroeconomic shocks and different institutions: Blanchard and Wolfers (2000) Fitoussi et al (2000) Bertola et al (2001) Nickell et al (2002), etc. Key conclusion of these studies – “ In the presence of adverse macroeconomic shocks, protective labour market institutions contribute to higher unemployment”. Some Cautionary Remarks In most of these cross-country analyses, results often depend upon the proxy used in econometric exercises and the sample of countries considered Variables such as union strength, unemployment benefit levels etc., are difficult to quantify and capture Wide variability of institutions across countries raises issues of comparable robust measures Several researchers consider cross- country aggregate data as ‘weak’ to draw reliable conclusions (Freeman, 2005) Empirical “Support” for the Institutionalists Baker, Glyn, Howell and Schmitt (2004) Card and Kruger (1995) Kucera and Sarna (2004) Buchele and Christiansen (1992, 1995, 1999), etc. Evidence on India Main focus of literature has been the Industrial Disputes Act (Chapter V-B) and the Contract Labour Act Some Major Studies exploring the so called adverse effects of the Industrial Disputes Act (1976 and 1982 amendments of Chapter V-B) : Fallon and Lucas (1993) Besley and Burgess (2004) Sanyal and Menon (2005) Aghion et al (2006) Ahsan and Pages (2006) The Besley-Burgess Study (2004) State-level amendments to the IDA classified as pr- worker, neutral and pro-employer and respective scores of +1, 0 and -1 assigned Assigned scores cumulated over time to arrive at a ‘regulatory measure’ for each state every year Such a measure is then used to explain economic performances with respect to the organised manufacturing sector Major Conclusions of the Besley- Burgess Study: Pro-worker legislations have contributed to the lowering of investment and employment in the organised manufacturing sector Have led to existence and growth of a large informal sector Net impact has been in terms of deterring productivity and constraining growth Raising Some Critical Issues Relating to the Besley-Burgess Study: Classifying a state as pro-worker or pro-employer on the basis of a single amendment can be misleading Problem of assigning scores when multiple amendments take place in a single year Fails in identifying specific components of labour laws impacting particular economic outcomes Measuring rigidities directly from legal statutes could be misleading; translation of laws into outcomes involves a complex intermediation process Questionable results related to classification and econometric estimation as pointed out by Bhattacharjea (2006) Major Problems with such Empirical Studies Fraught with methodological and technical difficulties Studies using the Besley-Burgess index carry over the errors of the original study Results refuted by subsequent studies (Bhalotra, 1998; Goldar, 2002; Hasan et al, 2003; Deshpande et al, 2004; Anant et al, 2005; Sharma, 2006; etc.) Contradictory pictures emerge depending upon the index used: World Bank Investment Climate Survey (2003) ranked Gujarat and Maharashtra as the ‘best’ states; both states classified as having ‘inflexible’ labour markets as per the Besley-Burgess study Increasing Flexibility and Casualisation A field based study of about 1,300 manufacturing firms across nine industry groups by Deshpande et al (2004) Key Findings of the study: 1. Both the unionised and non-unionised firms increased capital intensity over the period considered 2. Only half the firms reportedly were paying the statutory minimum wage 3. Firms increasingly resorted to greater use of nonpermanent workers Increasing casualisation of the workforce highlighted by several other studies (Sen et al, 2006; Indian Labour Market Report 2008; Guha, 2009; etc) Organised Manufacturing Sector: Key Empirical Findings Looking at the percentage distribution of total employment distribution in the size classes, the above 100 size has increased much more than below 100 despite IDA Chapter V-B threshold of 100 (1982 amendment) Distribution by Size of Employment Distribution of Employment Growth Rate - CAGR Percent Percent per Annum 1973-74 1980-81 1990-91 1997-98 2002-03 1973-80 1980-90 1990-97 1997-2002 0-49 14.4 13.8 17.5 16.8 20.5 3.5% 3.0% 2.2% -0.5% 50-99 8.2 9.0 10.8 13.1 11.7 5.5% 2.4% 5.7% -6.5% 100-199 9.4 9.2 10.7 12.9 12.8 3.8% 2.1% 5.6% -4.5% 200-499 13.1 12.1 13.5 19.0 17.2 2.9% 1.7% 8.0% -6.3% 500-999 11.6 9.7 12.0 13.6 12.2 1.5% 2.7% 4.7% -6.5% 1000-1999 12.8 13.7 10.1 9.4 8.4 5.2% -2.5% 1.8% -6.7% 2000-4999 16.7 15.9 9.5 10.0 8.3 3.4% -4.5% 3.7% -8.0% 5000+ 13.8 16.7 15.9 5.2 9.0 6.9% 0.1% -12.5% 7.0% Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 4.1% 0.6% 2.8% -4.4% Source: Computed from ASI data summary results, CSO, Various issues Wage and Productivity Trends 3.50 Real Average Wage and Real NVA per Worker 3.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 0.50 1980-81 1981-82 1982-83 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 0.00 Real Wage Per Worker Real NVA per Worker Source: Computed from ASI data summary results, CSO, Various issues Wage and Productivity: Growth Rates All India Year Compound Annual Growth Rates (in percent per annum) G.R. of Real Wage Per Worker G.R of Real NVA Per Worker 1980-81 to 1990-91 3.1% 8.0% 1990-91 to 1997-98 0.6% 5.7% 1997-98 to 2007-08 -1.1% 6.9% Source: Computed from ASI data summary results, CSO, Various issues Growth in average real wages have lagged behind average productivity, the wageproductivity gap has increased Average Wage and Salary Trends 0.70 Real Average Wage and Salary 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 1980-81 1981-82 1982-83 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 0.00 Real Wage per Worker(in Lakhs) Real Average Salary (in Lakhs) Average salary in real terms has gradually surpassed average real wages, and the gap has shown a marked increase in recent years Unit Labour Cost 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 1980-81 1981-82 1982-83 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 0.00 India Unit labour costs have been declining over the years, reflecting a relative shift in income distribution from labour to capital and other factors of production 1980-81 1981-82 1982-83 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 Wage –Rental Ratio 35.00 30.00 25.00 20.00 15.00 10.00 5.00 0.00 Wage Rental Ratio Wage-rental ratio has steadily declined, suggesting a relative cheapening of labour vis-à-vis capital Wage and Profit Shares: Trends 0.70 Share of Wages and Profits in Net Value Added 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 1980-81 1981-82 1982-83 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 0.00 Wages by NVA Profits by NVA Wage share in value added has come down remarkably while profit share in value added has registered a sharp increase in recent years Increasing Contractualisation All India Year Workers Directly Employed Workers Employed through Contractors Total Workers 1998-1999 5377193 987272 6364464 15.51% 1999-2000 5041339 1239320 6280659 19.73% 2000-2001 4882143 1253095 6135238 20.42% 2001-2002 4660496 1297351 5957848 21.78% 2002-2003 4739339 1422155 6161493 23.08% 2003-2004 4591237 1495671 6086908 24.57% 2004-2005 4851233 1748065 6599298 26.49% 2005-2006 5099750 2036347 7136097 28.54% 2006-2007 5516703 2363832 7880536 30.00% 2007-2008 5659750 2538360 8198110 30.96% 2008-2009 5977328 2799417 8776745 31.90% 2009-2010 6153723 3004079 9157802 32.80% Source: Computed from ASI data summary results, CSO, Various issues Ratio of Contract Workers to Total Workers (in %) Contract Workers as a proportion of Total Workers (in percent) 35.00% 30.00% 25.00% 20.00% 15.00% 10.00% Ratio of Contract Workers to Total Workers (in %) Contract workers as a percentage of total workers in organised manufacturing has increased greatly, belittling the rigidity argument Percentage Distribution of Strikes and Lockouts in Total Disputes 90.0% 80.0% 70.0% 60.0% 50.0% 40.0% 30.0% 20.0% 10.0% Strikes % 2006 2005 2004 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 0.0% Lockouts % Share of Strikes in total industrial disputes has come down, while that of lockouts has shored up, indicating general weakening of power of workers visà-vis the employers Percentage of Mandays Lost in Disputes 90.0% 80.0% 70.0% 60.0% 50.0% 40.0% 30.0% 20.0% 10.0% % of Mandays lost due to Strikes 2006 2005 2004 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 0.0% % of Mandays lost due to Lockouts Share of workdays lost due to lockouts has been higher than that for strikes since the nineties, signaling shift in power equations in favour of employers Some Capital Lessons Consideration of the empirical evidence of India’s industrial landscape reveals that the claims of the distortionists are exaggerated Need to look at a whole range of other critical variables for understanding economic outcomes; little basis to blame labour regulations for poor outcomes Inevitable outcome of neo-liberalism, based on ‘beggar thyself’ and ‘beggar thy neighbour’ policies, in a bid to attract global capital Labour has lost out to capital across the globe Capital interested in unhindered control of labour so as to reap both absolute and relative surplus value Certain Minor Messages Indeed certain labour institutions need to be revisited but suggestions of dissolution of the institutional framework akin to “throwing out the baby with the bath water” Labour laws in India have evolved in a knee-jerk and adhoc manner; the context in which many of them had evolved have witnessed a sea change Need for unification, harmonisation and rationalisation of labour laws Provision of minimum conditions of work and social security to the workers outside the purview of labour regulations