Europe-Asia Studies ISSN: (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: www.tandfonline.com/journals/ceas20 Coordinated Voting Against the Autocracy: The Case of the ‘Smart Vote’ Strategy in Russia Mikhail Turchenko & Grigorii V. Golosov To cite this article: Mikhail Turchenko & Grigorii V. Golosov (2023) Coordinated Voting Against the Autocracy: The Case of the ‘Smart Vote’ Strategy in Russia, Europe-Asia Studies, 75:5, 820-841, DOI: 10.1080/09668136.2022.2147485 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/09668136.2022.2147485 View supplementary material Published online: 06 Dec 2022. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 767 View related articles View Crossmark data Citing articles: 4 View citing articles Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=ceas20 EUROPE-ASIA STUDIES, 2023 Vol. 75, No. 5, June 2023, 820–841 Coordinated Voting Against the Autocracy: The Case of the ‘Smart Vote’ Strategy in Russia MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV Abstract Is coordinated anti-regime voting by opposition-minded citizens possible in authoritarian settings where the opposition does not coalesce against the regime? If so, what are the factors behind the citizens’ (un)willingness to vote strategically for the opposition? This study investigates the ‘smart vote’ (umnoe golosovanie) strategy of Aleksei Naval’nyi in the 2020 subnational elections in Russia and shows that it boosted non-regime candidates’ electoral results countrywide. The article also finds that the willingness of anti-regime voters to behave strategically depends on the candidates’ opposition credentials, and that this willingness can be affected by the scope of voter intimidation available to the authorities. IN ORDER TO CHALLENGE THE AUTHORITARIAN STATUS QUO effectively, those opposing it have to solve a number of collective action problems (Tucker 2007; Schedler 2013). As Gandhi observes, ‘opposition to the dictatorship may be widespread, but it does not pose a threat to the regime unless it is organised’ (Gandhi 2008, p. 95). For this reason, the formation of opposition alliances is often considered an important step towards liberalising electoral outcomes (Howard & Roessler 2006). However, this step may be difficult when genuine critics of the regime are not allowed to run in elections, so that the electoral arena is open only to those actors who have been co-opted (Albrecht 2005; Schedler 2013). Does the exclusion of some opposition forces, and the co-optation of others, prevent opposition-minded voters from meaningful collective action in authoritarian elections? If it does not, what are the factors behind the citizens’ willingness to vote collectively for opposition candidates or to abstain from doing so? These are the questions this study seeks to answer. Prior research has shown that pre-electoral opposition coalitions may catalyse regime change in autocracies (Howard & Roessler 2006; Bunce & Wolchik 2010; Donno 2013; Wahman 2013). Another branch of the literature sheds a light on conditions calling antiincumbent coalitions into existence (Wahman 2011; Beissinger 2013; Gandhi & Reuter Supplemental data for this article can be accessed online at: https://doi.org/10.1080/09668136.2022.2147485. Disclosure statement: No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s). © 2022 University of Glasgow https://doi.org/10.1080/09668136.2022.2147485 COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 821 2013) and enabling them to pose credible threats to non-democratic rule (Ufen 2020; Ong 2022). Much less is known, however, about the micro-level dynamics between a coalition of opposition parties and their support base of opposition-minded voters (Gandhi & Ong 2019). In part, this lack of scholarly attention can be connected to the fact that, until recently, electoral autocracies have not faced coordination attempts by the opposition other than in the form of pre-electoral coalitions, calls for election boycotts or electionrelated street protests (Hafner-Burton et al. 2018). At the same time, with the spread of social media, which facilitate micro-level political coordination, collective anti-regime action at the individual level can be organised in autocracies more efficiently than ever in the past (Zhuravskaya et al. 2020), especially when citizens are called upon not to participate in street protests but rather in legitimate and relatively safe activities such as voting. This study expands the literature on electoral coordination in authoritarian regimes by moving the focus from studying coalitions of opposition parties to attempts to coordinate opposition-minded voters. By switching attention from the elite level to the individual-level dynamics of the authoritarian electoral game, this study contributes to the emerging literature on citizens’ responses to collective anti-regime electoral enterprises (Gandhi & Ong 2019) and electoral behaviour in autocracies (Letsa 2020). This article investigates anti-regime voter coordination by studying the smart vote (umnoe golosovanie) campaign launched by the Russian opposition politician Aleksei Naval’nyi in November 2018 and implemented in the 2019 and 2020 subnational elections. The key element of the campaign was an application enabling oppositionminded citizens to synchronise their voting against the main pro-regime party, United Russia (Edinaya Rossiya—UR), in single- or multi-member plurality electoral districts. The smart vote campaign provided opposition voters with advice on which opposition candidate to vote for in order to prevent the election of the UR candidate in the given district. Accordingly, the organisers of the smart vote campaign claimed that they selected those opposition candidates who enjoyed the highest levels of support at the district level,1 even though the exact criteria for selection were never explained in full. A recent study by Turchenko and Golosov (2021) demonstrated that, in the 2019 municipal elections in St Petersburg, Naval’nyi’s strategy was to encourage opposition-minded voters to support the candidates backed by the smart vote campaign, thus reducing the UR vote. This study expands from prior research in two ways. First, it investigates the nationwide effects of the smart vote campaign on a sample of 44 elections held in 2020 at different levels of Russia’s administrative structure. Second, the theoretical basis of the empirical analysis allows our findings on Russia to be placed in the wider cross-national context of ongoing research on authoritarian politics and electoral behaviour. Technically, Naval’nyi’s campaign resembled the vote advice applications (VAAs) that are increasingly significant in well-established democracies (Garzia & Marschall 2016; van der Linden & Vowles 2017). The literature on VAAs shows that these electronic tools have an impact on voter behaviour. VAAs can boost turnout (Alvarez et al. 2014), 1 See, ‘Kak my budem pobezhdat’ “Edinuyu Rossiyu” na vyborakh. Umnoe golosovanie’, Navalny.com, 28 November 2018, available at: https://navalny.com/p/6017/, accessed 9 August 2021. 822 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV especially amongst younger voters (Marschall & Schultze 2015), improve citizens’ political knowledge (Kamoen et al. 2015) and affect the political choices of undecided voters (Kleinnijenhuis et al. 2019). In this study, we explore the impact of online tools on voting behaviour under authoritarian rule, adding to the growing scholarship on the influence exerted by the internet upon the politics of autocracies. We posit that, even in authoritarian settings where opposition parties are excluded from electoral participation, disunited and/or co-opted by the regime, it is possible for opposition voters to coordinate against pro-regime agents across different electoral contexts. At the same time, as indicated in the literature on voter responses to pre-electoral coalitions (Gschwend & Hooghe 2008; Gandhi & Ong 2019), citizens may retract their support for an opposition coalition if it includes their least preferred party. Thus, we expect that opposition voters may have strong biases towards some of the permitted opposition parties, which are considered pro-regime rather than genuinely oppositional. Finally, we expect that the scope of collective voting is negatively related to the amount of intimidation to which an opposition voter may be exposed. As Hafner-Burton et al. argue, intimidation can ‘coerce would-be opposition voters into voting for the incumbent out of fear of reprisal for supporting the opposition’ (Hafner-Burton et al. 2018, p. 465). We test the above expectations by analysing district-level data on the general population of candidates across the whole set of the 2020 subnational elections in which the smart vote campaign was implemented, supplemented with information on repeat runners who participated in the previous elections of 2015 and subsequent byelections in the same districts or localities under the same party labels. We focus on district-level rather than individual-level data. One of the reasons for this approach is quite straightforward: there are no public opinion poll data on the conduct of the smart vote campaign, its public perception or its efficacy. At the same time, our focus on district-level data offers several advantages. First, district-level analysis is focused on the setting wherein voter coordination actually occurs (Crisp et al. 2012). Therefore, we are able to assess the output of voter coordination rather than mere intentions and to avoid specific survey problems, such as social sensitivity bias or preference falsification. Second, the comparison of repeat runners’ electoral results—some of whom enjoyed smart vote support, while others did not—enables the effects of the smart vote to be estimated with a high degree of confidence. Third, the district level of analysis allows us to take into account the political and societal contexts in which voting takes place. The article proceeds as follows. The next section presents a theoretical discussion of opposition coordination and collective anti-regime voting under authoritarianism. After that, we provide an overview of Russia’s electoral politics with a special emphasis on the changing strategies pursued by Russia’s anti-regime opposition. We then describe the data, specify our theoretical expectations, and develop testable hypotheses. Finally, we perform a series of empirical tests using a variety of statistical techniques. Opposition coordination and anti-regime voting under authoritarianism Elections serve ambivalent goals under authoritarianism (Schedler 2013). On the one hand, elections enable an authoritarian incumbent to sustain his grip on power (Brownlee 2007; Greene 2007; Gandhi 2008; Wright & Escribà-Folch 2012). On the other, elections COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 823 provide the political opposition with a way to challenge the authoritarian status quo, which may lead to liberalising political outcomes (Howard & Roessler 2006). The feasibility of such outcomes depends on the opposition’s ability to both coalesce and mobilise its supporters (Howard & Roessler 2006; Bunce & Wolchik 2010; Donno 2013; Wahman 2013). Most literature on opposition coordination under authoritarianism focuses on political parties. Wahman (2011) finds that opposition parties are more willing to unite when they believe in the possibility of victory and when the policy gap between them and the incumbent is deep. Gandhi and Reuter (2013) argue that opposition coalitions are more likely to form in the presence of an influential and long-standing opposition party. Beissinger (2013) shows that broad societal dissatisfaction with the incumbent regime facilitates the formation of negative coalitions across diverse partisan groupings. Ufen (2020), in his study of the 2018 Malaysian general election, identifies several factors that led the coalition of opposition parties to victory, including the ability to run strong joint candidates, ideological closeness and tight links with civil society groups. Ong (2022) also highlights the importance of joint campaigns conducted by opposition alliances in autocracies. Since a united opposition may pose a credible threat to autocratic rule, it is in the interests of a dictator to counteract any attempts by opposition parties to form coalitions. Some authoritarian regimes are capable of preventing parties or candidates that can pose a threat to the regime from entering the electoral arena (Golosov 2013). This strategy can be implemented openly, by banning the activities of certain parties for political reasons (Bogaards et al. 2010), or covertly, by introducing legislation with a plethora of detailed, seemingly technical requirements for party or candidate registration that cannot be met by opposition parties (Karvonen 2007). Some permitted parties may not have any significant programmatic or policy disagreements with the incumbent authorities; this can be characteristic of parties that are personal political vehicles (Lust-Okar 2008) or narrow interest-based groups (Tordoff & Young 1999). Other parties have distinct programmatic or policy stances that are not appealing to wide sectors of the electorate, attracting a small but steady following instead, allowing for their characterisation as niche parties (Wagner 2011). It is sometimes argued that the autocrats’ willingness to tolerate such formations contributes to the stability of authoritarian regimes (Albrecht 2005).2 To contain opposition attempts to coordinate at the level of political parties, incumbents may also co-opt key opposition figures and induce splits in the opposition camp (Schedler 2013, p. 91). Yet even in overtly authoritarian contexts, opposition electoral coordination may be highly consequential because a poor electoral performance by the leading pro-regime party can undermine the regime’s image of popular support and its internal cohesion (Smyth 2020, p. 25). Moreover, in such circumstances the regime may be forced to rely on outright electoral fraud, which increases the risks of post-election protests (Tucker 2007; Magaloni 2010; Hafner-Burton et al. 2018). Consider an authoritarian setting where multiparty competition is allowed and the set of competitors is comprised of candidates from the pro-regime party, independents and the 2 For an application of this argument to Russia, see Wilson (2016). 824 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV candidates of moderate opposition parties that are subordinated to the regime and unable or unwilling to join forces to challenge the status quo. It is theoretically important to disentangle the reasons why anti-regime voters may wish to vote collectively for candidates who are allowed to compete against the ruling party or to abstain from doing so in such circumstances. Purely anti-regime voters in an autocracy are so defined because they support neither the overtly pro-regime parties nor those moderate parties that are perceived by these voters as regime affiliates. Therefore, the behaviour of such voters, if not manifest in the form of abstention, falls into the category of strategic voting. As defined in a scholarly tradition launched by Duverger (1954) and featuring, amongst others, a seminal contribution by Cox (1997), strategic voting is insincere instrumental voting.3 Typically, strategic voting in democracies takes place when a voter is willing to vote for their second most preferred party if the more preferred party is unlikely to win, particularly if there is a close contest between the second- and third-ranked parties. As demonstrated by a mounting number of studies reviewed in a recent volume published by Stephenson et al. (2018), strategic voting takes many shapes, depending on the structure of the party system, electoral rules and other country-specific factors. Irrespective of this diversity, the defining features of strategic voting are that it does not express the true preferences of the elector, and that it is used instrumentally by the voter to affect election outcomes.4 In a democracy, the calculus of strategic voting can be expressed as follows: R = PB + D – C (Riker & Ordeshook 1968, p. 28). In this model, R is the reward obtained by the voter, B is the expected benefit from voting for the preferred candidate, D is the benefit from doing the civic duty of voting, and C stands for the costs of voting. P is the probability that the citizen will, by voting, get the benefit, B. In an autocracy, instrumental benefits are not in the calculus of anti-regime strategic voting. An alternative instrumental motivation, still available for anti-regime voters, is inflicting harm on the regime. To explain this possible motivation, it is useful to review the gains that the autocrat seeks to derive from successful performance at the polls. We will concentrate on an institutional setting that is empirically most relevant to this study, that of elections to multimember assemblies. Of course, the primary goal of incumbent authorities, in autocracies as well as in democracies, is to retain power by winning a majority of seats for the ruling party. In consolidated autocracies, autocrats are normally able to achieve not only this goal but also to convince voters that they will not give up power in any circumstances. However, the scope of the ruling party’s electoral success also matters. Stable, consolidated authoritarian regimes tend to win elections by a large margin. Indeed, ‘supermajoritarian election outcomes and high turnout generate an image of invincibility 3 Of course, electoral authoritarianism does not exclude the possibility of sincere expressive or instrumental voting for the government or for the regime-controlled opposition (Frye et al. 2017). However, much of the reasoning about strategic voting is irrelevant to autocracies simply because there is no party of first preference for those voters who reject the regime in its entirety. 4 A specific form of insincere voting that can be observed in democracies is the so-called ‘protest voting’ when votes are cast for ideologically extreme or otherwise unacceptable parties, irrespective of their viability or coalition potential, in order to punish the parties of first preference for their perceived policy pitfalls (Alvarez et al. 2018). COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 825 that works to dissuade potential elite challenges, particularly those coming from powerful party officials’ (Magaloni & Kricheli 2010, p. 128). Such election outcomes also project an image of wholehearted majority support for the autocrat, which discourages opposition activism at the grassroots level and hinders the organisational development of anti-regime parties (Simpser 2013). Besides, the ruling party’s poor performance at the polls naturally enhances the representation of the officially allowed opposition parties in the assembly, hence increasing their bargaining capacity. Ultimately, this not only entails heavy bargaining costs for the autocratic executive but also facilitates these parties’ autonomy from the regime. Increases in the autonomy of such formations may be highly consequential in the process of regime transformation if, for whatever reason, it occurs during the assembly tenure (Mainwaring 1988). Thus, voting for the officially allowed opposition parties can inflict damage on the regime. The scope of this damage is determined by the probability of reducing the assembly representation of the dominant pro-regime party, which is necessarily tied to the corresponding growth in the representation of the official opposition. This makes it possible to rewrite the above formula for strategic voting as follows by replacing the PB term with PH, where H stands for the harm inflicted on the regime by reducing the scope of its electoral support and the size of the assembly delegation of the dominant pro-regime party. Upon this replacement, the above formula remains theoretically valid for authoritarian conditions not only due to the above argument, which supports the inclusion of the PH term but also because it can be reasonably expected that, for some anti-regime voters, the notion of voting as a civic duty remains meaningful (Gandhi & Ong 2019; Letsa 2020), and because the costs of voting occur irrespective of the political context (Riker & Ordeshook 1968, p. 27). This being said, it is important to supplement the above formula by adding three components that are specific to authoritarian conditions. First, anti-regime voters under authoritarianism often feel politically isolated and powerless, and see legitimate political participation as meaningless (Conaghan 2005). These feelings can be assuaged by a perceivably meaningful yet relatively risk-free opposition activity such as strategic voting. Such satisfaction is likely to be greater when there are reasons to view strategic voting as a concerted collective action rather than an act of individual resistance. Second, Gschwend and Hooghe (2008) find that in a democracy, party supporters are likely to refuse their support to a coalition of which their party is a member if they dislike their party’s coalition partner. Gandhi and Ong (2019), who studied voters’ commitment to opposition coalitions in a dictatorship, came to a similar conclusion. In a similar vein, anti-regime voters may refuse to support at the polls those parties not perceived to have a credible opposition stance. Thus, anti-regime strategic voting in an autocracy is influenced by the degree of aversion felt by opposition voters towards such parties. Third, anti-regime strategic voting under authoritarianism can be more costly for the voter than is normally the case in democracies. These costs are higher when regime agents are able to control the voting process and to intimidate voters (Frye et al. 2014, 2019; Hafner-Burton et al. 2018). In these conditions it may be less costly for an antiregime voter to abandon their strategic choice than to be punished. In particular, the wide use of economic coercion to mobilise voters in Russia’s elections has been documented in the literature (Frye et al. 2014). 826 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV Fourth, perceptions of outright election fraud can affect voters’ willingness to behave strategically. If election returns are widely believed to be rigged, there is no reason to support opposition candidates because they can be expected to lose anyway. Nevertheless, rational abstention from voting, while observable in many authoritarian regimes, does not make much sense because under the conditions of fraudulent elections, turnout figures can be falsified by the authorities in order to ensure that their legitimacy claims are met, a phenomenon widely observed in contemporary Russia (Moser & White 2017) and in other autocracies (Lindberg 2005). Under such conditions, opposition-minded voters can cast their votes against the official candidates either on the assumption that the ‘true’ results of the elections will be known by the authorities anyway, so that the dissatisfaction of the populace will not go unnoticed, or on the assumption that a greater turnout of opposition-minded voters will make electoral manipulation risker and more difficult for the regime (Golosov 2018). Opposition strategies in Russia’s authoritarian elections In the middle of the 2000s under the presidency of Vladimir Putin, Russia underwent a transformation from an unconsolidated democracy (Shevchenko & Golosov 2001) into an authoritarian regime that restricted civil liberties, controlled the media, and subverted the court system (Hassner 2008). Two aspects of this transformation were particularly consequential for electoral politics. By abolishing direct gubernatorial elections in the regions, the Kremlin co-opted subnational elites and put them at the service of the newly created dominant party, United Russia (Reuter 2017). Even more important was the political party reform implemented in the period 2004–2007. As many as 60 parties had been legally recognised in 2001–2004 (Golosov 2006). By introducing highly restrictive party registration requirements, coupled with the prohibition on party blocs at the national and regional level, the authorities managed to drastically reduce the number of parties to 15 by the end of 2007, and to just six by the end of 2009. The surviving parties were placed under the permanent threat of dissolution, which severely limited their autonomy from the regime and undermined their willingness to form coalitions with each other (Gel’man 2008; Gandhi & Reuter 2013, p. 145; Gill 2015, p. 114; Hutcheson 2018). In the 2011 parliamentary election, only four parties were able to cross the 7% legal threshold of representation, including UR and three parties of the permitted opposition: the Communist Party of the Russian Federation (Kommunisticheskaya Partiya Rossiiskoi Federatsii—KPRF), the nationalist and statist formation misleadingly called the Liberal Democratic Party of Russia (Liberal’no Demokraticheskaya Partiya Rossii—LDPR), and a self-described centre-left party, called A Just Russia (Spravedlivaya Rossiya) led by one of Putin’s close political associates. Despite these sterile conditions, UR’s share of the vote, as officially reported, declined from 64.3% in 2007 to 49.5% in 2011.5 5 See, the websites of the Central Election Commission of Russia (Tsentral’naya izbiratel’naya komissiya Rossiiskoi Federatsii), available at: http://izbirkom.ru/region/izbirkom and http://cikrf.ru, accessed 25 April 2021. COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 827 There were multiple reasons for UR’s less than successful performance in the 2011 elections. One of them can be linked to the strategy proposed by one of the opposition leaders, Aleksei Naval’nyi, who called for the voters to support any party except UR, which he referred to as ‘the party of crooks and thieves’ (White & McAllister 2014; Ross 2015; Smyth 2020). Although this term reflected the emotional tone of Naval’nyi’s campaign, a significant strategic component was also in place. Rather than urging voters to support parties that were ideologically distant from the regime, Naval’nyi emphasised the ability of the official opposition parties to win seats, thereby reducing the representation of UR. While it is impossible to estimate the consequences of Naval’nyi’s strategy with any degree of precision, it is worth noting that in the 2011 elections, all parties of the official opposition enhanced their results. In the aftermath of the 2011 elections, the authorities softened registration requirements for political parties. As a result, the number of parties greatly increased (Golosov 2014b). But anti-regime opposition parties, including Naval’nyi’s party,6 remained unregistered on various technical pretexts (Flikke 2016). At the same time, many of the newly registered entities were allowed into the electoral arena to split the vote (Golosov 2015), with the expectation that the increased number of wasted votes would skew the seat distributions in favour of UR. The results of the 2011 elections made the authorities reconsider their approach to proportional representation. During the previous period of political development, proportional representation had been introduced to consolidate United Russia. That goal achieved, its continued unlimited use was too risky. In 2013 and thereafter, the use of proportional representation was gradually subjected to limitations both at the national and subnational levels of electoral politics. In particular, this included the restoration of a mixed electoral system, with half the deputies to be elected in single-member districts by the plurality rule in the national legislative elections. These reforms made it imperative for Naval’nyi, who had, by 2018, emerged as a major figure in Russia’s opposition camp (Dollbaum 2020; Kazun & Semykina 2020), to refine his electoral strategy. On the one hand, the proliferation of parties undermined the strategy of voting for any other party except UR because under the new conditions, the gains of this strategy would be swept away by the high levels of vote wasting. On the other, the increased importance of single-member district races made it possible to employ them, quite consistently with international experience, as a major hub for strategic voting. In November 2018, Naval’nyi announced the smart vote campaign. Its main purpose was to urge opposition-minded voters to behave strategically by casting their votes for non-UR candidates who had a reasonable chance of defeating the UR candidates. It was widely recognised that Naval’nyi’s campaign had a significant impact on the results of the September 2019 regional legislative elections in Moscow (Dollbaum 2019; Bol’shakov & Perevalov 2020). One study presented empirically verified evidence that this was also the case in the concurrent municipal elections in St Petersburg (Turchenko & Golosov 2021). 6 In 2012 through 2019, Naval’nyi attempted to obtain official registration for his party under the names of People’s Alliance (Narodnyi Al’yans, 2012), Party of Progress (Partiya Progressa, 2014), and Russia of the Future (Rossiya Budushchego, 2018). None of these attempts was successful. 828 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV Evidence on the 2019 smart vote campaign from other regions is scarce, and it is not clear whether this strategy was efficient outside the biggest cities, where the share of pro-democracy voters is relatively high (Greene & Robertson 2019). In September 2020, the smart vote strategy was adopted in a greater number of localities, including non-capital cities. The theoretical argument presented in the previous section allows for the systematic juxtaposition of Naval’nyi’s smart vote strategy with the expected properties of antiregime voting under authoritarianism. The core element of this model is the PH term. The loading of the H term was the same as in 2011, as it was assumed that by defeating UR’s candidates at the polls, anti-regime voters could inflict significant harm on the regime. The main emphasis was on the P component. Indeed, a major challenge for the strategy stemmed from the fact that in multi-candidate races, it was difficult to establish which of the allowed opposition candidates had a reasonable chance of success. Naval’nyi developed a set of online information resources that would assist the voters in identifying viable candidates across a range of elections. In the 2020 elections, these resources included a webpage, an application for both iOS and Android devices, and a Telegram bot. A voter would receive advice on how to cast a ballot in a given electoral district by simply providing their address. The main difference between the smart vote strategy and VAAs is that, in democratic settings, the main purpose of VAAs is to match users to specific political parties in accordance with ideological or policy preferences (Garzia & Marschall 2016, p. 377), while the primary purpose of the smart vote campaign was to enhance the electoral viability of non-UR candidates not closely linked to the regime. While the stated purpose of the smart vote campaign was to reduce the representation of United Russia in representative assemblies, which was to be achieved by supporting those non-UR candidates who had a reasonable chance of winning,7 little is known about how Naval’nyi’s team actually selected these candidates. As Naval’nyi himself explained, albeit in very general terms, ‘in order [to place the strongest non-UR candidates onto the smart vote list], we are going to simply analyse previous election returns. Plus, [we have to conduct] opinion polls. Plus, let’s say it bluntly, it is often clear which of the candidates is the strongest one’.8 The role of opinion polls is particularly unclear. Even if some polling had been conducted by the Naval’nyi team in the run-up to the most important elections, such as the 2019 regional elections in Moscow (Naval’nyi 2019), it was impossible to conduct meaningful survey research aimed at establishing most viable candidates in thousands of municipal elections in which the smart vote campaign was implemented in 2019–2020. The resources available to the political organisations led by Naval’nyi, including his Anti-Corruption Foundation and the network of locally-based organisations that operated under the name of Shtaby Naval’nogo (Naval’nyi Headquarters) were not negligible, but they were obviously insufficient for large-scale 7 For a systematic exposition of the strategy by one of its key ideologists and organisers, see ‘Leonid Volkov ob “umnom golosovanii”’, Novaya gazeta, 3 December 2018, available at: https://newtimes.ru/ articles/detail/173927, accessed 9 August 2021. 8 See, ‘Kak my budem pobezhdat’ “Edinuyu Rossiyu” na vyborakh. Umnoe golosovanie’, Navalny.com, 28 November 2018, available at: https://navalny.com/p/6017/, accessed 9 August 2021. COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 829 opinion polling, even according to the otherwise very optimistic accounts of Naval’nyi’s supporters (Dergachev et al. 2021). Thus it would be reasonable to suggest that in most cases, Naval’nyi’s analysts relied on previous election returns or, in the absence of such information for the first-time runners, on subjective assessments based on their understanding of the political situation in a given locality and factors such as a candidate’s personal popularity, their embeddedness in political networks, and their finances and media resourcefulness. Of course, there is no reason to assume that such assessments were necessarily correct, but even if they were inaccurate, the recommendations of the smart vote campaign could still be consequential for coordinated anti-regime voting, which is central to our inquiry. Turning to the voter side of the smart vote strategy, and consistent with our theoretical reasoning, anecdotal evidence suggests that there were several motivations for coordinated anti-regime voting. As explained by one voter, ‘why did I turn out? Because it is my civic duty, because there is smart voting, because I do not want the hegemony of UR to persist’.9 The component of satisfaction brought by participation in collective action was also quite prominent in the smart vote campaign. As put by Naval’nyi in his pre-election appeal to the voters, ‘this is our first experience of organised collective action. The strategy of the authorities is wholly aimed at suppressing our will and cultivating powerlessness. Remember that we are not powerless, just unorganised. To take part in smart voting is a step towards organisation’.10 The costs of voting also could be significant because, as noted in the literature, many Russians are vulnerable to electoral intimidation, especially if they are employed in the public sector (Forrat 2018) or in statedependent firms (Frye et al. 2014, 2019). In other respects, the costs of voting in Russia are relatively low (Birch et al. 2002). The empirical setting and hypotheses The empirical setting for this study is the September 2020 subnational elections in Russia. All these elections were conducted concurrently on the so-called ‘unified day of voting’ (edinyi den’ golosovaniya) when, according to the Russian law, it is imperative to hold the majority of elections at the different levels of the country’s complex administrative structure. The 2020 campaign embraced legislative elections in 11 out of the 85 federal units (regions) of Russia and city council elections in 22 regional capitals. In addition, there were plenty of local contests, including city council elections in 12 cities with more than 200,000 inhabitants.11 There were also many races in smaller localities, but they are not addressed in this study because the smart vote campaign did not reach that level. 9 See, ‘V Peterburge—rekordno nizkaya yavka na vyborakh. Chitateli “Bumagi” rasskazyvayut, pochemu vse zhe poshli golosovat’’, Bumaga, 9 September 2019, available at: http://paperpaper.ru/v-peterburgerekordno-nizkaya-yavka-n/, accessed 25 March 2021. 10 See, ‘Obrashchenie v “den’ tishiny”’, Navalny.com, 7 September 2019, available at: http://navalny.com/ p/6227/, accessed 25 March 2021. 11 One of these cities, Sterlitamak, had to be excluded from this study because there was no smart vote campaign there. 830 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV Chief executive (gubernatorial) elections were also held in 18 regions. In these elections, however, the Naval’nyi team advised voting for any candidate except the incumbent or, if the incumbent was not on the ballot, except the candidate explicitly supported by the Russian federal executive. The reason is that under a two-round majority system employed in these elections, vote-wasting in the first round would be inconsequential. The smart vote campaign did not provide any advice regarding preferable choices in party list elections that were incorporated into the mixed electoral systems of many localities. None of them, however, used purely proportional systems. Thus, the overall number of elections in this study is 44.12 They took place, at different levels, in 29 regions of Russia, making for a diverse sample that is broadly representative of the nationwide voting patterns. In the 44 elections under investigation, as many as 1,082 seats were contested in singlemember districts and 85 in multimember districts. The specific effects of multimember plurality rules in Russia’s subnational elections are not negligible, but they are addressed in detail elsewhere (Golosov & Turchenko 2021). Overall, 1,167 seats were at stake. The number of the smart vote campaign nominees was 1,155. Comprehensive lists of these candidates were not published by campaign organisers. Our data on the candidates selected for the smart vote list were derived mostly from the Telegram bot (@smartvotebot). To get the available recommendations, we followed the routine recommended to all voters, which was to provide the bot with addresses located within specific districts drawn for a given election. Maps or descriptions of electoral districts were extracted from the official websites of legislative or representative bodies that were to be elected in 2020. As of March 2021, the smart vote recommendations were no longer available. An important peculiarity of the 2020 subnational elections in Russia was the unprecedented spread of early voting countrywide. The Central Election Commission of Russia (Tsentral’naya izbiratel’naya komissiya Rossiiskoi Federatsii) sanctioned formal provision for this on 24 July 2020, having established that the main election day, 13 September, would be preceded by two days of early voting. The official explanation of such a provision was that early voting served the purpose to make the electoral process ‘as comfortable as possible’ for voters during the COVID-19 pandemic. Indeed, as is widely recognised from previous experience, early voting in Russia limits the scope of electoral observation, facilitates the intimidation of state-dependent voters, and simplifies the use of electoral malpractice in many other ways (Bader 2016). A Russian election watchdog, Golos, reported numerous cases when early voting was used to control voter turnout in the September 2020 elections.13 Twenty political parties ran their candidates in different localities, and a solid number of independents also contested the elections. In sum, there were 4,505 non-UR candidates, who, ipso facto, had a chance of receiving votes via the smart vote campaign. Table 1 presents the distribution of smart vote support across different party affiliations for the full sample of candidates. The Table also reports detailed data on independents and five parties with the 12 The list of the included elections is presented in Table A1 in the online Appendix. ‘Itogi obshchestvennogo nablyudeniya za vyborami v edinyi den’ golosovaniya 13 sentyabrya 2020 goda’, Golosinfo.org, 15 October 2020, available at: https://www.golosinfo.org/articles/144816#2-2, accessed 17 July 2021. 13 COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 831 TABLE 1 NUMBERS AND ELECTORAL RESULTS OF CANDIDATES IN THE SEPTEMBER 2020 SUBNATIONAL ELECTIONS Smart vote KPRF LDPR A Just Russia Independents Motherland Yabloko Others Total/Mean Others N Mean vote share N Mean vote share 615 119 181 152 25 41 22 1,155 0.22 0.19 0.22 0.24 0.37 0.16 0.25 0.22 386 818 683 647 108 80 628 3,350 0.15 0.09 0.09 0.10 0.08 0.05 0.07 0.10 Note: All observed differences in means are significant at the 0.1% level (p < 0.001) in both independent t-tests and Wilcoxon rank sum tests (all two-tailed). Sources: Central Election Commission of the Russian Federation (Tsentral’naya izbiratel’naya komissiya Rossiiskoi Federatsii), available at: http://izbirkom.ru/region/izbirkom, accessed 9 August 2021; collected by the authors from the Telegram bot (@smartvotebot) of the smart vote campaign. highest numbers of nominees supported by the smart vote campaign: the KPRF, the LDPR, A Just Russia, Yabloko (Rossiiskaya Ob’’edinennaya Demokraticheskaya Partiya Yabloko), and a minor nationalist party, Motherland (Rodina). As many as 981 out of 1,155 candidates backed by the smart vote campaign were nominated by these parties, with a majority belonging to the first three of them, while 152 smart vote candidates ran as independents. Thus, smart vote support was heavily biased in favour of the main parties of the official opposition and independents. Table A2 in the online Appendix proves that this approach was consistent with the stated goals of the smart vote campaign: both in 2020 and in the previous elections of 2015, these categories of candidates tended to be more successful than the candidates nominated by minor parties. It is important to mention that, learning from their experience of 2019, the organisers of the 2020 smart vote campaign made their recommendations available briefly before the elections. As a result, the authorities were left without an opportunity to deny registration to the smart vote candidates. With only one exception, all of them remained on the ballot on election day. Turning to our working hypotheses, a note on the 2019 smart vote campaign is in order. In major urban localities, Moscow and St Petersburg, the results of the elections met the expectations of the smart vote campaign organisers in the sense that the shares of seats held by United Russia in the elected assembly did indeed decrease quite visibly. In Moscow, 20 deputies were elected to the city Duma (45 seats) with the support of the smart vote, which was the best result obtained by opposition candidates since the early 2000s (Dollbaum 2019). Naval’nyi called the outcome of the smart vote campaign in Moscow ‘fantastic’,14 even though Yabloko-linked scholars, particularly Bol’shakov and Perevalov (2020), asserted that, while the smart vote campaign had helped some 14 ‘Pobeda!’, Navalny.com, 9 September 2019, available at: https://navalny.com/p/6228/, accessed 9 August 2021. 832 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV opposition candidates, it had been a hurdle to others. However, the exact effects of the smart vote campaign in Moscow on the electoral performance of United Russia are difficult to estimate: officially, this party’s candidates did not contest the 2019 elections at all, running as independents instead; and, more importantly, the Moscow data do not allow for inference about how the smart vote campaign affected the performance of opposition candidates. The results of the 2019 smart vote campaign in St Petersburg were analysed at length in a previous article (Turchenko & Golosov 2021). In St Petersburg, 5,305 registered candidates were running for 1,560 mandates in the municipal assemblies. Of these, 1,313 people were supported by the smart vote campaign. Each constituency had its own set of candidates. However, the same people ran in different constituencies simultaneously (289 people). A total of 94 candidates running in different constituencies had smart vote support in some constituencies but not in others. Turchenko and Golosov (2021) compared the electoral results achieved by these candidates in different constituencies and found they were higher in those constituencies where smart vote support was provided. The accuracy of this conclusion was ascertained by comparing the results achieved by only those 78 out of 94 candidates who had been nominated in different constituencies with the support of the same party or as non-party candidates. A significant difference was found between the results achieved by the same candidates with or without the smart vote support, so that smart vote support provided the candidates with a surplus of about 7% of the vote on average (Turchenko & Golosov 2021, p. 72). But the question of the campaign’s efficacy in other localities remains open. As Turchenko and Golosov note, St Petersburg may be a most-likely place for the ‘smart vote’ strategy to be efficient because, in the city, the share of pro-democracy voters is relatively high. By the same token, the impact of the ‘smart vote’ strategy could be different in regions with greater shares of loyalist voters (Turchenko & Golosov 2021, pp. 75–6). One of the purposes of our current analysis is to resolve this problem. Based on the model of strategic anti-regime voting presented in this article, we expect that the intention of anti-regime voters to inflict harm on the regime, when coupled with two other theoretically possible motives, the desire to perform the civic duty of voting and to receive satisfaction from a risk-free opposition activity, affected elections results. This leads us to the following hypothesis (H1), that smart vote support systematically boosted the electoral results of its supported candidates across different-level electoral campaigns. The smart vote campaign aimed to improve coordination amongst opposition voters by directing their support to the strongest non-UR candidate. Yet for many opposition-minded voters, the programmatic and/or policy stances of the strongest parties of the officially allowed opposition, the KPRF, the LDPR and A Just Russia, were unacceptable because they could be considered part of the regime, thus being no different from UR. Aversion to these parties can be strong. Based on this logic, we propose the second hypothesis (H2), that the impact of the smart vote (if any) would be lower for the candidates of the three major official opposition parties than for the nominees of other parties and independents. The third hypothesis (H3) addresses the costs of voting from the angle of intimidation by authorities. As mentioned above, many Russian voters are vulnerable to electoral intimidation. The share of early voters in the 2020 elections was unprecedented. It could COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 833 have affected the efficacy of the smart vote campaign because early voting endows regime agents with an increased capacity to intimidate vulnerable groups of voters (such as college or university undergraduates, workers of state-owned or large private firms, or public employees) and to direct their electoral choices. Our hypothesis is thus that the impact of the smart vote (if any) would be lower if more people voted early. A caveat regarding the third hypothesis is in order. While we expect that large-scale early voting, resulting from the three-day extension for the ballot, would have affected the choices of anti-regime voters, it could also be utilised to mobilise regime supporters and/or politically indifferent voters. At the same time, the authorities could have used early voting to hide electoral fraud, thus making the impact of the smart vote campaign less apparent than it would have been in one-day elections. The structure of our data does not allow us to disentangle these aspects of early voting. Empirical analysis and findings According to the first hypothesis (H1), smart vote support would increase the electoral results of the opposition candidates across different-level electoral campaigns. Preliminary evidence in support of this expectation is reported in Table 1. Consistent with our expectations, the mean results of the smart vote candidates of different affiliations are higher than those of other candidates. However, the interpretation of this finding is complicated by a methodological problem also found in research on strategic voting in different national settings (Alvarez & Nagler 2000). Do smart vote candidates obtain higher results due to strategic voting, or do they perform better because their personal resources or previous electoral experience, as perceived by the proponents and crafters of the strategy, lead to their inclusion onto the smart vote list? To resolve this problem, we relied on a quasi-experimental approach similar to the one used in a study of the effects of campaign spending upon the electoral returns of individual candidates in the elections to the US Congress (Levitt 1994). The approach is focused on the observed cross-temporal differences in the electoral results of those candidates who ran both in the elections under investigation and in the previous elections held in the same districts or localities under unchanged party labels. Such candidates are conventionally referred to as ‘repeat runners’. Previous research on electoral politics in Russia has established that such candidates are widespread but rarely successful if they do not enjoy the advantage of incumbency (Golosov 2014a), which is consistent with evidence from different national electoral arenas (Squire & Smith 1984). The presence of such candidates does however generate valuable data on how temporal variation in the availability of certain resources, be it campaign funds or inclusion on the smart vote list, affects electoral performance. Thus, it becomes possible to control for candidates’ assets in statistical analysis. In this study, we identify several categories of repeat runners. Overall, as many as 1,030 candidates in the 2020 elections had contested seats in the same representative assemblies under the same party affiliations (or lack thereof) in the 2015 elections or, in several cases, in the 2016–2019 byelections. In 2020, 213 out of these 1,030 repeat runners were backed by the smart vote campaign, while 517 candidates were continuously affiliated with UR. In addition, there was a group of 300 repeat runners who were neither 834 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV TABLE 2 MEAN OF THE DIFFERENCES IN THE RESULTS OF REPEAT CANDIDATES IN THE 2020 AND PREVIOUS SUBNATIONAL ELECTIONS IN RUSSIA Test statistic (two-tailed) Level Full sample Regions Capitals Cities Groups N Mean of the differences Dependent ttest Wilcoxon signedrank test Smart vote-supported candidates Other non-UR candidates UR candidates Smart vote-supported candidates Other non-UR candidates UR candidates Smart vote-supported candidates Other non-UR candidates UR candidates Smart vote-supported candidates Other non-UR candidates UR candidates 213 0.05 0.00*** 0.00*** 300 517 50 0.00 −0.06 0.02 0.62 0.00*** 0.10 0.64 0.00*** 0.11 62 116 114 −0.00 −0.06 0.05 0.70 0.00*** 0.00*** 0.84 0.00*** 0.00*** 203 283 49 −0.00 −0.07 0.09 0.85 0.00*** 0.00** 0.80 0.00*** 35 118 0.03 −0.03 0.06† 0.09† 0.00** 0.11 0.07† Notes: †p < 0.10; *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001. Sources: Central Election Commission of the Russian Federation (Tsentral’naya izbiratel’naya komissiya Rossiiskoi Federatsii), available at: http://izbirkom.ru/region/izbirkom, accessed 9 August 2021; collected by the authors from the Telegram bot (@smartvotebot) of the smart vote campaign. supported by the smart vote campaign nor affiliated with UR. From a methodological perspective, such repeat runners can be viewed as a control group. Table 2 presents test statistics to estimate the differences between the results received by different categories of repeat runners in 2020 in comparison to the previous elections.15 As shown both by the dependent t-test and the Wilcoxon signed-rank test, candidates backed by the smart vote campaign improved their results markedly, while those of the candidates in the control group did not change significantly.16 The results of UR’s candidates deteriorated quite visibly, which is probably attributable to the declining popularity of the party. In their entirety, these findings allow for the conclusion that the smart vote support did enhance the electoral performance of those candidates who received it. As a second step in this analysis, we posit that, if H1 holds, then the differences amongst the electoral returns of the candidates supported by the smart vote campaign will be greater than amongst the candidates of other groups because of the impact of strategic voting. Based on the results of the one-way independent ANOVA and the Kruskal–Wallis test, reported in Table A3 in the online Appendix, we conclude that the expected differences do exist. Moreover, as shown in the post hoc tests presented in Table A4 in the online Appendix 15 Mean vote shares were taken for those repeat runners who ran in more than one election in 2015–2019. It is important to mention that the smart vote effect was stronger in the subsamples of regional capitals and other cities than in the subsample of regional legislative elections that comprised both urban and rural electoral districts, and where more than three-quarters of all non-UR candidates (see Table A2 in the online Appendix) were affiliated with major official opposition parties. 16 COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 835 and visualised in Figure A1 in the online Appendix, the differences are statistically significant when the smart vote group is compared to the other groups for the full sample and, with some exceptions, for the subsamples defined by different types of elections. This adds to the systematic evidence supporting our first hypothesis. To test our second (H2) and third (H3) hypotheses, we performed several OLS regression analyses with fixed effects. Individual non-UR candidates were units of analysis, and their electoral results, measured as absolute vote shares, constituted the dependent variable. To test H2, we built an interaction term between the smart vote support dummy variable and a candidate’s affiliation with any of the three main official opposition parties, also expressed as a dichotomous variable. In a similar vein, H3 was tested by using an interaction term between the smart vote support dummy and the share of votes cast before the main election day. The analyses were performed on the full sample of candidates and on the three subsamples defined by the levels of elections,17 which allowed for assessing the smart vote effect under varying environmental constraints. We expected to see a stronger effect in regional capital cities, as their populations are younger and better educated than at the level of regions with both rural and urban settlements, as well as at the level of smaller cities. We ran two identically designed models for each sample: the first model does not contain interactions while the second does. All models clustered errors at the electoral district level. The district-level controls included, first, a dummy variable expressing the absence of UR’s nominee (1, otherwise 0)18 and second, the overall number of candidates in the district. Candidate-level controls included the age, gender, a dummy for repeat runners (1, otherwise 0), and a dummy for incumbents (1, otherwise 0). The summary statistics of the variables are reported in Table A5 in the online Appendix. Table 3 reports the results regarding the vote shares received by non-UR candidates. The coefficients of the smart vote support variable are positive and significant in all models. This is consistent with the results obtained when testing H1 and indicates that these results remain valid after controlling for a variety of district- and individual-level factors. It is also important to mention that the coefficient of the smart vote support is bigger for the subsample of regional capitals. The interaction term between the smart vote support dummy and the affiliation with one of the main opposition parties is significant for the full sample, as well as for two out of the three subsamples. As Figure 1 (plot A) and Figure A2 (plots A1 and A2) in the online Appendix indicate, candidates’ affiliations with the main official opposition parties did, as expected, reduce the advantage stemming from the smart vote support. Figure 1 (plot A) demonstrates that the smart vote support improved the results of the candidates affiliated with main official opposition parties by 14%, while for the independents and candidates affiliated with other parties, an improvement by 18% can be observed. In the subsample of non-capital city 17 Single-member plurality systems were in use in all but two localities. Controlling for multimember electoral districts by a dummy variable did not change the output presented in Table 3 (results are not shown, available on request from the authors). 18 No such instances were registered in regional legislative elections, which explains the absence of this variable in the related model. For multimember plurality districts, the variable was defined as the absolute share of seats contested by United Russia. Full sample Smart vote support Major official opposition parties Early voting 0.10*** (0.00) 0.01 (0.00) −0.14*** (0.02) SV × Major official opposition parties SV × Early voting Lack of formal UR nominee Number of candidates per district Age Gender Incumbency Repeat runners Constant Election FE Region FE Observations R 2/R 2 adjusted 0.10*** (0.01) −0.01*** (0.00) 0.00*** (0.00) −0.01* (0.00) 0.25*** (0.02) 0.02*** (0.00) 0.12*** (0.01) Yes Yes 4,505 0.403/ 0.398 Regions (2) 0.18*** (0.01) 0.01*** (0.00) −0.05** (0.02) −0.03** (0.01) −0.27*** (0.03) 0.10*** (0.01) −0.01*** (0.00) 0.00*** (0.00) −0.01* (0.00) 0.25*** (0.02) 0.02*** (0.00) 0.09*** (0.01) Yes Yes 4,505 0.425/ 0.420 Capitals (3) (4) (5) 0.08*** (0.01) 0.01* (0.01) −0.20*** (0.01) 0.17*** (0.03) 0.02*** (0.01) −0.14*** (0.01) −0.05† (0.03) −0.21*** (0.03) 0.13*** (0.01) 0.00 (0.00) −0.35*** (0.04) −0.02*** (0.00) 0.00* (0.00) −0.01 (0.00) 0.15*** (0.04) 0.01† (0.01) 0.20*** (0.02) N/A Yes 823 0.520/ 0.509 −0.02*** (0.00) 0.00* (0.00) −0.01 (0.00) 0.14*** (0.04) 0.01† (0.01) 0.19*** (0.02) N/A Yes 823 0.551/ 0.540 0.07*** (0.01) −0.01*** (0.00) 0.00*** (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.23*** (0.03) 0.01* (0.01) 0.16*** (0.01) N/A Yes 2,804 0.473/ 0.467 Cities (6) 0.21*** (0.01) 0.01*** (0.00) −0.26*** (0.04) −0.05*** (0.01) −0.37*** (0.06) 0.07*** (0.01) −0.01*** (0.00) 0.00*** (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.23*** (0.03) 0.01* (0.01) 0.14*** (0.01) N/A Yes 2,804 0.489/ 0.483 (7) 0.06*** (0.01) −0.01 (0.01) −0.07* (0.04) 0.12*** (0.02) −0.00 (0.00) 0.00** (0.00) −0.04*** (0.01) 0.31*** (0.04) 0.03* (0.02) 0.11*** (0.03) N/A Yes 878 0.324/ 0.312 (8) 0.11*** (0.02) −0.01 (0.01) −0.01 (0.04) 0.01 (0.02) −0.19*** (0.04) 0.12*** (0.02) −0.00 (0.00) 0.00** (0.00) −0.03*** (0.01) 0.31*** (0.04) 0.03* (0.02) 0.10*** (0.03) N/A Yes 878 0.338/ 0.324 Notes: †p < 0.10; *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001. Robust standard errors clustered on electoral district in parentheses. Individual non-UR candidates are units of analysis. Sources: Central Election Commission of the Russian Federation (Tsentral’naya izbiratel’naya komissiya Rossiiskoi Federatsii), available at: http://izbirkom.ru/region/izbirkom, accessed 9 August 2021; collected by the authors from the Telegram bot (@smartvotebot) of the smart vote campaign. MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV (1) 836 TABLE 3 SMART VOTE SUPPORT UPON THE VOTE SHARES RECEIVED BY NON -UR CANDIDATES IN THE 2020 SUBNATIONAL ELECTIONS (OLS MODELS , COEFFICIENTS / STANDARD ERRORS IN PARENTHESES ) COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 837 FIGURE 1. MARGINAL EFFECTS OF THE SMART VOTE SUPPORT ON ELECTORAL RESULTS Note: Based on Model 2 in Table 3 (95% CIs are plotted). Sources: Central Election Commission of the Russian Federation (Tsentral’naya izbiratel’naya komissiya Rossiiskoi Federatsii), available at: http://izbirkom.ru/region/izbirkom, accessed 9 August 2021. Data collected by the authors from the Telegram bot (@smartvotebot) of the smart vote campaign. council elections, the impact of the interactive term falls short of statistical significance. This may indicate that, in relatively small localities, party affiliations as factors of voter choice are less important than in party-structured electoral arenas such as whole regions or regional capitals. Russia is not different from many other countries, new democracies and electoral autocracies alike, in that party structures at the grassroots level are very weak (Hutcheson 2003). In all other respects, H2 is strongly supported by our analysis. The interaction term between the smart vote support dummy and the share of early voting is significant in all models. The biggest impact of the smart vote support, as demonstrated by Figure 1 (plot B) and Figure A2 (plots B1, B2, and B3) in the online Appendix, can be observed at very low levels of early voting, and the impact gradually vanishes as early voting becomes widespread. As Figure 1 (plot B) shows, the smart vote effect ceases to be significant when the share of early voting reaches 56%. These findings are in line with H3. Conclusion Contemporary autocrats differ from their historical predecessors in many respects, and one of the peculiarities of new authoritarianism is its reliance on the conventional institutions normally associated with democracy. Today, quasi-competitive multiparty elections lie at the core of the institutional order of authoritarian regimes. By imitating democratic politics, these regimes consolidate their domestic position and international standing. In order for elections to be both useful and safe for autocratic leaders, it is 838 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV essential for them not to let anti-regime opposition into the electoral arena. At the same time, an autocrat must ensure the participation of only those parties that, for a variety of reasons, are viewed as incapable of either forming coalitions or mobilising the turnout of anti-regime voters. A regime will seek to marginalise such voters, effectively disenfranchising them through lack of acceptable choices. Even under the conditions of electoral authoritarianism, however, it remains possible for anti-regime voters to behave strategically by voting for those parties that, while deemed harmless by the regime and therefore tolerated in the electoral arena, can reduce the dominance of main pro-regime parties and undermine their claims of overwhelming support in the electorate. In this article, we theoretically explicated the calculus of the strategic anti-regime voter in a situation where the opposition parties do not attempt to form any kind of coalition. The motivation of this voter combines the goal of inflicting harm on the regime with an assessment of the likelihood of one of the allowed candidates defeating the dominant party’s candidate. Amongst a number of other elements, the resulting motivation structure includes the benefit from carrying out the civic duty of voting, satisfaction from a perceivably meaningful yet relatively risk-free opposition activity, aversion towards the programmatic and/or policy stances of official opposition parties, which is expected to detract voters from behaving strategically, and the amount of intimidation potentially faced by an opposition voter. This theoretical framework has been applied to strategic voting in one of the world’s most salient electoral authoritarian regimes, Russia, by using the empirical evidence from the September 2020 subnational elections that were held concurrently in a wide variety of localities across the country. In these elections, Aleksei Naval’nyi’s smart vote campaign urged voters to act strategically by casting their votes for the strongest non-UR candidates not closely linked to the regime. Our empirical analysis demonstrates the general validity of the strategic anti-regime voting model presented in this article. The smart vote campaign boosted the electoral results of its supported candidates in elections at different levels. At the same time, consistent with the model, we found that the impact of the smart vote was reduced if candidates lacked convincing opposition credentials. The analysis also shows that the willingness of anti-regime voters to behave strategically can be affected by the scope of voter intimidation available to the authorities. The study could be developed further by using specifically designed opinion polls to test the weight of the individual components of the model within opposition voters’ motivational structure. MIKHAIL TURCHENKO , Associate Professor, Political Science Department, European University at St Petersburg, 6/1A Gagarinskaya Street, St Petersburg, 191187, Russian Federation. Email: mturchenko@eu.spb.ru http://orcid.org/0000-0001-8535-5473 GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV, Professor, Head of Political Science Department, European University at St Petersburg, 6/1A Gagarinskaya Street, St Petersburg, 191187, Russian Federation. Email: ggolosov@gmail.com http://orcid.org/0000-0001-9769-9230 COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 839 References Albrecht, H. (2005) ‘How Can Opposition Support Authoritarianism? Lessons from Egypt’, Democratization, 12, 3. Alvarez, R. M., Kiewiet, D. R. & Lucas Núñez, L. (2018) ‘A Taxonomy of Protest Voting’, Annual Review of Political Science, 21. Alvarez, R. M., Levin, I., Mair, P. & Trechsel, A. (2014) ‘Party Preferences in the Digital Age: The Impact of Voting Advice Applications’, Party Politics, 20, 2. Alvarez, R. M. & Nagler, J. (2000) ‘A New Approach for Modelling Strategic Voting in Multiparty Elections’, British Journal of Political Science, 30, 1. Bader, M. (2016) ‘The Reintroduction of Early Voting in Russian Elections: A Tool for Electoral Manipulation?’, Russian Politics, 1, 1. Beissinger, M. (2013) ‘The Semblance of Democratic Revolution: Coalitions in Ukraine’s Orange Revolution’, American Political Science Review, 107, 3. Birch, S., Millard, F., Popescu, M. & Williams, K. (2002) Embodying Democracy: Electoral System Design in Post-Communist Europe (Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan). Bogaards, M., Basedau, M. & Hartmann, C. (2010) ‘Ethnic Party Bans in Africa: An Introduction’, Democratization, 17, 4. Bol’shakov, I. V. & Perevalov, V. V. (2020) ‘Konsolidatsiya ili protest? “Umnoe golosovanie” na moskovskikh vyborakh’, Politiya, 1. Brownlee, J. (2007) Authoritarianism in an Age of Democratization (New York, NY, Cambridge University Press). Bunce, V. J. & Wolchik, S. L. (2010) ‘Defeating Dictators: Electoral Change and Stability in Competitive Authoritarian Regimes’, World Politics, 62, 1. Conaghan, C. M. (2005) Fujimori’s Peru: Deception in the Public Sphere (Pittsburgh, PA, University of Pittsburgh Press). Cox, G. W. (1997) Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral Systems (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press). Crisp, B. F., Olivella, S. & Potter, J. D. (2012) ‘Electoral Contexts That Impede Voter Coordination’, Electoral Studies, 31, 1. Dergachev, V., Burchakov, A., Safronova, V., Berdnikova, E. & Rynda, A. (2021) ‘“Tochki stressa dlya Kremlya”: Shtaby Naval’nogo ob’’yavili o samorospuske. Chem oni zapomnilis’?’, BBC Russian Service, 29 April, available at: https://www.bbc.com/russian/features-56932344, accessed 9 August 2021. Dollbaum, J. M. (2019) ‘Outsmarting Electoral Authoritarianism? Alexey Navalny’s “Smart Voting” in Moscow and Beyond’, Russian Analytical Digest, No. 239, September. Dollbaum, J. M. (2020) ‘Protest Trajectories in Electoral Authoritarianism: From Russia’s “For Fair Elections” Movement to Alexei Navalny’s Presidential Campaign’, Post-Soviet Affairs, 36, 3. Donno, D. (2013) ‘Elections and Democratization in Authoritarian Regimes’, American Journal of Political Science, 57, 3. Duverger, M. (1954) Political Parties: Their Organization and Activities in the Modern State (New York, NY, Wiley). Flikke, G. (2016) ‘Canaries in a Coal Mine: The Uphill Struggle of Russia’s Non-System Liberals’, Demokratizatsiya: The Journal of Post-Soviet Democratization, 24, 3. Forrat, N. (2018) ‘Shock-Resistant Authoritarianism: Schoolteachers and Infrastructural State Capacity in Putin’s Russia’, Comparative Politics, 50, 3. Frye, T., Gehlbach, S., Marquardt, K. L. & Reuter, O. J. (2017) ‘Is Putin’s Popularity Real?’, Post-Soviet Affairs, 33, 1. Frye, T., Reuter, O. J. & Szakonyi, D. (2014) ‘Political Machines at Work: Voter Mobilization and Electoral Subversion in the Workplace’, World Politics, 66, 2. Frye, T., Reuter, O. J. & Szakonyi, D. (2019) ‘Hitting Them with Carrots: Voter Intimidation and Vote Buying in Russia’, British Journal of Political Science, 49, 3. Gandhi, J. (2008) Political Institutions under Dictatorship (New York, NY, Cambridge University Press). Gandhi, J. & Ong, E. (2019) ‘Committed or Conditional Democrats? Opposition Dynamics in Electoral Autocracies’, American Journal of Political Science, 63, 4. Gandhi, J. & Reuter, O. J. (2013) ‘The Incentives for Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Non-Democratic Elections’, Democratization, 20, 1. Garzia, D. & Marschall, S. (2016) ‘Research on Voting Advice Applications: State of the Art and Future Directions’, Policy & Internet, 8, 4. Gel’man, V. (2008) ‘Party Politics in Russia: From Competition to Hierarchy’, Europe-Asia Studies, 60, 6. 840 MIKHAIL TURCHENKO & GRIGORII V. GOLOSOV Gill, G. (2015) Building an Authoritarian Polity: Russia in Post-Soviet Times (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press). Golosov, G. V. (2006) ‘The Structure of Party Alternatives and Voter Choice in Russia: Evidence from the 2003–2004 Regional Legislative Elections’, Party Politics, 12, 6. Golosov, G. V. (2013) ‘Authoritarian Party Systems: Patterns of Emergence, Sustainability and Survival’, Comparative Sociology, 12, 5. Golosov, G. V. (2014a) ‘Co-optation in the Process of Dominant Party System Building: The Case of Russia’, East European Politics, 30, 2. Golosov, G. V. (2014b) ‘The September 2013 Regional Elections in Russia: The Worst of Both Worlds’, Regional & Federal Studies, 24, 2. Golosov, G. V. (2015) ‘Do Spoilers Make a Difference? Instrumental Manipulation of Political Parties in an Electoral Authoritarian Regime, the Case of Russia’, East European Politics, 31, 2. Golosov, G. V. (2018) ‘Electoral Integrity and Voter Turnout in Contemporary Autocracies’, in Garnett, H. A. & Zavadskaya, M. (eds) Electoral Integrity and Political Regimes: Actors, Strategies and Consequences (London, Routledge). Golosov, G. V. & Turchenko, M. (2021) ‘Countering the “Sweep Effect”: Opposition Voter Coordination versus Electoral System Effects in Authoritarian Local Elections’, Communist and Post-Communist Studies, 54, 1–2. Greene, K. F. (2007) Why Dominant Parties Lose: Mexico’s Democratization in Comparative Perspective (New York, NY, Cambridge University Press). Greene, S. A. & Robertson, G. B. (2019) Putin v. The People: The Perilous Politics of a Divided Russia (New Haven, CT, Yale University Press). Gschwend, T. & Hooghe, M. (2008) ‘Should I Stay or Should I Go? An Experimental Study on Voter Responses to Pre-Electoral Coalitions’, European Journal of Political Research, 47, 5. Hafner-Burton, E., Hyde, S. & Jablonski, R. (2018) ‘Surviving Elections: Election Violence, Incumbent Victory, and Post-Election Repercussions’, British Journal of Political Science, 48, 2. Hassner, P. (2008) ‘Russia’s Transition to Autocracy’, Journal of Democracy, 19, 2. Howard, M. M. & Roessler, P. G. (2006) ‘Liberalizing Electoral Outcomes in Competitive Authoritarian Regimes’, American Journal of Political Science, 50, 2. Hutcheson, D. S. (2003) Political Parties in the Russian Regions (London & New York, NY, Routledge Curzon). Hutcheson, D. S. (2018) Parliamentary Elections in Russia: A Quarter-Century of Multi-Party Politics (Oxford, Oxford University Press/British Academy). Kamoen, N., Holleman, B., Krouwel, A., van de Pol, J. & de Vreese, C. (2015) ‘The Effect of Voting Advice Applications on Political Knowledge and Vote Choice’, Irish Political Studies, 30, 4. Karvonen, L. (2007) ‘Legislation on Political Parties: A Global Comparison’, Party Politics, 13, 4. Kazun, A. & Semykina, K. (2020) ‘Presidential Elections 2018: The Struggle of Putin and Navalny for a Media Agenda’, Problems of Post-Communism, 67, 6. Kleinnijenhuis, J., van de Pol, J., van Hoof, A. M. J. & Krouwel, A. P. M. (2019) ‘Genuine Effects of Vote Advice Applications on Party Choice: Filtering Out Factors That Affect Both the Advice Obtained and the Vote’, Party Politics, 25, 3. Letsa, N. W. (2020) ‘Expressive Voting in Autocracies: A Theory of Non-Economic Participation with Evidence from Cameroon’, Perspectives on Politics, 18, 2. Levitt, S. D. (1994) ‘Using Repeat Challengers to Estimate the Effect of Campaign Spending on Election Outcomes in the U.S. House’, Journal of Political Economy, 102, 4. Lindberg, S. I. (2005) ‘Consequences of Electoral Systems in Africa: A Preliminary Inquiry’, Electoral Studies, 24, 1. Lust-Okar, E. (2008) ‘Competitive Clientelism in Jordanian Elections’, in Lust-Okar, E. & Zerhouni, S. (eds) Political Participation in the Middle East (Boulder, CO, Lynne Rienner). Magaloni, B. (2010) ‘The Game of Electoral Fraud and the Ousting of Authoritarian Rule’, American Journal of Political Science, 54, 3. Magaloni, B. & Kricheli, R. (2010) ‘Political Order and One-Party Rule’, Annual Review of Political Science, 13. Mainwaring, S. (1988) ‘Political Parties and Democratization in Brazil and the Southern Cone’, Comparative Politics, 21, 1. Marschall, S. & Schultze, M. (2015) ‘German E-Campaigning and the Emergence of a “Digital Voter”? An Analysis of the Users of the Wahl-O-Mat’, German Politics, 24, 4. Moser, R. G. & White, A. C. (2017) ‘Does Electoral Fraud Spread? The Expansion of Electoral Manipulation in Russia’, Post-Soviet Affairs, 33, 2. COORDINATED VOTING AGAINST THE AUTOCRACY 841 Naval’nyi, A. (2019) ‘Umnoe golosovanie. Smotrim sotsiologiyu ot FBK’, Ekho Moskvy. Blogi, 28 August, available at: https://echo.msk.ru/blog/corruption/2490725-echo/, accessed 9 August 2021. Ong, E. (2022) ‘What Are We Voting for? Opposition Alliance Joint Campaigns in Electoral Autocracies’, Party Politics, 28, 5. Reuter, O. J. (2017) The Origins of Dominant Parties: Building Authoritarian Institutions in Post-Soviet Russia (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press). Riker, W. H. & Ordeshook, P. C. (1968) ‘A Theory of the Calculus of Voting’, American Political Science Review, 62, 1. Ross, C. (ed.) (2015) Systemic and Non-Systemic Opposition in the Russian Federation: Civil Society Awakens? (London & New York, NY, Routledge). Schedler, A. (2013) The Politics of Uncertainty: Sustaining and Subverting Electoral Authoritarianism (New York, NY, Oxford University Press). Shevchenko, I. & Golosov, G. V. (2001) ‘Legislative Activism of Russian Duma Deputies, 1996–1999’, Europe-Asia Studies, 53, 2. Simpser, A. (2013) Why Parties and Governments Manipulate Elections: Theory, Practice and Implications (New York, NY, Cambridge University Press). Smyth, R. (2020) Elections, Protest, and Authoritarian Regime Stability: Russia 2008–2020 (New York, NY, Cambridge University Press). Squire, P. & Smith, E. R. A. N. (1984) ‘Repeat Challengers in Congressional Elections’, American Politics Quarterly, 12, 1. Stephenson, L. B., Aldrich, J. H. & Blais, A. (2018) The Many Faces of Strategic Voting: Tactical Behaviour in Electoral Systems around the World (Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press). Tordoff, W. & Young, R. A. (1999) ‘The Presidential Election in Gabon’, Review of African Political Economy, 26. Tucker, J. (2007) ‘Enough! Electoral Fraud, Collective Action Problems, and Post-Communist Colored Revolutions’, Perspectives on Politics, 5, 3. Turchenko, M. & Golosov, G. V. (2021) ‘Smart Enough to Make a Difference? An Empirical Test of the Efficacy of Strategic Voting in Russia’s Authoritarian Elections’, Post-Soviet Affairs, 37, 1. Ufen, A. (2020) ‘Opposition in Transition: Pre-Electoral Coalitions and the 2018 Electoral Breakthrough in Malaysia’, Democratization, 27, 2. van der Linden, C. & Vowles, J. (2017) ‘(De)Coding Elections: The Implications of Voting Advice Applications’, Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties, 27, 1. Wagner, M. (2011) ‘Defining and Measuring Niche Parties’, Party Politics, 18, 6. Wahman, M. (2011) ‘Offices and Policies—Why Do Oppositional Parties Form Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Competitive Authoritarian Regimes?’, Electoral Studies, 30, 4. Wahman, М. (2013) ‘Opposition Coalitions and Democratization by Election’, Government and Opposition, 48, 1. White, S. & McAllister, I. (2014) ‘Did Russia (Nearly) Have a Facebook Revolution in 2011? Social Media’s Challenge to Authoritarianism’, Politics, 34, 1. Wilson, K. (2016) ‘How Increased Competition Can Strengthen Electoral Authoritarianism: Party-System Pluralization in Russia’, Problems of Post-Communism, 63, 4. Wright, J. & Escribà-Folch, A. (2012) ‘Authoritarian Institutions and Regime Survival: Transitions to Democracy and Subsequent Autocracy’, British Journal of Political Science, 42, 2. Zhuravskaya, E., Petrova, M. & Enikolopov, R. (2020) ‘Political Effects of the Internet and Social Media’, Annual Review of Economics, 12.