SCHOOL OF POSTGRADUATE STUDIES AN ASSESMENT OF THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL DEFICITS ON ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ZAMBIA FROM 1090-2022 A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE SCHOOL OF POSTGRADUATE STUDIES, UNIVERSITY OF LUSAKA IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE AWARD OF THE MASTER OF SCIENCE IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE. BY MARTHA NAMUSIKA SEPETO MSCECF21210539 ©2022 [DATE] [COMPANY NAME] [Company address] TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER ONE ........................................................................................................................................... 2 1.0 Introduction and Background.............................................................................................................. 2 1.2 PROBLEM STATEMENT ................................................................................................................. 4 1.3 STUDY OBJECTIVES ....................................................................................................................... 4 1.3.1 GENERAL OBJECTIVE ............................................................................................................. 4 1.3.2 SPECIFIC OBJECTIVES ..................................................................................................... 5 1.4 STUDY HYPOTHESIS ...................................................................................................................... 5 1.5 SIGNIFICANCE OF STUDY ............................................................................................................ 5 CHAPTER TWO: LITERATURE REVIEW ............................................................................................... 6 2.0 Introduction ......................................................................................................................................... 6 2.1 LITERATURE REVIEW ............................................................................................................. 6 2.1.1 Neo-Classical Theory............................................................................................................ 6 2.1.2 Keynesian Theory ................................................................................................................. 9 2.2 2.2.1 2.3 Theories on the non-existent relationship between public debt and economic growth............... 10 Ricardian Equivalence Hypothesis ......................................................................................... 10 EMPIRICAL LITERATURE REVIEW ..................................................................................... 11 2.3.1 Empirical review of the negative relationship between public debt and economic growth ...... 11 Empirical review on the positive relationship between public debt and economic growth ................ 12 2.3 Conceptual Framework ..................................................................................................................... 13 Conclusion .............................................................................................................................................. 14 CHAPTER THREE: RESEARCH METHODOLOGY.............................................................................. 15 3.0 Introduction ....................................................................................................................................... 15 3.1 Research Design................................................................................................................................ 15 3.2 Target Population .............................................................................................................................. 15 3.3 Data Collection Method .................................................................................................................... 15 3.4 Data Validity ..................................................................................................................................... 15 3.5 Data Analysis .................................................................................................................................... 16 3.6 Empirical Model ............................................................................................................................... 16 3.7 Ethical Considerations ...................................................................................................................... 16 REFERENCES ........................................................................................................................................... 17 CHAPTER ONE 1.0 Introduction and Background Reinhart and Rogoff's (2010) work sparked interest in studying the long-run relationship between fiscal deficit and economic growth across countries (Checherita-Westphal & Rother, 2012; Tchereni et al., 2013; Panizza & Presbitero, 2013, 2014; Mencinger et al., 2014; Egert, 2015; Adamu & Rasiah, 2016; Shittu et al., 2018). Similarly, a number of empirical studies have attempted to determine whether there is a tipping point (debt-threshold) for fiscal deficits beyond which economic growth plummets significantly (for a review see Eberhardt & Presbitero, 2015; Chudik et al., 2017; Yang & Su, 2018.) In economic growth models, a large fiscal deficit as a percentage of GDP can boost aggregate demand and growth in the short run, but it crowds out private capital expenditure and dampens growth in the long run (Eberhardt & Presbitero, 2015). According to Chudik et al. (2017), the relationship between fiscal deficit and economic growth differs across countries due to institutional quality, degree of financial deepening, prevailing economic conditions, historical records of meeting debt obligations, political stability, and political system nature (Kourtellos et al., 2013). Zambia borrowed heavily to finance its fiscal deficit between 1980 and 1990, as did many other African countries. In particular, by the end of 1990, the sovereign debt had reached approximately USD 8 billion (i.e., 244 percent of GDP), resulting in a severe financial burden and slow economic growth between 1990 and the mid-2000s (Smith et al., 2017). Zambia completed the Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative (MDRI) and the Highly Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) initiative in 2005, qualifying for USD 6.6 billion in sovereign debt relief (Smith et al., 2017). Between 2006 and 2011, sovereign debt increased at a slow but steady rate, rising from approximately USD 3.2 billion (25 percent of GDP) in 2006 to approximately USD 5.1 billion (22 percent of GDP) in 2011. On the contrary, Zambia's sovereign debt has risen at an alarming rate, from approximately USD 5.1 billion at the end of 2011 to USD 14.91 billion at the end of 2018. Aside from the composition of Zambia’s public debt switching from being largely concessional to mostly non-concessional and the overall debt rising, the debt servicing costs have also swelled over time, putting pressure on the Government’s limited resources. The consequence of this has been the shift in public expenditure from critical areas, such as economic affairs and social protection, towards debt servicing. This has resulted in the Government having to borrow more money in order to make up for the spending shortfalls in these critical areas created by the high debt servicing costs. As a result of Government’s failure to invest in productive sectors due to the shrinking fiscal space, real GDP growth has been on the decline, alongside other structural imbalances that the country is faced with. During the period 2016-2019, GDP grew at an average of 3.2% per year compared to annual averages of 4.3% and 8.7% over the period 2011-2015 and 2006-2010 respectively. In 2020, real GDP growth was recorded at -2.8% as shown in Figure 4.3, as a result of the COVID19 pandemic. During this period, the stock of public debt grew from 18.9% of GDP in 2010 to 126% of GDP in 2020. 140 12 120 10 8 100 6 80 4 60 2 40 0 20 growth rate (%) debt-to-GDP (%) Figure 4.3: Zambia's Debt-to-GDP Ratio and Real GDP Growth, 2006 – 2020* -2 0 -4 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Debt to GDP [Left Axis] GDP growth [Right Axis] Source: Author’s compilation using IMF figures. As debt grows, it brings with it the challenges of servicing interest payments and at the worst, the risk of defaulting on payments. In 2017, Zambia was considered to be at a high risk of debt distress by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), 12 years after obtaining the HIPC debt relief. Further, in 2020 it became the first African country to default on debt in the Covid-19 pandemic era, as it defaulted on a US$42.5 million Eurobond payment. By end 2021, the country had reached a StaffLevel Agreement with the IMF to receive a US$1.4 billion extended credit facility to provide it with the much-needed fiscal space to deal with its debt overhang. 1.2 PROBLEM STATEMENT Over the last decade, the Zambian economy has been characterized by deterioration in the macroeconomic environment, sluggish economic growth and an increasingly constrained fiscal space. For instance, Zambia's real GDP growth declined from an annual average rate of 5.4 percent during 2010-2015 to about 1.9 percent over 2016-2020. In addition, the fiscal deficit as a share of GDP increased to 14.5 percent in 2020 from a manageable 5.7 percent in 2016 (MoFNP, 2016) (MoFNP, 2021). As it is commonly known, Zambia has also been buckling under an increasingly heavy debt burden over the last decade, culminating in a public debt-to-GDP ratio of about 117 percent in 2020. Further, although average annual inflation remained stable and within single digits between 2016 and 2019, it rose sharply to 15.6 percent in 2020 from 9.1 percent in 2019. Consequently, these weak macroeconomic fundamentals pose a serious threat to development finance mobilization and sustainable economic development, particularly as the country continues to recover from the economic strain resulting from the COVID-19 pandemic (World Bank, 2020). Since 2010, Zambia’s expenditure patterns have been characterized by higher than planned expenditures. This has been largely on account of higher debt servicing costs and capital spending, which crowded out social and other critical spending. Even with higher than planned revenues, this over expenditure has significantly contributed to the high fiscal deficits. Despite this, scholars have shown evidence of the positive impact of fiscal on economic growth. Natwi and Erickson (2016) in Ghana found that a positive and statistically significant relationship existed. Further, a short run bidirectional granger causality was found between public debt and economic growth in Ghana between 1970 and 2012. Studies by Suangweme and Odhiambo (2020 in Zimbabwe revelaed otherwise. The revealed that domestic fiscal deficit was more harmful to Zimbabwe than foreign public debt as evidenced by a higher negative coefficient on domestic public debt. Therefore, it is imperative to conduct an empirical analysis of Zambia’s case 1.3 STUDY OBJECTIVES 1.3.1 GENERAL OBJECTIVE The main objective of this research is to examine the effects of the fiscal deficit on economic growth in Zambia from 1990-2022 1.3.2 SPECIFIC OBJECTIVES The specific objectives of the study are: οΆ To investigate the relationship between fiscal debt and economic growth. οΆ To examine the effects of fiscal deficits on economic growth. οΆ To examine the impact of the impact of the level of debt on economic growth. οΆ To establish how debt servicing affects domestic funds 1.4 STUDY HYPOTHESIS Below are the postulated null hypotheses for this study: H0: there is no significant relationship between budget deficit and economic growth H0: there is no significant relationship between total debt and economic growth H0: there is no significant relationship between inflation rate and economic growth H0: there is no significant relationship between unemployment rate and economic growth H0: there is no significant relationship between level of education for decision makers and economic growth H0: there is no significant relationship between Institutional capacity to contract debt and economic growth H0: there is no significant relationship between FDI and economic growth H0: there is no significant relationship between Foreign Aid and economic growth 1.5 SIGNIFICANCE OF STUDY The main objective of this study is to examine the effects of the fiscal deficit on economic growth in Zambia from 1990-2022. The study will also analyze the direction effect of the resultant effect (be it neutral, negative or positive) which will help us to capture the previous deviations in the nation over the stated period as well as investigate the possible changes for the whole economy. The results of the model will provide policy insight to policy makers in as regards fiscal deficits and economic growth in Zambia. Additionally, the findings of the study will greatly add on to the existing Zambian literature as regards the impact of fiscal deficits on economic growth. CHAPTER TWO: LITERATURE REVIEW 2.0 Introduction The main aim of this chapter was to present some theoretical and empirical literature arguments underlying debate on the relationship between public debt and economic growth. The main theories which are going to guide the study are the Neo-classical theory that assumes a negative relationship between public debt and economic growth, the Keynesian and Wagner theories, which postulates a positive relationship, and the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis which emphasizes on a non-existent relationship between the two variables. 2.1 LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1.1 Neo-Classical Theory The Neo-classical theoretical view suggests that the impact of public debt on economic growth is negative. Public debt is assumed to have a negative impact on real macroeconomic variables and this is explained fundamentally by the debt overhang hypothesis. The debt overhang is defined as the presence of an existing or inherited debt that is sufficiently large, such that creditors do not expect to be fully repaid with confidence. In other words, a country experiences debt overhang when the expected present value of its potential future resource transfers falls short of the value of its debt. Because the country cannot fully service its public debt using available resources, it undertakes negotiations with its creditors to determine how the debt will be paid back. As such, in order to meet its debt servicing obligations to resolve the debt overhang, the country may resort to reduced spending in other priority areas. According to the debt overhang hypothesis, if an economy’s total debt stock is established to exceed its repayment ability in the future, expected debt service will undoubtedly be an increasing function of its output level. In countries that are heavily indebted, debt overhang is considered to be a leading cause of distortions in the economy resulting in slow economic growth. This is because these countries lose their attractiveness to private investors, while debt servicing consumes so much of the of the country’s revenue, such that the potential of returning to a sustainable growth path is reduced (Hassan et al., 2016). This focus on public debt servicing thus leads to depressed overall economic activity through the multiplier effect via various channels (Krugman, 1988: Claessens et al., 1996: Ejigayehu and Persson 2013). The debt overhang hypothesis postulates that the accumulation of public debt, mostly acquired due to worsening fiscal deficits affects economic growth through 3 channels namely: the crowding out effect, the fiscal illusion and the rational expectations theory (Odhiambo and Saungweme, 2018). (a) The crowding out effect Crowding out exists when public spending, which is primarily undertaken through government borrowing, reduces the lending capacity of the economy in terms of domestic financing to the private sector. As government borrows domestically, it tends to drive up the cost of private loans due to the increased demand. Additionally, it uses up the necessary funds that could have otherwise been channelled to the private investors. This in turn reduces the amount of private sector spending. The crowding out effect of public debt on private investment occurs in two ways: one way is through prices, that is, interest rates and the other is through quantity that is, credit rationing (Anyanwu et al., 2017). Another channel through which public debt may crowd out investment is through credit rationing. Credit rationing occurs when market players have restricted access to credit because financial institutions limit the supply of funds to private customers. As governments seek funds to meet their spending obligations, they tend to source this from the domestic market. This borrowing, if done persistently, causes a decline in available resources left for private sector to undertake investment. Debt accumulation may therefore impact economic growth by creating a liquidity constraint in the market. Additionally, if public debt repayment consumes a greater part of an economy’s savings, Government tends to rely more on short-term investments rather than long term, so as to service debt. This causes public debt to amplify public policy uncertainty as fiscal policy tends to be more inclined towards debt servicing thereby increasing systemic risk as well as the cost of capital. This disturbs the decision-making processes by private economic agents. (Mankiw and Elmendorf 1998: Claessens et al. 1996: Odhiambo and Saungweme, 2018). (b) Fiscal illusion Fiscal illusion is defined as the misunderstanding of the fiscal burden or the amount of tax paid by citizens due to incomplete information. In such a case, taxpayers regard their tax burden to either be smaller, or adversely heavier than it actually is. This happens because certain sources of government revenue are either not observed, or not fully observed by citizens. Fiscal illusion is primarily caused by a lack of transparency in the fiscal system which obscures citizens from knowing the true cost of public programs. For example, when government spends money from a source that is not transparent to citizens, some if not all citizens benefit from this expenditure and thus support the Government and its policies. However, if the citizens have full information about government sources of financing for this expenditure, in particular that they are financing the spending, they might not fully support the public programs (Mueller, 2003). If fiscal illusion is significant among citizens, it may lead to less efficiency and transparency in the use of public resources by the Government. Transparency requires that information is provided to citizens about what government is doing, that is, its policies and operations and this promotes accountability (Obama, 2009). When citizens face multiple tax instruments which include excise, sales and property taxes which are spread over a long period of time, the tax burden they actually face is usually underestimated. Alternatively, reduced tax cuts lower thus encouraging government to spend more on public services. That is, the full weight of future taxes is not apparent to tax payers as Government substitute’s public debt for tax finance. This is because future servicing of debt may lead to an increase in future taxes in order to raise revenue for the aforementioned debt servicing. In this case, citizens incorrectly observe the swap between current public debt and future tax finance to be an increase in their net worth. This leads them to increase current consumption at the expense of their saving and investment, thereby leading to depressed economic growth in the long run (Patinkin 1965: Odhiambo and Saungweme, 2018: Wasiluk and Giegiel, 2020). (c) Rational expectations theory The rational expectations theory argues that the negative impact of public debt on economic growth comes from either incorrect macroeconomic forecasts or from the uncertain reaction to macroeconomic stabilisation policies by economic agents. The theory also suggests that the negative impact of public debt could be much larger if public debt increases future policy uncertainty or leads to future prospects of confiscation. This could possibly occur through inflation and financial repression in which government borrowing restricts financial players from operating at full capacity (Churchman 2001: Cochrane 2011). From the aforementioned, the debt overhang hypothesis appears to hold in the Zambian context. In particular, the hypothesis speaks to the high debt servicing costs that tend to suffocate other spending priorities in the country. The economy has experienced the adverse effects of debt servicing. Overtime, the Zambia’s largest share of the budget has been allocated towards general public expenditure and majority of which, goes towards servicing of public debt. For example, in the 2011 national budget, 28.5% was earmarked for general public expenditure and this percentage has grown overtime to 41.6% of the budget in 2020. In the recent 2022 budget, about 50% of the national funds are envisaged towards this general public expenditure with debt and debt servicing accounting for about 90% of the total amount. On the other hand, important functions of government such as economic affairs have had a shrinking allocation of the budget from 25.6% in 2011 to 19.5% in 2022. With the country’s tight fiscal space, the allocations towards debt leave little room for other priority functions of government to be expanded. The result of this is stunted growth of the economy in general. 2.1.2 Keynesian Theory The view that forms the basic argument for the positive relationship between public debt and economic growth is the Keynesian theory. This theory is thought of to occur in two ways. The first suggests that public debt increases the levels of productive public spending which then acts as an automatic stabiliser reducing fluctuations in economic output. The second way posits that government spending that is deficit financed has a greater positive effect on the economy than tax financed government spending. Public debt, created by an absolute decrease in capital tax rates or by a significant rise in public sector capital investments, raises the net return to capital. Based on this theory, an expansionary fiscal policy resulting in growing public debt and budget deficits increases aggregate demand, which results in a higher growth rate. Further, public debt may also lead to increased investment activity which crowds in private investors thereby expanding aggregate supply as well. In addition to the Keynesian view of the positive impact of debt on economic growth, there is a conventional theory on the relationship between these two variables based on the assertion that government borrowing from the international financial and capital markets is necessary to fill the gap between domestic investment and savings. This is to say that in an economy in which output is below full potential, unemployment will be high and supply constraints on short-run demand absent. Therefore, a combination of high foreign public debt, and its persistent effects into the future, will have a positive fiscal multiplier effect on the economy. Thus, fiscal expansion is self- financing and stimulates aggregate demand in the long run in a depressed economy when interest rates are rising, leading to economic growth. 2.2 Theories on the non-existent relationship between public debt and economic growth The basic theoretical argument of the non-existent effect of public debt on economic growth is brought forth by Ricardo in the Ricardian Equivalence Hypothesis (REH), which states that the relationship between public debt and economic growth is non-existent. 2.2.1 Ricardian Equivalence Hypothesis The REH theory emphasises that public debt does not affect economic growth. This is because it is assumed that at the time when fiscal stimulus takes place and the budget deficit is growing whilst government debt is accelerating, market players prepare for a future period of severe measures and tax rises. The players therefore shift their focus from consumption and investment to increasing savings, which neutralises the impact of the demand stimulating fiscal policy. According to Ricardo, under certain settings the real economy is independent of the government’s choice of raising revenue, that is, either through taxes or debt issuance. This suggests that differences in domestic and foreign public debt stocks are invariant with changes in major real macroeconomic variables, such as gross investment and output. Therefore, there is no real effect on the economy’s growth path. This is so because changes in government spending and hence public debt, results in identical changes in private savings and no real impact on the real economy is noted thus rendering fiscal policy ineffective. In other words, the hypothesis stipulates that government debt only explains movements in financial assets among economic agents and only affects private consumption and savings with no detrimental economic consequences as long as solvency is not jeopardised. Therefore, the Ricardian Equivalence Theory suggests that public debt cannot be used as an economic stimulation tool (Ricardo, 1817: Buchanan, 1976: Barro, 1989: Pereira & Rodrigues, 2001: Szabo, 2012). The REH however is only holds theoretically when six key assumptions are considered. These include: perfect capital markets, a constant population growth, rational economic agents, an infinite time horizon, non-distortionary taxes, and initial tax cut beneficiaries bearing the government debt service burden. Thus, if the above assumptions hold, then shifts in the government’s funding strategy will be met by an equal adjustment in private savings to neutralize movements in public savings (Elmendorf & Mankiw, 1999). 2.3 EMPIRICAL LITERATURE REVIEW There is a wide variety of empirical arguments surrounding the relationship between debt and economic growth with different conclusions. This literature can broadly be divided into three categories. One that supports the positive relationship between the two variables, the other that provides evidence for a negative relationship between the two variables and lastly the view that the relationship between the two variables is non-existent. 2.3.1 Empirical review of the negative relationship between public debt and economic growth A number of studies have demonstrated the negative effect of public debt on economic growth. For example; Suangweme and Odhiambo (2020), Chikalipah (2020), Zulu (2017), Yung-Li (2015), Fuentes (2013), Calderon and Fuentes (2013), Chongo (2013), Panizza and Presbitero (2012), Woo and Kumar (2010) and Ayadi (2008), have found a negative relationship between public debt and growth in each of their studies. Suangweme and Odhiambo (2020), carried out a study using the Auto Regressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) approach to determine the impact of public debt on economic growth in Zimbabwe for the period between 1970 and 2017. The empirical results of the study revealed that public debt impacted negatively on economic growth in Zimbabwe irrespective of the type of debt, whether domestic or foreign, and irrespective of whether the public debt is aggregated or disaggregated. The study further revealed that domestic public debt was more harmful to Zimbabwe than foreign public debt as evidenced by a higher negative coefficient on domestic public debt. The empirical findings from the study apply both in the long and short run. The conclusions of the study were that the negative effect of public debt on economic growth was mostly due to the crowding out effect on investment on account of high cost of capital and credit rationing. Zulu (2017), who used the OLS analysis to ascertain the impact of external debt on economic growth in the period between 2013 and 2017. Real GDP was used as the dependent variable and proxy for economic growth while external debt, debt service payment and exchange rate were independent variables. The analysis highlighted a negative relationship between high external debt and economic growth. Additionally, a negative relationship between debt repayment and economic growth was noted whilst exchange rate had a positive relationship with economic growth. Prudent debt utilisation was recommended, coupled with debt sustainability that ensures efficient fiscal consolidation. Furthermore, Chongo (2013), carried out an econometric analysis to investigate the impact of rising public debt on economic growth in Zambia in the period 1980 to 2008 employing the VECM approach. The study investigated the channels through which debt is said to have an impact on growth, that is, through public and private investments as well as domestic savings. Using debt to GDP ratios and public debt service to revenue ratios as main variables, a negative long run relationship between debt and growth was found. It was further established that debt negatively impacted private investments and domestic savings, confirming the overhang and crowding out effects of debt. Chongo (2013) also found a positive relationship between public debt and public investments. The study therefore recommended the need for government to enhance the legal framework around debt acquisition that ensures ratification of any borrowing needs. Secondly, borrowed funds must be channelled towards investments with high returns while ensuring fiscal sustainability. Further, Government must reduce its dominance in the domestic market as it seeks resources to fund its fiscal deficits and instead opt for an expansion of the revenue base to finance expenditure. Empirical review on the positive relationship between public debt and economic growth Several scholars, including Thao (2018), Natwi and Erickson (2016), Egbetunde (2012), Uzun et al (2012), and Mohanty and Mishra (2012), have found a statistically significant relationship between public debt and economic growth (2016). Thao (2018) analysed the linkage between public debt and economic growth in six countries of the Association of South East Asian Nations (ASEAN) over a period of 1995 to 2015 and found a significant positive impact of public debt on GDP per capita growth rate. This was based on the generalised method of moments (GMM) regression analysis, with no evidence of the damaging effect of high country indebtedness on economic growth being found. This implies that public debt in the ASEAN countries has been utilised to effectively finance public investments, thereby promoting economic growth in the long run. Similarly, evidence of the positive impact of debt on economic growth is provided by Natwi and Erickson (2016) in a study investigating the causal relationship between the two variables in Ghana. Using the Johansen cointegration and Error Correction Model to examine the long run and causal relationship between public debt and economic growth, it was found that a positive and statistically significant relationship existed. Further, a short run bidirectional granger causality was found between public debt and economic growth in Ghana between 1970 and 2012. Further studies on the positive relationship include Egbetunde (2012), who examined the causal nexus between public debt and economic growth in Nigeria between 1970 and 2012. Having utilised the Vector Autoregressive (VAR) model and cointegration tests, a significant long run relationship, as well as a bi-directional causality between the variables, was noted. This, however, was found to only be feasible if government was transparent about the loans obtained and channelled it to developmental activities rather than for personal benefit. Likewise, Uzun et.al (2012), used a panel ARDL model to determine the relationship between indebtedness and economic growth rate involving 27 transition economies. The study revealed a positive relationship between GDP per capita growth rate and debt in the period between 1991 and 2000. The analysis further revealed that external sources of finance were needed to eliminate problems associated with production marketing and income saving as well as to change economic structures into market-based economies. 2.3 Conceptual Framework The conceptual framework takes after the model developed by (Mbuthia et al, 2021) who depicted the existence of a linear relationship between the dependent variable (GDP growth and the independent variables (Budget deficit, total debt, Inflation rate, Unemployment Rate, Level of education for decision makers, FDI and Foreign Aid ) Source; (Mbuthia et al, 2021) Budget deficit Level of education for decision makers debt Economic growth Foreign Aid Public Borrowing Foreign Direct Investment Conclusion The paper presents reviews of both theoretical and empirical literature on the relationship between public debt and economic growth. Exploring this relationship across three broad categories – a positive relationship, a negative relationship, and a non-existent relationship – the paper presents evidence from literature that supports all three hypotheses. Using descriptive analysis to explore the particular case of Zambia, we find that debt has a negative effect on economic growth in the Zambian context. This is supported by evidence from the empirical studies that have been reviewed. Notable among the channels through which debt impacts the Zambian economy are through private investments, domestic savings and increased interest rates. These findings confirm the debt overhang theory through the crowding out effects on the Zambian economy. CHAPTER THREE: RESEARCH METHODOLOGY 3.0 Introduction Research Methodology refers to the measures, and approaches used in conducting the research and outlines the research design, population of the study, sampling techniques, data collection and data analysis methods (Kothari, 2003). 3.1 Research Design According to Dooley (2007) a research design is an outline that is used to find solutions to the research problems that provides the plan on how the research will be conducted. This study will adopt a quantitative research design because of the nature of the data. 3.2 Target Population A population is a collection of all elements under consideration. It is a collection of elements, people or objects that are of interest that the researcher seeks to investigate. For this study, the Zambian government was the population of interest. 3.3 Data Collection Method This study will rely on secondary time series data obtained from the Ministry of Finance, International Monetary Fund, Bank of Zambia and the World Bank Development Indicators. The data will first be obtained and then cleaned after which it will be exported to exported to Stata for analysis. 3.4 Data Validity According to Kothari (2004) the validity of the data is the extent to which inferences are made based on the usefulness and appropriateness of the numerical scores. Validity is the most important criteria by which the survey provides for the required information to meet the study response. For this study, the sources of the data include the Ministry of Finance, International Monetary Fund, Bank of Zambia and the World Bank Development Indicators which are credible and widely accepted institutions. 3.5 Data Analysis To analyze the existence of a statistical relationship between taxation, FDI, foreign aid, Government Expenditure and economic growth in Zambia, the study will make use of a multiple regression analysis technique at a test significance level of 0.05. The existent relationship between the variables will be assessed using the regression equation while the test of significance will be analyzed using the p-value approach. 3.6 Empirical Model The empirical model of the study was formulated by taking Budget deficit, total debt, Inflation rate, Unemployment Rate, Level of education for decision makers, FDI and Foreign Aid as independent variables while introducing gross domestic product growth as the dependent variable. The regression model thus takes the form; πΊπ·π = π(π΅πΊππ·πΉ, ππ·π, πΌππΉ, πππΈππ, πΈπ·π, πΉπ΄, πΉπ·πΌ) πΊπ·π = π½0 + π½1 ππ +π½2 πΉπ·πΌ + π½3 πΉπ΄ + π½4 πΊπππΈππ + π½5 ππ΅ + Ξπ‘ Where: π΅πΊππ·πΉ = is budget deficit at a time t ππ·π = is total debt at a time t πΌππΉ = is Inflation rate at a time t πππΈππ = is Unemployment Rate at a time t πΈπ·π = is Level of education for decision makers at a time t πΉπ΄ = is Foreign Aid at a time t πΉπ·πΌ = is Foreign Direct Investment at a time t 3.7 Ethical Considerations The study will make use of actual data collected from the Ministry of Finance, International Monetary Fund, Bank of Zambia and the World Bank Development Indicators, The researcher will not engage in any falsification of results or the manipulation of results in order to suit economic theory. However, some apriori expected signs between the variables will be stated so that in an event that the results do not align with them, no alterations will be made. REFERENCES Alesina, M. and Perotti, R. 1999. Fiscal Policy, Profits, And Investment. National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper 7207. Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138. Ayadi, F. and Ayadi, O. 2008. The Impact of External Debt on Economic Growth: A Comparative Study of Nigeria and South Africa. Journal of Sustainable Development in Africa. Volume 10, No.3. Barro, R. J. 1989. The Ricardian approach to budget deficits. The Journal of Economic Perspectives. Volume 3. pg. 37-54. Baum, A., Checherita-Westphal, C., and Rother, P. (2012). Debt and growth: New evidence for the Euro Area. ECB Working Paper. No. 1450. Bird, R. M. (1971). Wagner’s law of expanding state activity. Public Finance. Volume 26, 1-26. BOZ, 2021. 2021 Annual Report, Lusaka: Bank of Zambia. FSD Zambia , 2020. FinScope 2020 Survey Topline Findings. FSD. Lusaka GRZ, 2009. Public Private Partnership Act, Lusaka: Government of the Republic of Zambia. Lwanga, E. N., 2021. “Financial Access Expansion and Rural-Urban Welfare Disparities: Evidence from Zambia”, AERC Research Paper 461 African Economic Research Consortium. Nairobi Lwanga, E. N., 2021. Financial Access Expansion and Rural-Urban Welfare Disparities: Evidence from Zambia”, AERC Research Paper 461 African Economic Research Consortium. Nairobi Martínez, J., 2006. Access to financial services in Zambia”. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4061. The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Ministry of Finance and National Planning, 2022. Annual Economic Report. Lusaka Ministry of National Development Planning , 2017. Seventh National Development Plan 2017-2021, Lusaka: Government of the Republic of Zambia. MoFNP, 2016. Annual Economic Report. Lusaka: Ministry of Finance. MoFNP, 2021. National Budget. Lusaka: Ministry of Finance and National Planning. MoFNP, 2022. 2021 Annual Economic Report, Lusaka: Ministry of FInance and National Planning. Pensions and Insurance Authority, 2020. Annual Report. Lusaka. PIA, 2020. Annual Report, Lusaka: Pensions and Insurance Authority. Public Private Partnership Act, n.d. Government of the Republic of Zambia.. Lusaka Ratha, D., 2015. What are Remittances?. Washington DC: World Bank. Siwale, T. & Chibuye, B., 2019. Mining taxation policy in Zambia: The tranny of indecision. [Online] Available at: https://www.theigc.org/blog/mining-taxation-policy-in-zambia-the- tyranny-of-indecision/ UNCTAD, 2013. Maximising the Development Impact of Remittances. Geneva: UNCTAD. UNDP , 2021. Development Finance Assessment Guidebook 3.0.. Retrieved from https://inff.org/resource/development-finance-assessment-guidebook ed. s.l. UNDP, 2018. Gambia Development Finance Assessment. UNDP, 2021. Tanzania Development Finance Assessment Report. World Bank, 2020. Africa Pulse Report - Assessing the Economic Impact of the COVID-19 and Policy Responses in Sub-Saharan Africa. Lusaka: World Bank. World Bank, 2021. From Green, Resilient and Inclusive Recovery. Washington DC: World Bank. World Bank, 2022. Africa's Pulse Report: Analysis of Issues Shaping Africa's Economic Future. Washington DC: World Bank. World Bank, 2022. World Development Indicators Data. Washington DC: World Bank. World Bank-KNOMAD, 2021. Resilience COVID-19 Crisis Through a Migration Lens - Migration and Development Brief 34. Washington DC: World Bank. Zambia Information and Communications Technology Authority , 2020.. ICT Statistics Portal and Database. Retrieved from https://www.zicta.zm/ ed. Lusaka, Zambia Zambia Institute for Policy Analysis and Research. 2018. Are Interest Payments on Debt Derailing Fiscal Consolidation? Zambia Statistics Agency, 2020. 2019 Labour Force Survey Report. Zambia Statistics Agency and Ministry of Labour and Social Security. Lusaka.