Uploaded by lilianacarbonework

Backup of vertical price antitrustnov

advertisement
Quick Reference Rules of Law
1.
Setting Vertical Minimum Prices. Vertical price restraints are to be judged by the rule of reason and are not per se illegal.
(Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., dba Kay’s Kloset … Kay’s Shoes)
2.
The Colgate Doctrine. So long as no monopoly is present, a manufacturer is free to impose conditions on retailers as a condition
precedent to further sales. (United States v. Colgate & Co.)
3.
Vertical Maximum Price Fixing. Vertical maximum price fixing is not a per se violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act. (State Oil
Company v. Khan)
4.
Dealer Termination. To state a cause of action for price-fixing a plaintiff distributor must prove that the manufacturer and other
distributors were acting in concert to illegally fix prices. (Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp.)
5.
Territorial and Customer Restraints. A nonprice vertical restraint should be judged under the rule of reason. (Continental T.V.,
Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc.)
6.
Exclusive Dealing under the Rule of Reason. Where the buyer and seller are in the same state, the relevant market may still be
found to be regional or even national. (Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co.)
7.
Per Se Rule for Tying Arrangements. A tying arrangement is only illegal under the Sherman Act where a monopolistic position
is held and a substantial volume of commerce in the “tied” product is restrained. (Times-Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States)
8.
Per Se Rule for Tying Arrangements. Where a seller exercises economic dominance over a market so that the purchaser’s free
exercise of judgment is curtailed, no tying arrangements are permissible. (Northern Pacific Railway v. United States)
9.
Tying Product Power and Anticompetitive Effects. Tie-in agreements are illegal only if the market power of the owner of the
tying product allows him to unilaterally affect prices. (Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde)
10.
Tying Product Power and Anticompetitive Effects. Lack of market power as to primary equipment does not preclude market
power in derivative aftermarkets. (Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc.)
11.
Tying Product Power and Anticompetitive Effects. A product is integrated where it combines the functionalities of two separate
products to produce benefits that only the unified combination can achieve. (United States v. Microsoft Corp.)
12.
Tying Product Power and Anticompetitive Effects. The rule of reason, rather than per se analysis, governs the legality of tying
arrangements involving platform software products. (United States v. Microsoft Corp.)
13.
Tying and Intellectual Property. The mere fact that a tying product is patented does not support the presumption of market
power in the patented product. (Illinois Tool Works, Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc.)
14.
Full System Contracts and Franchise Arrangements. A full system sales unit may be reasonable where there are legitimate
reasons for selling normally separate items in a combined form and economic conditions justify a policy of compulsory service. (United States
v. Jerrold Electronics Corp.)
Intrabrand Distributional Restraints
Resale Price Maintenance –
Setting Vertical Minimum Prices
Quicknotes
RULE OF REASON The standard for determining whether there has been a violation of § 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act, requiring a
determination of whether the activity unreasonably restrains competition as demonstrated by actual harm.
STARE DECISIS Doctrine whereby courts follow legal precedent unless there is good cause for departure.
VERTICAL AGREEMENTS. Agreements entered into by entities at different levels of production for the purpose of restraining trade.
Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., dba Kay’s Kloset … Kay’s Shoes
Manufacturer (D) v. Retailer (P)
551 U.S. 877 (2007).
NATURE OF CASE: Appeal from judgment finding a per se violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act.
FACT SUMMARY: Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. (Leegin) (D) stopped selling to PSKS, Inc.’s (PSKS’s) (P) Kay’s Kloset store when
Leegin (D) discovered that Kay’s Kloset had been marking down Leegin’s (D) goods, and PSKS (P) sued for violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act.
Leegin (D) contended that the U.S. Supreme Court’s longstanding rule of per se illegality for vertical price restrains should be overruled and
replaced with a rule of reason.
RULE OF LAW
Vertical price restraints are to be judged by the rule of reason and are not per se illegal.
FACTS: Given its policy of refusing to sell to retailers that discounted its goods, including its Brighton line of fashion accessories, below suggested
prices, Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. (Leegin) (D) stopped selling to PSKS, Inc.’s (PSKS’s) (P) Kay’s Kloset store when Leegin (D)
discovered that Kay’s Kloset had been marking down the entire Brighton line. PSKS (P) filed suit, alleging, inter alia, that Leegin (D) violated the
antitrust laws by entering into vertical agreements with its retailers to set minimum resale prices. The U.S. Supreme Court granted certiorari in the
case, and Leegin (D) contended that the Court’s longstanding rule of per se illegality for vertical price restrains should be overruled and replaced
with a rule of reason. [The procedural posture of the case is not indicated in the casebook extract.]
ISSUE: Are vertical price restraints to be judged by the rule of reason and are not per se illegal?
HOLDING AND DECISION: (Kennedy, J.) Yes. Vertical price restraints are to be judged by the rule of reason and are not per se illegal. This
case raises the issue of whether the rule of per se illegality for vertical price restraints, first handed down in Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park
& Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911), should be replaced with a rule of reason. The accepted standard for testing whether a practice restrains trade in
violation of § 1 is the rule of reason, which requires the fact finder to weigh “all of the circumstances,” including “specific information about the
relevant business” and “the restraint’s history, nature, and effect.” Resort to per se rules is confined to restraints “that would always or almost
always tend to restrict competition and decrease output.” Thus, a per se rule is appropriate only after courts have had considerable experience with
the type of restraint at issue, and only if they can predict with confidence that the restraint would be invalidated in all or almost all instances under
the rule of reason. Accordingly, any departure from the rule-of-reason standard must be based on demonstrable economic effects rather than on
formalistic line drawing. The reasons upon which Dr. Miles relied, including a treatise published in 1628, do not justify a per se rule governing the
American economy today, given that those reasons did not consider economic effects or procompetitive effects, of vertical price restraints.
Therefore, it is necessary to examine, in the first instance, the economic effects of vertical agreements to fix minimum resale prices and to determine
whether the per se rule is nonetheless appropriate. Economics literature is replete with procompetitive justifications for a manufacturer’s use of
resale price maintenance, and the few recent studies on the subject also cast doubt on the conclusion that the practice meets the criteria for a per se
rule. The justifications for vertical price restraints are similar to those for other vertical restraints. Minimum resale price maintenance can stimulate
interbrand competition among manufacturers selling different brands of the same type of product by reducing intrabrand competition among
retailers selling the same brand. This is important because the antitrust laws’ primary purpose is to protect interbrand competition. A single
manufacturer’s use of vertical price restraints tends to eliminate intrabrand price competition; this in turn encourages retailers to invest in services
or promotional efforts that aid the manufacturer’s position as against rival manufacturers. Resale price maintenance may also give consumers more
options to choose among low-price, low-service brands; high-price, high-service brands; and brands falling in between. Absent vertical price
restraints, retail services that enhance interbrand competition might be underprovided because discounting retailers can free ride on retailers who
furnish services and then capture some of the demand those services generate. Retail price maintenance can also increase interbrand competition
by facilitating market entry for new firms and brands and by encouraging retailer services that would not be provided even absent free riding.
Setting minimum resale prices may also have anticompetitive effects; and unlawful price fixing, designed solely to obtain monopoly profits, is an
ever-present temptation. Resale price maintenance may, for example, facilitate a manufacturer cartel or be used to organize retail cartels. It can also
be abused by a powerful manufacturer or retailer. Thus, the potential anticompetitive consequences of vertical price restraints must not be ignored
or underestimated. Notwithstanding the risks of unlawful conduct, it cannot be stated with any degree of confidence that retail price maintenance
“always or almost always tend[s] to restrict competition and decrease output.” Vertical retail-price agreements have either procompetitive or
anticompetitive effects, depending on the circumstances in which they were formed; and the limited empirical evidence available does not suggest
efficient uses of the agreements are infrequent or hypothetical. A per se rule should not be adopted for administrative convenience alone. Such rules
can be counterproductive, increasing the antitrust system’s total cost by prohibiting procompetitive conduct the antitrust laws should encourage.
And a per se rule cannot be justified by the possibility of higher prices absent a further showing of anticompetitive conduct. The antitrust laws
primarily are designed to protect interbrand competition from which lower prices can later result. The argument for a per se rule overlooks that, in
general, the interests of manufacturers and consumers are aligned with respect to retailer profit margins. Resale price maintenance has economic
dangers. If the rule of reason were to apply, courts would have to be diligent in eliminating their anticompetitive uses from the market. Factors
relevant to the inquiry are the number of manufacturers using the practice, the restraint’s source, and a manufacturer’s market power. The rule of
reason is designed and used to ascertain whether transactions are anticompetitive or procompetitive. This standard principle applies to vertical price
restraints. As courts gain experience with these restraints by applying the rule of reason over the course of decisions, they can establish the litigation
structure to ensure the rule operates to eliminate anticompetitive restraints from the market and to provide more guidance to businesses. Moreover,
stare decisis does not compel continued adherence to the per se rule here. Because the Sherman Act is treated as a common-law statute, its
prohibition on restraints of trade evolves to meet the dynamics of present economic conditions. The rule of reason’s case-by-case adjudication
implements this common-law approach. Here, respected economics authorities suggest that the per se rule is inappropriate. Also, both the
Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission—the antitrust enforcement agencies with the ability to assess the long-term impacts of
resale price maintenance agreements—recommend replacing the per se rule with the rule of reason. In addition, this Court has “overruled [its]
precedents when subsequent cases have undermined their doctrinal underpinnings.” It is not surprising that the Court has distanced itself from Dr.
Miles’ rationales, because the case was decided not long after the Sherman Act was enacted, when the Court had little experience with antitrust
analysis. Only eight years after Dr. Miles, the Court reined in the decision, holding that a manufacturer can suggest resale prices and refuse to deal
with distributors who do not follow them. More recently, the Court has tempered, limited, or overruled once strict nonprice vertical restraint
prohibitions. The Dr. Miles rule is also inconsistent with a principled framework for it makes little economic sense when analyzed with the Court’s
other vertical restraint cases. Deciding that procompetitive effects of resale price maintenance are insufficient to overrule Dr. Miles would call into
question cases those other cases. Finally, PSKS’s (P) arguments for reaffirming Dr. Miles based on stare decisis do not require a different result, as
there is little economic justification for the current differential treatment of vertical price and nonprice restraints. In sum, the per se rule for vertical
price restraints is a flawed antitrust doctrine that does not serve the interests of consumers. Accordingly, Dr. Miles is overruled, and vertical price
restraints are to be judged according to the rule of reason. [Reversed.]
Quicknotes
CONDITION PRECEDENT The happening of an uncertain occurrence, which is necessary before a particular right or interest
may be obtained or an action performed.
MONOPOLY A privilege or right conferred upon an individual or entity granting it the exclusive power to manufacture, sell
and distribute a particular service or commodity; a market condition in which one or a few companies control the sale of a
product or service thereby restraining competition in respect to that article or service.
PRICE-FIXING An illegal combination in violation of the Sherman Antitrust Act entered into for the purpose of setting prices
below the natural market rate.
RESTRAINT OF TRADE Agreement between entities, for the purpose of impeding free trade, that results in a monopoly,
suppression of competition, or affecting prices.
SHERMAN ACT Makes every contract or conspiracy in unreasonable restraint of commerce illegal.
United States v. Colgate & Co.
Federal government (P) v. Manufacturer (D)
250 U.S. 300 (1919).
Download