NBS8337 Economics of Commodity Markets Trends in Commodity Prices Trends in Commodity Prices • Classical Economists held the view that the trend in commodity prices in relation to manufactured goods should be positive as the supply of primary commodities would be constrained by the fixed amount of land while the supply of manufactures would be augmented by technological progress. • Prebisch (1950) and Singer (1950) claimed that commodity prices should decline in relation to manufactures in the long run, labelled as the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis (PSH). • Deaton and Laroque (2003) set out a model showing prices of commodities in developing countries contain no trend by linking them to the Lewis model. Trends in Commodity Prices • Price of non-renewable resources would rise with the rate of interest and that the production trajectory would be monotonically declining until the resource is exhausted (Hotelling 1931). • Empirical evidence is contradictory. • Slade (1982) suggest a U-shaped time path for natural resource prices when there is exogenous technical change and endogenous change in the grade of metals mined. Prebisch-Singer Hypothesis • PSH claimed that the relative price od commodities in terms of manufactured goods shows a downward trend. • PSH rested their case on three stylised facts: • Developing countries were highly specialised in the production and export of primary commodities. • Technical progress was concentrated mainly in industry. • The relative price of commodities to manufactured goods had fallen steadily since the late 19th century. • Because of developing countries specialisation in primary commodities, PSH claim that it is unlikely to benefit their economy. Prebisch-Singer Hypothesis • If technical progress in the manufacturing sector exceeds that of the primary commodity sector then we would see the supply of manufactures growing faster than the supply of commodities and this would lead the relative supply of commodities to manufactures shifting to the left. • The relative price of primary commodities would increase • This was the Classical view that technical progress in industrialised countries translates into welfare gains for developing countries. Prebisch-Singer Hypothesis • World Market for Primary Commodities relative to Manufactures. S’ [P(c)/P(m)]’ [P(c)/P(m)] S E’ E D Q(c)/Q(m) Prebisch-Singer Hypothesis • PSH pointed put that this mechanism did not work. • Instead of commodity prices increasing, they had actually fallen • Prebisch (1950) and Singer (1950) based their conclusion on a visual inspection of the data : Inverse of the NBTT of UK from 1876 to 1947. Prebisch-Singer Hypothesis • Why commodity prices might experience declining trend • By way of the diagram, the demand schedule could shift to the left along with relative supply and the shift of demand would be greater causing the new equilibrium to be at point E” (see diagram in next slide) associated with a lower relative commodity price. • Or alternatively, the supply schedule could shift to the right causing the price to fall corresponding to equilibrium point E’’’ (see diagram in next slide). Prebisch-Singer Hypothesis • World Market for Primary Commodities relative to Manufactures. S’ [P(c)/P(m)] [P(c) )/P(m)]” [P(c )/P(m)]’’’ S E’ [P(c)/P(m)]’ E E” E’’’ D Q(c)/Q(m) Demand Side Argument: Singer (1950) • Demand for primary commodities have lower income elasticity. • 1. Income growth tends to lower the relative demand for, and hence relative price of primary commodities. • 2. Also, technical progress in manufacturing can cause the demand for primary commodities to grow slower than manufactures. • Both 1 and 2 would cause the demand schedule to shift relatively more thn that of the supply schedule. Supply Side Argument: Prebisch (1950) • Strong labour unions in industrialised countries cause wages in manufacturing to ratchet upwards during booms and to be sticky downwards during recessions. • This causes a ratchet up of the cost of manufactures. • Weak labour unions in developing countries fail to increase wages during booms and cannot prevent falls during recessions. • Thus cost of primary commodities rises by less than manufactures during booms and falls by more during recessions creating a decline in the relative cost of primary commodities. • This causes rightward movement in the supply schedule. Prebisch-Singer Hypothesis • Policy Implications • The PSH argues that developing countries should adopt industrialisation. • Diversification of commodities • Commodity Stabilisation programmes Deaton-Laroque Model • Demand is given by: ππ‘ = π΄π¦π‘ − π΅ππ‘ + π + ππ‘π • Where ππ‘ denotes quantity demanded, π¦π‘ denotes income, ππ‘ denotes price, ππ‘π is a stationary unobservable I(0) random variable. • We assume π΄ > 0 so that demand exclusive of price movements is increasing with world income. Deaton-Laroque Model • The supply process is a simple version of the Lewis Model π π‘ = π π‘−1 + π· ππ‘ − π∗ + ππ‘π • Where π π‘ denotes quantity supplied, π∗ denotes the marginal cost of production on marginal land or marginal cost of extraction of mineral, ππ‘ denotes price, ππ‘π is a stationary unobservable I(0) random variable which is the supply shock. • We assume π· > 0 so that supply increases when price is above marginal cost and vice versa. Deaton-Laroque Model • Assuming no inventories and equating supply and demand: π΄π¦π‘ − π΅ππ‘ + π + ππ‘π = π π‘−1 + π· ππ‘ − π∗ + ππ‘π π΅ + π· ππ‘ = π΄π¦π‘ + π − π π‘−1 + π·π∗ + ππ‘π − ππ‘π ππ‘ = π΅ + π· −1 π΄π¦π‘ + π − π π‘−1 + π·π∗ + ππ‘π − ππ‘π (A.1) • Substituting this result in the supply process: π π‘ = π π‘−1 + π·ππ‘ − π·π∗ + ππ‘π π π‘ = π π‘−1 + π· π΅ + π· −1 π΄π¦π‘ + π − π π‘−1 + π·π∗ + ππ‘π − ππ‘π − π·π∗ + ππ‘π Deaton-Laroque Model • After some rearranging: π π‘ = π΅ + π· −1 π΅π π‘−1 + π΄π·π¦π‘ + π·π − π·π΅π∗ + π·ππ‘π + π΅ππ‘π Δπ π‘ = π΅ + π· −1 π·(π΄π¦π‘−1 − π π‘−1 ) + π΄π·Δπ¦π‘ + π·π − π·π΅π∗ + π·ππ‘π + π΅ππ‘π Deaton-Laroque Model • From the demand and supply processes we can write: Δππ‘ = π΄Δπ¦π‘ − π΅Δππ‘ + Δππ‘π Δπ π‘ = π· ππ‘ − π∗ + ππ‘π • Equating the two: π΄Δπ¦π‘ − π΅Δππ‘ + Δππ‘π = π· ππ‘ − π∗ + ππ‘π • or, π΄Δπ¦π‘ + Δππ‘π − ππ‘π = π·ππ‘ − π·π∗ + π΅ππ‘ − π΅ππ‘−1 • Adding and subtracting π΅π∗ on the LHS of the eqn. π΄Δπ¦π‘ + Δππ‘π − ππ‘π = π·ππ‘ − π·π∗ + π΅ππ‘ − π΅ππ‘−1 + π΅π∗ − π΅π∗ Deaton-Laroque Model • Rearranging: π΄Δπ¦π‘ + Δππ‘π − ππ‘π = (π΅ + π·)ππ‘ − π΅ππ‘−1 + π΅π∗ − (π΅ + π·)π∗ π΅ππ‘−1 − π΅π∗ + π΄Δπ¦π‘ + Δππ‘π − ππ‘π = (π΅ + π·)ππ‘ − (π΅ + π·)π∗ π΅ + π· (ππ‘ −π∗ ) = π΅(ππ‘−1 −π∗ ) + π΄Δπ¦π‘ + Δππ‘π − ππ‘π • The reduced form price process: (ππ‘ −π∗ ) = π΅ + π· −1 π΅(ππ‘−1 −π∗ ) + π΄Δπ¦π‘ + Δππ‘π − ππ‘π (1) Deaton-Laroque Model • The result (equation 1) shows that in the short run, price will respond to fluctuations in demand and supply. If prices deviate from their steady-state inter-temporal equilibrium, given by π΅ + π· −1 π΄Δπ¦π‘ where Δπ¦π‘ is the mean growth rate of income, then prices will show signs of adjustment. • In other words, (empirically) if we were to conduct unit root tests on the price series, we would expect to obtain a stationary process with linear adjustment. Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • The relative price considered: ratio of extractive-industry price index to an overall price index. • π(π‘): • π(π‘): the output of metal in the extractive industry at time π‘. the grade of ore mined at time π‘. [grade is ordered by increasing extractions costs]. • π΅(π): the willingness to pay for π. • πΆ π, π, π‘ : the total extraction cost. • π(π): the density of the metal for grade π. • π: the social discount rate. Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • Objective: to choose a time path for extraction rates that will maximise the discounted stream of current and future benefits minus costs. • The maximisation problem is: πππ₯ • π ∞ −ππ‘ π 0 π΅ π − πΆ(π, π, π‘) ππ‘ s.t. π π‘ = π π‘ π(π π‘ ) Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • The optimal control problem can be solved by introducing the costate variable π(π‘) • The Hamiltonian is set up as: • π» = π −ππ‘ π΅ π − πΆ(π, π, π‘) − ππ • π» = π −ππ‘ π΅ ππ − πΆ(ππ, π, π‘) − ππ • To choose the control variable: • π»π = π −ππ‘ π΅′ π − πΆ ′ π − π = 0 • Or, π΅′ π = π π ′π + πΆ −ππ‘ [imposing the constraint] Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • Or, π΅′ = • Or, π π ππ ππ‘ + πΆ′ π ππ ππ‘ = + π πΆ′ (equation B.1) • where π π is the inverse demand function. • To obtain the path of the state variable: • ππ ππ‘ = π»π = π −ππ‘ π΅′ ππ ′ − πΆ ′ ππ ′ − πΆπ (equation B.2) Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • Differentiating B.1 w.r.t. time π‘: ′ • π=πΆ + π ππ ππ‘ π+π ππ‘ π −π′πππ ππ‘ π2 • Rearranging the expression: ′ •π=πΆ + ππ ππ‘ π+π ππ‘ π π − π′πππ ππ‘ π2 equation B.3 Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade ππ (note: ππ‘ • Substituting B.2 in B.3 we get: •π= πΆ′ ′ + •π=πΆ + ππ ππ‘ π+π΅′ ππ′ −πΆ ′ ππ′ −πΆπ π ππ ππ‘ π+πππ′ −πΆ ′ ππ′ −πΆπ π − − π′πππ ππ‘ π2 π′πππ ππ‘ π2 = π) Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • Now, rearranging the terms: ′ •π=πΆ + πππ′ π − ππ ππ‘ π + π π πΆπ − πΆ ′ ππ′ π + π′πππ ππ‘ π2 • The expression in square brackets can be shown to be equal to • Therefore; π = πΆ ′ − πΆπ π + ππ ππ‘ π π equation B.4 π ππ′ π Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • Slade makes the assumption about marginal cost (i.e. πΆ ′ ) that it is an additive function such that: • πΆ = β π + π(π‘) π • Therefore we have: πΆ ′ = β π + π(π‘) πΆ ′ = β′π + π πΆπ = β′ π Substituting these expressions in B.4 π = β′π + π − β′ π π + ππ ππ‘ π π Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • Finally, some more rearranging: • π = β′π + π − • π = (β′ π − β′ π π β′ π π ) ππ ππ‘ π + π ππ ππ‘ π +π+ π • or, • • • π ′ π = β (π − ) + π π ππ ππ‘ π π=π+ π π since π − = 0; π + ππ ππ‘ π π equation B.5 constraint of optimisation Price Dynamics of Natural Resources: Slade • Define π = ππ ππ‘ π: rental rate or the marginal value of the resource in the ground. • Going back to equation B.1: π π = ππ ππ‘ π + πΆ′ • We can write: π = πΆ ′ + π • So that price equals marginal extract cost plus rent. • Going back to equation B.5: • We can write βΆ π = π + ππ • So that the rate of change of marginal cost due to changes in technology plus the discount rate times rent. Reading • 1. Cuddington, J.T., Ludema, R., Jayasuriya, S. 2002. The PrebischSinger Redux. Office of Economics Working Paper. U.S. International Trade Commission. No. 2002-06-A. • 2. Deaton, A., and Laroque, G., 2003. A model of commodity prices after Sir Arthur Lewis. Journal of Development Economics, 71(2), pp.289-310. • 3. Slade, M. 1982. Trends in Natural Resource Commodity Prices: An Analysis of the Time Domain. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 9, pp. 122 – 137.