HEALTH CARE IN THE MACRO ECCONOMY Uwe Reinhardt, Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs and Department of Economics Princeton University MEDICAID LEADERSHIP INSTITUTE Princeton, New Jersey September 13, 2011 External factors beyond out control Self-Inflicted macroeconomic wounds U.S. Health Care A health system carefully calibrated to be inefficient Dysfunctional federal government OUTLINE I. THE MACRO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT II. THE HEALTH-CARE ECONOMY III. OPTIONS FOR COST CONTROL IN HEALTH CARE I. THE MACRO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT I. THE MACRO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT A. Factors beyond our control 1. Aging of the population Ratio of older people to working-age people SOURCE: Report of the Trustees of the Social Security System, http://www.socialsecurity.gov/oact/tr/2011/tr2011.pdf I. THE MACRO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT A. Factors beyond our control 1. Aging of the population 2. Outsourcing of labor to computers 3. Outsourcing of labor to low-cost countries SOURCE: Rolfe Larson, Blog: Business Planning, August 18,2011 For an enterprise active in the global market place, the word “nation” has no meaning. The entire globe is the “nation.” This is particularly true of innovative enterprises built on science and technology. Consider Apple Inc.’s iPad. VALUE-CHAIN LINKS IN “OPERATIONS”or MANUFACTURE Component A Korea ∙∙∙ Component B Japan ∙∙∙ Component N Assembly Switzerland China Most of the iPad’s components are procured from Korea and Japan, and some from Europe, although just where these components are actually manufactured is not clear to outsiders. Apple reaps huge profits from the iPad, which costs only between $230 to $300 to manufacture but sells for $500 to over $800, depending on the model. These profits, which accrue for the most part to some highly paid US based Apple executives and engineers and to the firm’s owners (with some going to retailing). Innovation and entrepreneurship by Apple Inc. adds significantly to US GDP, but less so to U.S. jobs. This has become the American dilemma with jobs: We invent new products and manufacture them elsewhere. Worse (for us) still, many of the emerging markets (BRICs) are now poised to move into higher and higher value-added links of the value chain – not only in manufacturing, but also in services, such as finance. That development imperils the jobs even of hitherto secure, higher-skilled, middle class Americans. Many of them might end up Medicaid eligible. COUNCIL ON FOREIGN RELATIONS In this paper, the authors make a distinction between 1. the sectors of our economy that produces goods or services traded across international borders (e.g., cars or MRI machines), and 2. The sectors producing goods and services not traded across borders (e.g., real estate construction, most healht care services, government services, etc.) SECTOR PRODUCING NON-TRADED OUTPUT • Almost all 27 million jobs created since 1990 were created in this sector, mainly by government, health care, real-estate construction and retailing. • But, these sectors experienced slow growth in value added per employee. • Because of government’s fiscal problems, both sectors not likely to grow as fast in the future. • This creates a major dilemma for job creation in the U.S. SECTOR PRODUCING TRADED OUTPUT • On a net basis, the traded sector contributed only 0.6 million jobs during 1990-2008. • This sector did have more rapid growth in value added (GDP) per employee, because its production moved up the global value-chain, leaving lower-valued production to emerging markets. • But the emerging markets will soon move up the global value- chain as well, putting increasing pressure on employment in the U.S. traded output sector. Reference: Michael Spence and Sandile Hlatshwayo, The Evolving Structure of the American Economy, Council on Foreign relations, (March 2011) SOURCE: Michael Spence and Sandile Hlatshwayo, The Evolving Structure of the American Economy and the Employment Challenge, Council on Foreign Relations, March 2011 THE MAJOR JOB CREATORS IN THE UNITED STATES 22.5 Government 18.5 16 Health Care 10 14 Retail 12 Accommodation & Food services 12 8.5 9 Construction 1990 2008 7 0 5 10 15 Millions of Jobs SOURCE: Approximated from Spence and Hlatswayo, Figure 6. 20 25 This realignment of jobs in the U.S. has significant and serious effects on the nation’s income distribution which, in turn, has significant and serious effects on politics and thence on the distribution of health care among the American people. Although I am not a political scientist, I suspect that this shift in jobs and incomes adds to the angry tone of our debate over U.S. health reform. Anthony B. Atkinson, Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, “Top Incomes in the Long Run History,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2011; 49:1, 3-71. FIGURE 1 --AVERAGE INCOME GROWTH IN THE UNITED STATES 14% AVERAGE TOP 1% Bottom 99% Annual percentage growth 12% 10.3% 10.1% 10% 8% 6% 4.4% 4.0% 4% 2.7% 2% 3.0% 1.3% 1.2% 0.6% 0% 1976-2008 1993-2000 2002-2007 FIGURE 2 -- FRACTION OF TOTAL INCOME GROWTH CAPTURED 70% 60% 65% 58% 50% 45% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1976-2007 1992-2000 2002-2007 These long-term structural problems would have emerged even if the U.S. had been governed by smart public fiscal, industrial and educational policies. Unfortunately, these structural problems have been amplified by some self-inflicted wounds. I. THE MACRO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT A. Factors beyond our control B. Self-inflicted wounds FIRST SELF-INFLICTED WOUND A staunch anti-government attitude in the population and among leading policy makers. In his first inaugural address as President of the United States, Ronald Reagan proclaimed: "Government is not a solution to our problem; government is the problem." (January 20, 1981) This idea now dominates American politics and public policy. Our old, overcrowded and sometimes crumbling public infrastructure is a monument to this anti-government sentiment. It also makes it impossible now to redeploy the idle real estate construction industry into repairing and modernizing our infrastructure through a government stimulus program that would reduce unemployment in the process. Americans cannot even dream of such an infrastructure. CHINESE BULLET TRAIN – FASTEST IN THE WORLD Even the President’s most recent jobs program – should it be enacted, which probably it won’t be – is much too timid to make any dent in this problem. It’s 10-year cost amounts to 3% of current GDP – too small a donkey to carry much of a load. ADDITIONAL FEDERAL SPENDING IN 2012 ON JOBS PROGRAM Total of $421 billion (Additional infrastructure spending of $35 b in 2013). Infrastructure spending in 2012, $55 , 13% Keynesian mechanisms (payroll tax holiday, UE insce.etc.), $218 , 52% Incentives for employers to hire workers, $118 , 28% Aid to states for jobs, $30 , 7% SECOND SELF-INFLICTED WOUND Fiscal mismanagement by the federal government. U.S. fiscal policy: How `` cool! Sunshine all around! © Tsung-Mei Cheng Nixon/ Ford Carter Reagan/Bush I Clinton Bush II Obama ???? In the words of Douglas Elmendorf, the Director of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO): SOURCE: Congressional Budget Office, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/110xx/doc11047/05-13-CBO_Presentation_to_AAAS.pdf The theory among some Americans is that we can solve all our economic problems – including unemployment – with yet more major tax cuts. Can they be serious? TOTAL TAXES AS PERCENT OF GDP, 2009 Denmark 48.2 Sweden 46.4 OECD AVGE. Italy 44.8 43.5 42.8 Austria France 41.9 Netherlands 39.1 Germany 37 United Kingdom Americans are not an overtaxed people 34.3 Canada Spain 31.1 30.7 30.3 Switzerland Japan 28.1 24 26.1% IN 2008 United States 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 Source: OECD Tax Data Base, http://www.oecd.org/document/60/0,3746,en_2649_34533_1942460_1_1_1_1,00.html#A_Revenue Statistics 55 Unfortunately, America’s home-grown savings have been insufficient to cover: 1. the depreciation of the existing U.S. capital stock; 2. net new private investments in business and residential capital stock, and 3. the mounting deficits in the public sector. PRIVATE PERSONAL AND BUSINESS SAVINGS A SA PERCENTAGE OF GDP, NET OF DEPRECIATION ALLOWANCE, 1980-2009 PERSONAL SAVINGS BUSINESS SAVINGS TOTAL NET PRIVATE SAVINGS 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 SOURCE: Economic Report of the President 2011, Table B-1 AND B-32. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Because domestic savings have been too low to cover private investments and public deficits, we have had to rely on foreign savings for many years – notably from China, from Japan, and from some other countries. U.S CURRENT ACOUNT DEFICIT (M - X) 1980 - 2009 $900 $800 These are annual net borrowings from abroad. $700 $600 $500 $400 $300 $200 $100 $80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 1 $(100) SOURCE: Economic Report of the President 2011, Table B-103. 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Our children will have to repay this external debt in one or both ways: 1. Paying significantly added taxes to pay of foreign-held U.S. bonds when they become due, or 2. Surrendering real U.S. assets (land, income-yielding real estate or entire companies) to the foreign creditors. And they had no vote on the fiscal policies that begot this debt. And why is this macro-economic backdrop relevant to health-care policy ? II. THE HEALTH CARE ECONOMY REAL vs FINANCIAL RESOURCES ABSORBED BY HEALTH CARE Health spending – now over 17% of U.S. GDP is measured here. It is what the providers of care get. Individuals who receive Claims on GDP (i.e., Money) health care goods or who surrender Prices services as patients Individuals real resources to Real Resources (i.e., health care) health care The utilization of health care is measured and controlled here PERCENT OF GDP CLAIMED BY HEALTH CARE, 1980-2009 U.S. France Switzerland Germany Canada Sweden 19 Percent of GDP 17 15 13 11 9 7 Source: OECD Data Base, 2011. 20 08 20 06 20 04 20 02 20 00 19 98 19 96 19 94 19 92 19 90 19 88 19 86 19 84 19 82 19 80 5 U.K. Americans have always believed that their health spending per capita and as percent of GDP towers above those of all other nations, because we get more and superior health care than do citizens of other nations. With the exception of a few procedures – e.g., cancer care – the evidence for that felicitous belief is weak to nonexistent. American health care cost so much more per capita for two major reasons: 1. The enormous complexity of the system and the huge administrative overhead that entails; 2. Higher prices for most health-care goods and services than are paid by citizens of other countries. THE VALUE CHAIN IN U.S. HEALTH CARE Medical Research Operations Research and Management Consulting Media and Publ. Rel. Consulting Risk Management Consultants Producers of Products Wholesalers The health-care workforce Financial Accounting and Auditing Compliance Consulting Firms Producers of Health Marketing Services Lobbying Firms Legal Services Others, in case I forgot some Public and Private Health Insurers Patients and the Care Services Informationinfrastructure Services Insurance brokers and others servicing the insurance industry Insured Why are prices so high in the U.S.? Because at the behest of the supply side, our politicians have structured the payment side of our health system on the Divide et Impera principle. Each private insurers – even those with relatively large market share in a local market – is too weak to resists price increases by hospitals, with few exceptions. The Income--Employment Facet Health-Care Spending Health-Care Incomes HEALTHPrices of Health-Care Goods and Services Health-Care CARE SECTOR Wage Rates Rates of Return to Capital, etc. Real resources OWNERS OF HEALTHCARE RESOURCES THE REST OF SOCIETY The Health Care & Health Facet OBJECTIVE A: OBJECTIVE B: Enhancing the patients’ quality of life Enhancing the “providers” quality of life HEALTH CARE AS AN EXCHANGE OF FAVORS The flow of funds in U.S. health care, 2009 OTHER PRIVATE PRIVATE HOUSEHOLDS STATE GOV’T Medicaid, etc. 12.6% 59% Medicaid Taxes Vouchers, Subsidies for Health Insurance FEDERAL GOV’T 46% Medicare, Medicaid, etc, 33.6% Cuts in Paycheck EMPLOYERS PRIVATE INSCE. Premiums for individually purchased health insurance Out of pocket at point of service (12%%) 34.5% PROVIDERS OF HEALTH CARE Taxes In December 2010, the trade association of private health insurers in the US – the AHIP – published this report on the average prices charged to larger insurers by Oregon Hospitals QUESTION: Why did private insurers and employers behind them accept this steep price increase? COMPARATIVE PRICES FOR A NORMAL DELIVERY: Total hospital and physician cost US 95 pctl. $13,799 US average $8,435 US low $6,379 Switzerland $3,485 Germany $2,147 France $3,768 Canada $2,266 Australia $4,592 $0 $2,000 $4,000 $6,000 $8,000 $10,000 $12,000 $14,000 $16,000 SOURCE: International Federation of Health Plans, 2010 COMPARATIVE PRICES FOR AN APPENDECTOMY: Total hospital and physician cost US 95 pctl. $25,344 US average $13,123 US low $7,758 Switzerland $2,570 Germany $3,285 France $2,795 Canada $3,810 Australia $6,526 $0 $5,000 $10,000 $15,000 $20,000 $25,000 SOURCE: International Federation of Health Plans, 2010 $30,000 COMPARATIVE PRICES FOR LIPITOR: US 95 pctl. $134 US average $129 Switzerland $78 Germany $78 Canada $31 Australia $33 $0 $20 $40 $60 $80 $100 $120 $140 SOURCE: International Federation of Health Plans, 2010 $160 Laugese and Glied in HEALTH AFFAIRS September 2011: 1647-56. III. OPTIONS FOR COST CONTROL IN HEALTH CARE During the past four decades, health-care spending in the U.S. have grown on average more than 2 percentage points faster than the rest of the GDP. If that trend continues for the next four decades, we’ll be spending 40% of our GDP on health care by 2050. This is not going to happen. The economy can’t take it any more. PROJECTED HEALTH SPENDING 2009-19 BY SOURCE $5,000 Medicaid Other Public Priv. Insce. Out-of-Pocket Other Private Projected NHE in 2019 = $$4.5 trillion or 19.3% of GDP $4,000 Private $3,500 $3,000 $2,500 Government Billions of Dollars $4,500 Medicare $2,000 $1,500 $1,000 $500 Medicare $0 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 SOURCE: CMS Data and Statistics, Sept. 2010 Update. 2017 2018 2019 Given our increasingly skewed income distribution, who will pay for the ever larger numbers of lower-middle class and poor American families’ health care? OPTIONS FOR CONTROLLING HEALTH SPENDING BETTER Option A: Reform the way we pay for health care HEALTH SPENDING = PRICES x UTILIZATION Option B: Ration the use of health care Single-payer health system (e.g., Canada or Vermont(?) All-payer health system with multiple payers (e.g. Germany or Switzerland) Multi-tiered, market-driven health system that rations health care by income class √ I believe that in the next two decades the U.S. health system may well evolve along the following lines (the third option): 1. Public hospitals and public clinics for publicly insured Americans, especially the poor, but perhaps also for a restructured Medicare. It allows politicians to ration health care without ever having to admit it. 2. For the employed middle class, a mixed system, tiered by cost through tiered reference pricing (now used mainly for prescription drugs) that can be camouflaged as “value-based purchasing. That approach also permits rationing of some health care by income class without anyone having to say so openly. 3. For the upper-income groups, boutique medicine, which is already growing in the U.S. Stay tuned!