Defending State-Centric Regionalism through Mimicry and Localization: Regional Parliamentary Bodies in the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and Mercosur Jürgen Rüland, University of Freiburg juergen.rueland@uni-freiburg.de Karsten Bechle, GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies, Hamburg bechle@giga-hamburg.de Paper prepared for presentation at the IPSA-ECPR Conference on “Whatever happened to North-South?”, São Paulo, 16 to 19 February 2011 Defending State-Centric Reg1ionalism through Mimicry and Localization: Regional Parliamentary Bodies in the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and Mercosur1 Jürgen Rüland (University of Freiburg) & Karsten Bechle (GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies) Introduction The past 20 years have witnessed an unprecedented proliferation of regional organizations in all parts of the globe. Closely associated with this New Regionalism is the claim of an alternative model of regional cooperation. Many of the regional organizations formed in recent years explicitly dissociate themselves from the European Union as the globally most advanced regional cooperation scheme and model of regional integration. In contrast to the EU’s selective supranationalism they stress a strictly intergovernmental process of cooperation. Surprisingly, though, some, but by no means all of them, have also created bodies that are usually associated with a deepening of regional integration and constitutionalization; in other words, institutions closely associated with European regionalism. One of these bodies is regional parliamentary organizations. This paper seeks to explain this paradox. It seeks to explore why regional organizations have established parliamentary bodies and which functions they perform. As cases to answer this puzzle 1 The Southeast Asian part of the paper grew out of research under the Freiburg Southeast Asia Program “Grounding Area Studies in Local Practice” supported by the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research (BMBF). The Freiburg Institute of Advanced Studies (FRIAS History) provided the support and time for writing the paper. The part on South America grew out of a PhD project on the role of ideas in the regional integration process of Mercosur. The authors also thank the BMBF (Rüland) and the German Academic Exchange Service (DAAD) (Bechle) for travel grants to attend the IPSA/ECPR Congress in Sao Paolo. 1 we selected the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and Mercosur. Both are wellestablished regional organizations often associated with the New Regionalism. While this is undisputable in the case of Mercosur which was created in 1991, ASEAN, founded in 1967, may less easily be subsumed under the New Regionalism. Yet, the grouping has strongly influenced regional organizations formed in the more recent past. Many of them have carefully studied ASEAN’s experiences with regional cooperation and emulated its intergovernmentalist cooperation format. While ASEAN and Mercosur share certain structural similarities, both cases exhibit sufficient variance to make them interesting cases for comparison. The key difference is that contrary to Mercosur ASEAN does not require members to be democracies. Although with the not yet accomplished accession of Venezuela, Mercosur‘s democracy norm has been diluted, ASEAN members exhibit much greater political diversity, including new democracies such as Indonesia, highly defective democracies such as the Philippines and Thailand, semi-authoritarian regimes such as Malaysia and Singapore and autocracies such as Vietnam, Laos, Cambodia, Brunei and Myanmar. In the subsequent sections, we first assess the explanatory scope of a number of theories applied in the study of regionalism and International Relations and show that most of them have difficulties of explaining persuasively the formation, ideational roots, functions and performance of regional parliamentary bodies in ASEAN and Mercosur. We argue that sociological institutionalism is better equipped than variants of realism, liberal institutionalism and neofunctionalism to explain these issues. By applying norm diffusion theory, we show in the following two case studies that regional parliamentary bodies perform functions which are neither geared towards a deepening of regional integration through legalization and constitutionalization, nor towards the solution of collective action problems or democratizing regional governance. Rather, they have been established to retain the respective regional organization’s “cognitive prior” (Acharya 20004, 2009), which restricts decision-making to a small bureaucratic elite. This cognitive prior is in the case of ASEAN an amalgamation of imported European pre-Second World War organicist and corporatist ideas and 2 local elite constructions of power, kingship and statehood. Similarly, in the case of Mercosur, it rests upon deeply entrenched corporatist ideas and norms. The latter have more recently been covered by a veneer of neo-populism which, fused with elements of liberal democracy, has nevertheless largely retained the region’s “delegative” model of democracy (O’Donnell 1994). Theoretical Issues How can the rise of regional parliamentary bodies be theoretically explained? For conventional realist approaches international institutions are epiphenomena of international relations. They do not attach much attention to regional organizations and thus may not be expected to care about the rise of regional parliamentary bodies. An exception are variants of realism which recognize that in contemporary international politics institutions do increasingly matter and that international politics is no longer primarily determined by sheer military or compulsory power. Hegemonic stability theory, for instance, posits that durable international institutions emerge if they are created by a hegemon. Regional hegemons interested in a favorable institutional environment are thus seen as being pivotal in the formation of regional integration schemes. If this includes the formation of regional parliamentary bodies, regional powers would expect that they legitimize and strengthen their leadership role. But hegemonic stability theory fails to explain why a regional leader such as in the case of ASEAN Indonesia or in the case of Mercosur Brazil actively promotes a regional parliamentary organization without using it to enhance its regional influence. Also more recent approaches of institutional realism acknowledge the increasing significance of institutional power in international relations (He 2008). They differ from hegemonic stability theory by no longer positing that only hegemons create international institutions. For them institutions may also be created by weaker powers which employ them as devices for “soft” or “institutional balancing.” Soft or institutional balancing can take the form of internal or external balancing. 3 Internally, it would be geared towards changing or maintaining the intra-regional power equation, external balancing targets states outside the region or the power equilibrium between regions. In this view, regional parliamentary bodies would be primarily created by one or several members of a regional organization to respond to shifts in the intra-regional power equation. But institutional realism cannot explain the creation of regional parliamentary bodies which – as in the case of ASEAN or Mercosur - have not been utilized to change the intra-regional and, even less, the extra-regional power equation. For liberal institutionalism the creation of international institutions is a response to mounting bordercrossing problems and a device to manage complex interdependence. States create international institutions because they are faced with pressing functional needs which they are unable to solve individually in a cost-effective way. Successful cooperation is seen by liberal institutionalists as creating new forms of (regional) governance with an inherent trend towards legalization, contractualization and constitutionalization of international politics. This view is strongly inspired by the experiences of European integration and Western constitutionalism. It entails a strong normative and teleological dimension as it presumes sacrifices of national sovereignty and a secular trend towards supranationalism. In this perspective regional parliamentary bodies are created to balance the strongly governmental and state-centric nature of regionalism, democratizing regional governance, and hence enhance the latter’s legitimacy. But liberal institutionalists cannot explain why parliamentary bodies are created even though they are not equipped with competences to contribute to the solution of regional collective action problems and to democratize regional governance. Finally, neofunctionalism and supranationalism can explain the emergence of regional parliamentary bodies only, if they have been promoted and created by supranational bodies. Due to the New Regionalism’s strictly intergovernmental nature, the neofunctionalist perspective fails to elucidate the phenomenon of regional parliamentary bodies. Intergovernmentalism may at least explain the 4 fact that the formation of parliamentary bodies is usually a response to initiatives launched by member governments, but it may not explain the often deplored rhetoric-action gap characterizing the performance of regional parliaments. Our own approach seeks to shed light on these puzzles. We claim that sociological institutionalism provides better insights into the emergence of regional parliamentary bodies which do not enhance the political influence of regional powers, are not devices of institutional balancing and are not created to contribute to the resolution of collective action problems or the democratization of regional governance. Rather have regional parliamentary bodies been established in response to external and/or intra-regional normative pressures as institutions endowing regional organizations with legitimacy, modernity and respectability. Organizations respond to normative challenges in several ways. Wholesale normative transformation by adopting new, externally propagated paradigms occurs rarely. The belief that external norm entrepreneurs may induce norm recipients to fully change deeply entrenched beliefs and world views is an overly optimistic assumption of the early norm diffusion literature. It is driven by the Western-centrism and the telos of mainstream modernization theory and attaches agency primarily to the external norm entrepreneurs. More recent empirical evidence however suggests that this view ignores agency on the part of the norm recipients. Much more than being passive norm-takers, they may completely reject new ideas, adopt them rhetorically or amalgamate them with existing ideas (Acharya 2004, 2009). The latter two approaches are the most frequent responses of norm recipients to external challenges and need to be discussed in greater detail. Adopting new norms rhetorically is what in the norm diffusion literature is known as isomorphic behavior. In order to acquire legitimacy and to survive, organizations emulate the structure of the most advanced organization in their field. According to DiMaggio & Powell isomorphic behavior may take a coercive, mimetic and normative form (DiMaggio & Powell 1983:150). Coercive isomorphism 5 denotes a process in which compulsory or structural power exerted by one superior organization force other organizations to resort to isomorphic behavior (Ibid.:150). Mimetic isomorphism is a response of organizations to uncertainty which may be the result of ambiguous organizational goals or a lack of understanding organizational technologies (ibid.:151). Finally, normative isomorphism is facilitated by professional socialization, professional networks and filtering of personnel through hiring in the same organizational field (ibid.:152). One major characteristic of isomorphic behavior is that organizational adjustments remain largely ceremonial, causing multiple processes of decoupling in the form of rhetoric-action gaps and a hiatus between the norms underlying the new model and the normative orthodoxy (Meyer & Rowan 1979). At this point we go beyond the foundational studies, which capture the structural emulation but do not care about the cognitive underpinnings of the emulating organizations. We argue here that isomorphic behavior exists where organizations have only emulated the model organization, but retained their normative orthodoxy more or less unchanged. This occurs where the decision to imitate the structural equivalent of another organization is exclusively made in a top-down manner by an inner-ruling circle without public discourse (in case of a repressive regime) – or following what Schimmelfennig called “controversial” and “pseudo-competitive argumentation” (in case of a more permissive regime) (Schimmelfennig 2003:211). All three modes of communication (or noncommunication) do not facilitate even a partial transformation of the identity of the norm recipients. It may thus be further presumed that isomorphic behavior is likely to occur, if the response to normative challenges is chiefly designed as an act to satisfy an international audience and to muster a modicum of external legitimacy (Manea & Rüland 2010). Acharya’s concept of localization differs from isomorphic behavior by being more than only a rhetorical appropriation of new organizational structures and external norms by local recipients. It is the result of a public discourse shaped by “competitive argumentation.” The latter denotes a type of “rhetorical action,” in which the actors accept the warrant, that is, “the kinds of grounds that are 6 admissible and suitable to accept a claim” [or a norm], whereby “the grounds themselves [….] are disputed” (Schimmelfennig 2003:211). Consensus about the validity of norms opens up opportunities for mutual persuasion which in some instances may trigger a wholesale normative transformation, but more frequently only leads to limited concessions by the norm recipients in the form of fusing the new norms with the normative orthodoxy. Localization thus constitutes a strategy to contain the costs for preserving major elements of the ideational orthodoxy, but it also entails a partial transformation of identity among the norm recipients and changes societal notions of what is normatively appropriate. Such a partial transformation can be identified if the norm recipients adopt certain elements of new ideas and when they translate them into limited institutional reforms. Localization tends to occur when the external norm entrepreneurs find vocal allies within the recipient society or organization and when the ancien régime must not only increase its international respectability but also strengthen its domestic legitimacy. Yet, even though localization changes the normative orthodoxy, local norm recipients seek to make them compatible with the cognitive prior through framing, grafting and pruning so that the core, or even a major part, of the old set of norms is retained (Acharya 2004, 2009). Localization is thus a more elaborate strategy than isomorphic behavior to build legitimacy through the “modernization of tradition” (Rudolph & Hoeber-Rudolph 1967). It also involves greater concerns for organizational efficiency and thus creates a less pronounced rhetoric-action gap than isomorphic adaptation and may thereby shield against further destabilizing normative challenges. The following sections serve to test our theoretical claims empirically. They briefly contextualize the emergence of regional parliamentary bodies in the evolution of Southeast Asian and South American regionalism and seek to explain why regional parliamentary bodies have been formed and why and how they have changed over time. 7 The Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) The Formation of the ASEAN Inter-Parliamentary Organization (AIPO) In 1967 Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand founded ASEAN after two earlier attempts to promote regional cooperation in Southeast Asia, the Association of Southeast Asia (ASA) (1961) and Maphilindo (1963), had failed. With the accession of Brunei (1984), Vietnam (1995), Laos and Myanmar (1997) and Cambodia (1999) all Southeast Asian countries have joined ASEAN except Timor Leste which gained independence from Indonesia in 2002. The creation of ASEAN was certainly inspired by the rising tide of communism in Southeast Asia, but also by the desire to create peaceful inter-state relations in a region notoriously rich in unresolved disputes. After all the pro-Western governments in the region comprehended that only peaceful dispute settlement would create the favorable conditions essential for the attraction of foreign capital and technology on which their development strategy strongly relied. With rapid economic growth and broad-based prosperity they hoped to contain the communist challenge. Crucial in this respect was Indonesia’s ending of its konfrontasi against Malaysia (1963-1966), a lowintensity conflict initiated by Jakarta in response to the formation of the Federation of Malaysia, which Indonesia viewed as a neo-colonialist Trojan horse directed against Indonesia. Indonesia subsequently adopted a leadership role in the formation of ASEAN, in the process becoming the grouping’s primus inter pares. It transferred to ASEAN norms of Malay village political culture such as musyawarah dan mufakat (deliberation to reach consensus) and the concept of ketahanan regional (regional resilience), an extension of its national security doctrine of ketahanan nasional (national resilience). The latter indicated that Indonesia was also a strong proponent of an intergovernmental format of regional cooperation which distinguished ASEAN from the European Community’s (EC) selective supranationalism. In the early years, the annual foreign ministers meeting became the association’s main decision-making body, later replaced by summits of the heads of state and 8 government. With the widening functional scope of cooperation, additional ministerial rounds in the respective policy fields increased the grouping’s organizational complexity. Day-to-day routine work was in the hands of senior officials, since 1976 supported by a Jakarta-based secretariat. By that time, ASEAN had developed a set of shared cooperation norms laid down in the Treaty of Amity and Cooperation (TAC) of 1976. In the 1990s, ASEAN succeeded in framing these norms including noninterference into the internal affairs of other members, peaceful dispute settlement, territorial integrity, sovereign equality, mutual respect, harmonious relations and tolerance to become the grouping’s trademark hitherto known as the ASEAN Way. While ASEAN’s organizational structure was highly state-centric and dominated by ministerial bureaucracies, the association began to involve non-governmental groups in regional governance from the early 1970s onward. ASEAN’s foreign ministers supported the formation of the ASEANChamber of Commerce and Industries (ASEAN-CCI) in 1972 and accredited a number of other business associations. Coinciding with these developments, Indonesia started an initiative to form a regional legislative body in 1974. After lengthy deliberations, ASEAN member countries finally agreed on a statute in 1977 and eventually launched the ASEAN Inter-Parliamentary Organization (AIPO). One year later, in September 1978, AIPO held the first of its so far thirty-four General Assemblies in Singapore (The House of Representatives of the Republic of Indonesia and AIPO Secretariat 2003:2). In 2007 the AIPO statute was slightly amended and the organization renamed ASEAN InterParliamentary Assembly (AIPA). As laid down in the AIPA statute, the parliamentary forum’s main decision-making and executive bodies are the General Assembly, the Presidency, the Executive Committee, the Committees, a women’s group (WAIPA), the Secretariat, the National AIPA Secretariats and, launched very recently, the AIPA Caucus. The General Assembly as the main formal decision-making body meets annually and convenes in the country holding the AIPA presidency. Each member country sends up to fifteen delegates. The delegation is headed by the Speaker or his representatives, at least five members of 9 the delegation must be women and, in order to ensure a modicum of continuity, at least five members must have participated in the immediately preceding General Assembly. The General Assembly adopts policy initiatives and provides inputs to policy formulation on issues of common concern through resolutions and recommendations. All its decisions must be made by consensus. It is supported by six Standing Committees,2 Study Committees and Ad-hoc Committees. The presidency rotates among member countries in alphabetical order. The President represents AIPA at ASEAN Summits and chairs the Executive Committee. The latter is composed of not more than three delegates of each member parliament, one of whom shall be the Speaker. The Executive Committee prepares the agenda of the General Assembly, proposes setting up committees, monitors the implementation of the latter’s resolutions, supervises the AIPA Secretariat and appoints the Secretariat’s staff.3 The AIPA Secretariat is headed by a Secretary General, who is appointed by the AIPA President with the approval of the General Assembly for a 3-year term. He or she monitors and conducts all AIPA activities and interacts with ASEAN, in particular the ASEAN Secretariat, and with other international parliamentary organizations. With only five experts the Secretariat’s staff is small, which may suffice to carry out routine work but which is absolutely inadequate to tackle more ambitious tasks. In its monitoring and implementing tasks the Secretariat is thus strongly dependent on the AIPA National Secretariats which serve as links between the national legislature and AIPA. The revised Statute of 2007 not only changed AIPO’s name to AIPA, but in accordance with the objectives of the ASEAN Charter also sought to strengthen ASEAN’s implementation capacity and thereby contribute to a deepening of Southeast Asian regionalism.4 One way of doing this is to work 2 These are Committees on Political, Economic, Social and Organizational Matters, Joint Communiqué and Dialogue with Observer Countries. 3 See AIPA Statute, AIPA Website http://www.aipasecretariat.org/about/statutes/ (accessed 19 September 2010). 4 http://www.aipasecretariat.org/about/background-history/the-renaming-of-aipo-to-aipa/ (accessed 19 September 2010. 10 towards a greater harmonization of legislation among ASEAN countries and to place greater emphasis on the implementation of AIPA’s resolutions through the member legislatures. In order to facilitate these two objectives, AIPA formed a new body, the AIPA Caucus. The Caucus consists of three members from each country, one member from Special Observer Countries, the Secretary General of AIPA and one official each from the respective AIPA National Secretariats.5 AIPA’s organizational structure suggests that the forum is not a genuine regional legislature. As a legislature it would perform representative, legislative and oversight functions. AIPA, however, does not perform any of these functions to a noteworthy extent. AIPA’s representativeness is spurious as the majority of member countries send handpicked delegates from the ruling parties to the General Assembly. Opposition legislators are conspicuously absent. As a strictly intergovernmental institution AIPA also lacks legislative powers. It exerts its limited recommendatory functions mainly through resolutions of which it has passed over 400 since its inauguration in 1977. This said does not mean to belittle the effect of resolutions. Resolutions passed by a highly articulate, representative and, hence, legitimate body may well develop substantial discursive power. The debates preceding resolutions may help to create fresh insights into existing problems, resolutions may have agenda-setting functions and may frame, dramatize and publicize issues, thereby exerting early warning functions. Yet, as much as AIPA’s resolutions are intended to serve as policy inputs to regional governance, they are usually very general and lacking precise guidelines and technical specifications how identified problems could be addressed and remedied. This vagueness leaves national legislatures much room for interpretation on how to translate resolutions into national law, a deficiency seriously impeding the envisioned harmonization of ASEAN laws. Worse even, as AIPA resolutions are non-binding, national legislatures cannot be forced to implement them, thereby complicating another goal AIPA has placed high on its agenda since its 5 See AIPA Website, http://www.aipasecretariat.org/reports/aipa-caucus-reports/first-aipa-caucus-report/ and http://www.aipasecretariat.org/reports/aipa-caucus-reports/second-aipa-caucus-report/ (accessed 19 September 2010). 11 renaming. Finally, the AIPA Caucus as the new body designed to support a greater legalization of ASEAN through promoting the harmonization of national legislation, is so far organizationally absolutely underequipped to perform the ambitious tasks envisaged for it. Given the body’s pro-government composition, it is also hardly surprising that it does not critically scrutinize official ASEAN policies. In fact, its oversight performance is weak. Rather than acting as watchdogs over regional policies, AIPA General Assemblies retroactively affirm policies previously agreed by ASEAN. AIPA resolutions “support,” “welcome,” “re-affirm” or “endorse” ASEAN policies, even if these are at variance with the aspirations and expectations of legislators’ constituents and the policies promoted by national legislatures. One illustrative example in this respect is AIPA’s persistent support for trade liberalization under the auspices of ASEAN’s Economic Community pillar despite the fact that the Indonesian, Philippine and Thai parliaments prefer more protectionist policies. An exception in this respect is the ASEAN Inter-Parliamentary Myanmar Caucus (AIPMC), a group of legislators loosely connected with AIPA which formed the caucus in 2004. Most of its members are from Indonesia, Malaysia, Thailand and the Philippines, and a few from Singapore and Cambodia. They vocally criticize ASEAN’s policy of “constructive engagement” towards Myanmar, although Jones has shown that the governments of some of these countries merely instrumentalize their parliamentarians to initiate shifts in their Burma policy without overly damaging official relations (Jones 2009). Yet, due to the controversial issues raised by the caucus which especially the authoritarian regimes in ASEAN regard as irritating, AIPA so far denied the Caucus recognition as an official body of AIPA. The same occurred to the ASEAN Inter-Parliamentary Caucus on Good Governance which was launched in late 2005 by many of the legislators who are active in the AIMPC. 12 Explaining ASEAN’s Legislative Body How do we explain the formation of AIPO and the fact that the forum of Southeast Asian legislators is quite remote from a regional legislature? Indonesia has initiated AIPO, but neither used it to create for itself a favorable institutional environment nor as an institutional arena for strengthening its regional leadership role. AIPO also did not become a vehicle for purposes of institutional balancing. While all these observations rule out realist explanations, liberal institutionalist explanations likewise cannot well explain AIPO’s formation and operation as legislators did little to contribute to the solution of the region’s collective action problems. Sociological institutionalism offers a more persuasive answer to our puzzle, explaining the initiative to create AIPO as mimetic isomorphic behavior.6 The latter is – as we have argued above - a response of organizations to uncertainty resulting from ambiguous organizational goals and/or a lack of understanding organizational technologies (DiMaggio & Powell 1983:151). Taking a closer look at the circumstances of AIPO’s formation, ASEAN was indeed in a situation of profound uncertainty. The end of the Vietnam War ushered in major geopolitical changes to which the organization had to respond by adjusting its organizational goals. While it did this with the Treaty of Amity and Cooperation (TAC) and the Declaration of ASEAN Concord at its first summit held in Bali in 1976, several of its member governments such as Indonesia, Thailand and the Philippines also faced domestic challenges and intensifying demands for more democracy. Uncertainties also loomed in the economic realm. Malaysia and Singapore lost their Commonwealth preferences with the British accession to the EC, while import substitution in Thailand and the Philippines had reached the limits of narrow domestic markets and was in the stranglehold of protectionist vested interests. As ASEAN countries continued to regard continuous rapid economic growth as a major precondition to contain communist threats, most of them initiated a shift towards a more outward-looking export- 6 See also Jetschke (2009) and Jetschke & Rüland (2009). 13 oriented development strategy. While their policies of economic opening were plurilateral, the EC was one of the main targets. In the early 1970s ASEAN countries intensified relations with the EC, which by the end of the decade became an ASEAN dialogue partner, a process culminating in a cooperation treaty concluded in 1980. In the view of ASEAN governments, more European capital could be attracted and economic relations intensified, if the association succeeds boosting its legitimacy and respectability. Hence, the imitation of European structures of economic interest representation through the formation and accreditation of regional business organizations and the establishment of a regional legislative body. Already in the 1970s the EC was widely acknowledged as the most advanced and most successful scheme of regional integration which other regional organizations found worthwhile to emulate. While the idea to create a regional legislative body may have been the result of institutional mimicry, the actual formation may be better explained as coercive isomorphic behavior. Although the initial response of ASEAN member countries to the Indonesian overtures was lukewarm, they eventually agreed to the formation of AIPO when after the Helsinki Accord, Jimmy Carter’s election as U.S. president and the emergence of transnational advocacy networks, democracy and human rights for the first time became international themes and exerted pressures on ASEAN’s autocracies. Their structural dependencies on Western powers have certainly been part of their motivation to rhetorically emulate the European Parliament and to create a façade of adherence to democratic principles. That the formation of AIPO was driven by isomorphic behavior can also be gleaned from the fact that it did not go hand in hand with even a partial identity change among ASEAN government elites. The formation of AIPO was an exclusively elitist decision, without even a modicum of public debate and largely addressed to an international audience. It left ASEAN’s cognitive prior largely unaltered. ASEAN’s cognitive prior differs strongly from the liberal-pluralist model of interest representation to which ASEAN seemed to tilt with the accreditation of interest groups and the formation of a 14 legislative body. The operation of AIPO was devised in a way that it largely kept intact the organicist and corporatist mode of interest representation which ASEAN’s authoritarian regimes had imported from Europe since the 1920s, localized with organicist elements of local political culture and from the domestic domain transferred to AIPO and ASEAN’s other mechanisms of interaction with interest groups. European authoritarian corporatism stressed social unity, harmonious class relations which it sought to secure through vertical instead of horizontal societal organization, limitation of political participation to “participation in implementation” instead of “participation in decision-making”7 and likening the political system to an organic or familial system. These ultra-conservative notions of societal organization tallied well with local beliefs about the nature of power. The latter, derived from Hindu-Brahmanic court rules in the Indianized parts of Southeast Asia, perceived power as a resource that is indivisible, finite, amoral and concentrated in the ruler. Decentralization or the existence of multiple power centres, due to their power-limiting effects virtues in liberal-pluralist theory, were therefore regarded as weakness and symptom of the ruler’s waning legitimacy (Anderson 1972). Authoritarian corporatism also resonated well in Islamic societies with the unity of religion and state, Confucianism, socialist political systems and in Philippine Catholicism. A closer look at AIPO’s operation suggests that the forum has never shed its organicist and corporatist ideational underpinning. First, until to the present, many delegations regard the exclusion of opposition legislators as an act of strengthening regional unity. Second, AIPO and, subsequently, AIPA’s largely affirmative posture towards ASEAN’s regional policies indicates that it is a body for strengthening “participation in implementation” rather than “participation in decision-making.” AIPO, in other words, is thus primarily acting as a transmission belt, making ASEAN policies palatable to legislatures which usually exhibit greater scepticism towards regional cooperation than government bureaucrats. Third, until very recently, AIPO documents suggest that the forum’s largely anti-liberal notions of concepts such as democracy and human rights have hardly changed since the 7 For the various modes of participation, see Cohen& Uphoff (1980). 15 1970s. Fourth, and final, a closer examination of the speeches held at the General Assemblies indicates that the language of corporatism with its frequent references to kinship and familism, unity and harmony is still ubiquitous. The renaming of AIPO into AIPA has hardly changed this pattern. It is another mimetic response, this time driven by increasing external and domestic pressures on ASEAN governments to democratize their polities and, for the first time, also regional governance. While most of these demands to democratize ASEAN decision-making centred on civil society participation, forcing ASEAN to make substantial concessions and triggering a partial identity change among some member governments, there was little pressure to democratize ASEAN’s legislative body. Demands to create a regional legislature date back to the 1980s, but have never received serious consideration. Given the low public trust legislatures and legislators enjoy in most ASEAN countries, they were never mentioned in public debates as vehicles to democratize regional governance. The re-naming of AIPO thus had few practical consequences and did not change the bodies’ operation. Mercosur From the Joint Parliamentary Commission to the Mercosur Parliament The origins of regional integration in the Southern Cone date back to a series of bilateral agreements between Argentina and Brazil throughout the 1980s. Eventually the smaller neighbours Uruguay and Paraguay were invited to join the integration process and in March 1991 Mercosur was formally launched through the Treaty of Asuncion.8 After a transitional period of 3 years, Mercosur’s institutional structure was fixed in December 1994 by the Protocol of Ouro Preto (POP). Its main decision-making bodies are the Council of the Common Market (Consejo del Mercado Comun, CMC), 8 Mercosur’s foundational treaty and the protocols mentioned below are available from the organization’s website: http://www.mercosur.org.uy. 16 the Common Market Group (Grupo del Mercado Comun, GMC) and the Commission of Commerce (Comisión de Comercio del Mercosur, CCM). As the superior organ of Mercosur the CMC exercises the political leadership of the organization. It is composed of the ministers of foreign affairs and economy, who meet at least twice a year in the presence of the heads of state. The GMC is the executive organ of Mercosur and subordinated to the CMC. It takes the necessary measures to implement the decisions adopted by the Council. Finally, the CCM is in charge of the commercial policy and the application of the external tariff. While the Argentinean-Brazilian tandem that initiated the integration process remained crucial for Mercosur’s further development, the regional hegemon Brazil has often been the driver behind such initiatives as the establishment of the Mercosur Parliament. With its lean institutional structure, the consensual practice of decision-making and the focus on pragmatism and flexibility Mercosur is a typical example of the New Regionalism. Mercosur functions on a strictly intergovernmental base. All bodies are composed of national staff and binding decisions have to be taken by consensus. There is no transfer of national sovereignty to any supranational instance. The Administrative Secretariat, which is located in Montevideo, Uruguay, is the only permanent body established by the POP. This notwithstanding, the POP also established a Joint Parliamentary Commission (Comisión Parlamentaria Conjunta, CPC), which is the representative body of the Member State’s parliaments. Civil society should be represented by the Consultative Economic and Social Forum (Foro Consultivo Económico Social, FCES). The CPC, which was formally succeeded by the Mercosur Parliament in 2006, was originally composed of sixteen delegates from each member state’s national legislature. According to its Rules of Procedure,9 it had a consultative and deliberative character. It requested information about the path of integration from other Mercosur institutions and it was meant to accelerate the internal proceedings within the national parliaments to ensure a quick implementation of those Mercosur 9 CPC, Res. N° 2/97. 17 norms, which need to be incorporated into national law. The CPC thus functioned as a transmission belt between the regional organization’s decision-making organs and the national parliaments. Regular meetings took place twice a year in the country which held the Pro Tempore Presidency of the Mercosur. At the top of the CPS’s institutional structure stood an executive board that was composed of the members of the executive boards of the national sections. Each board consisted of the president, a vice-president, a secretary general and an assistant secretary. The CPC furthermore maintained a small permanent administrative secretariat (SAPP) in Montevideo. It created eight subcommissions. All its decisions had to be taken by consensus of the national delegations, who expressed themselves through a majoritarian vote of their members. Although the CPC and the FCES were conceived of as an expression of Mercosur’s social dimension, their institutional structure and practices mirrored the prevailing norms and ideas held by political elites in the member states at the time. Nevertheless it was upon the initiative of the CPC that shortly after the transition from authoritarian rule, the member states’ compromise with democracy was cast into institutional form. The Protocol of Ushuaia, signed in 1998 by all member states including the associated members Bolivia and Chile, made the adherence to the rule of democracy a necessary precondition for the participation in the regional integration process. Yet democracy, as understood by the elites in most Southern American countries, is largely confined to its procedural dimension. This also explains why the inclusion of Venezuela is not regarded as an infringement of Mercosur’s democratic norm. South America’s political regimes have thus been described as “democracies with adjectives,” “hybrid regimes” or “delegative democracies.” Mercosur’s institutional structure with its focus on flexibility and its operative practice with the outstanding role of the presidents in the settlement of controversies reflect this delegative leadership style. Although the CPC had been working for the establishment of a parliamentary body for many years, it thus took most observers by surprise when the then new president of Brazil, Lula da Silva, and his Argentinean counterpart, Eduardo Duhalde, in January 2003 declared that the CPC should advance in 18 the direction of a Mercosur parliament. The idea to strengthen Mercosur’s institutional structure got further momentum after the election of Nestor Kirchner in Argentina, with the Mercosur Parliament (Parlasur) eventually constituted in Montevideo in December 2006 (Casal 2005; Caetano 2006). The Constitutive Protocol of the Mercosur Parliament10 provided for two transitional periods. The first one ranged from 2007 until 2010 and the second one started in 2011 and will last until 2014. During the first period, Parlasur was composed of eighteen representatives from each national parliament. The composition of the Mercosur parliament thus tended to reproduce the political power equation within national parliaments. Only Venezuela, where oppositional candidates declined to participate in national legislative elections, was merely represented by members of the government party. As Venezuela is still in the process of admission, its representatives have a voice but cannot vote. Beginning with the second period there will be a decreasing proportional representation11 and parliamentarians from each member state will be elected directly according to the time schedule of national elections.12 The second transitional period will result in a dissociation of the national and the regional parliamentary bodies since Parlasur delegates may not exercise any other legislative or executive functions in their member states or other Mercosur organs. Beginning in 2014 parliamentarians in all member states shall be elected simultaneously by direct, universal and secret suffrage. Paraguay and Uruguay will then hold eighteen seats, Argentina forty-three and Brazil seventy-five. As a counterweight to these imbalances, most decisions have to be taken by a 10 CMC, Dec. N° 23/05, Protocolo Constitutivo del Parlamento del Mercosur. Throughout the second transitional period Uruguay and Paraguay retain eighteen seats, whereas Argentina holds twenty-six and Brazil thirty-seven seats. 12 Paraguay has already elected its Parlasur delegates during the presidential and legislative elections in September 2008. Argentina will probably choose its delegates in 2011, Brazil in 2012. See Parlasur website: http://www.parlamentodelmercosur.org/innovaportal/v/4993/1/secretaria/parlasur_discute_sobre_eleccione s_directas.html (accessed on 4 February 2011). 11 19 “special” majority (mayoría especial) which requires two-thirds of all representatives and has to include delegates from all member states.13 According to its constitutive protocol Parlasur represents the peoples of the Mercosur, respecting their ideological and political plurality. It will promote and defend democracy, peace and liberty and it shall guaranty the participation of the actors of civil society in the integration process. The parliament is directed by a president who represents it and is in charge of its official communication. He or she is elected by the general assembly and presides the plenary sessions. The president is assisted by one vice-president from each of the other member states. Together they compose the board of officers (mesa directiva). Members of the board are elected for 2 years with one possible reelection. The board of officers, amongst others, proposes the administrative and financial organization and staff regulations to the plenary, approves the agenda, convenes extraordinary sessions of the parliament, and establishes the composition of the standing committees. It is assisted by a parliamentarian secretary and an administrative secretary. Four permanent secretariats are established at the seat of the parliament: besides the parliamentarian secretariat and the administrative secretariat there is also a secretariat for institutional relations and social communication and one for international relations and integration. The Parliament has ten standing committees, which may be supplemented by temporary and special committees and by external delegations.14 Ordinary sessions take place at least once a month. From the inaugural session in May 2007 until the end of 2010 Parlasur held twenty-seven plenary and ten extraordinary sessions.15 13 Political Agreement for the Consolidation of Mercosur and Corresponding Propositions, see Parlasur website: http://www.parlamentodelmercosur.org/innovaportal/file/3029/1/Acuerdo%20Pol%EDtico.pdf (accessed on 4 February 2011). The agreement was approved by the CMC in October 2010 through Dec. N° 28/10. 14 Standing committees have been established on judicial and institutional affairs; economic, financial, commercial, fiscal and monetary affairs; international and interregional affairs and strategic planning; education, culture, science, technology and sports; work, employment policies, social security and social economy; sustainable regional development, territorial planning, housing, health, environment and tourism; citizenship and human rights; internal affairs, security and defence; infrastructure, transport, energetic resources, agriculture, livestock and fishing; budget and internal affairs. 15 See Parlasur-website: http://www.parlamentodelmercosur.org (accessed on 4 Februar 2011). 20 With the transition from the CPC to the Parliament the representative functions of Mercosur’s regional body have been remarkably improved. By abandoning the principle of an equal representation of all member states and adopting a model of decreasing integration, Parlasur better copes with the enormous demographic differences between its member states. Even more important are the provisions for the establishment of political groups. Whereas the CPC was organized along national commissions, which had to converge on a single vote by majority rule, delegates in the Mercosur Parliament may form groups according to their political alignment and thus transcend national boundaries. Parlasur also examines petitions from legal and individual persons and channels them towards the decision-making bodies of Mercosur. Yet the improved representativeness of the Mercosur parliament contrast sharply with its lack of legislative functions. The Constitutive Protocol and the Rules of Procedure provide for a wide array of parliamentary acts. But they do not give the parliament any substantial legislative power. Parlasur may propose legislative projects and present them to the CMC; it may also propose measures for the harmonization of member states’ legislation and present them to the national parliaments. Yet throughout its first transitional period the parliament has mainly acted through declarations and recommendations directed at the decision-making bodies of the Mercosur. Declarations often express the Parliament’s “support” or “endorsement” of member states’ foreign policies or the positions they take in multilateral organizations. But they also express the Parliament’s consent to the further deepening of regional integration. Accordingly, recommendations often call for concrete measures in areas such as civic participation or infrastructure projects. Furthermore there are a large number of provisions regarding the internal organization of the parliament. Most outstanding from its present record, however, is the lack of opinions (dictámenes) given by the parliament. The Constitutive Protocol stipulates that the Parliament gives its opinion on legislative projects, which need to be incorporated into national law in one or more member states, if the Council sends them to the Parliament before they are approved. The national parliaments in turn take provisions for the 21 quick implementation of a legislative project if it has been endorsed by the Mercosur Parliament. This idea was first introduced in a much celebrated inter-institutional agreement between the CMC and the CPC in 2003, which was the outcome of a project to improve the institutional quality of the CPC sponsored by the European Commission (Dreyzin de Klor 2004: 30 f). Yet the CMC has never made use of the instrument and still seems to ignore it under the new provisions of the Mercosur Parliament. Parlasur also performs some oversight functions. It may request reports and written opinions from the bodies with decision-making authority and the consultative organs established in the POP. These have to be responded within a maximum space of 180 days. Furthermore, at the beginning and the end of its half-year term, the Pro Tempore Presidency of the Mercosur has to present the parliament its working program and a report on its completed activities, respectively. Parlasur also holds semestral meetings with the FCES. Explaining Mercosur’s institutional structure The founding of Mercosur can be explained as a reaction to the multiple uncertainties faced by its member states at the time. Throughout the 1980s the Southern American countries had successively undergone a process of democratic transition. But it was not yet sure how stable the new regimes would be. The democratic government of Argentina, for instance, still had to face a number of military uprisings throughout the first decade after transition. Moreover, the country had just lost a war and its international reputation was damaged by the dismal human rights record of the preceding military government. The preservation of democracy, stability and peace were amongst the most pressing needs in order to regain at least a modicum of credit on the international stage. No less uncertain was the economic outlook for the future Mercosur members. The outbreak of the Latin American debt crisis in the early 1980s seemed to irrevocably foreclose a return to the 22 protectionist and inward-oriented development model that had prevailed throughout the region since the 1930s. Moreover, the incipient globalization of the world economy and the formation of economic blocks in other world regions left Southern Americans with fears of becoming marginalized. Regional integration was thus conceived of as a means to collectively integrate the hitherto often overprotected economies of the Southern Cone in the world economy. In this situation of uncertainty Mercosur members harked back to the European Union as the most prominent and successful example of regional integration. While Mercosur’s main decision-making bodies, the CMC and the GMC, resemble the European Council and the European Commission, the grouping’s representative bodies, the FCES and the parliamentary institution (CPC), mimic the European Economic and Social Council and the European Parliament, respectively. In fact, the formation of a regional parliamentary assembly satisfies all key criteria of a mimetic isomorphic behavior as defined in the theoretical part of the paper. The idea to provide Mercosur with representative institutions was not derived from a consensus that had emerged in a previous process of communicative action. A public discourse about the future institutional shape of regional integration was non-existent at the time. Isolated from societal pressures, a small political elite within the national executives decided upon the institutional outlook of Mercosur with the objective of improving the organization’s international reputation and, by coincidence, their own political legitimacy. In practice, however, the commitment to parliamentarian representation and the inclusion of civil society exhibited the decoupling typical for isomorphic responses to normative pressures. Even though Mercosur’s institutional outlook resembles that of the European Union, the corresponding organs have by no means achieved a comparable importance in the process of taking and implementing decisions. Mercosur has largely been an organization run by its national executives. All important decisions and the resolution of conflicts have been reserved to the presidential level. The regional integration scheme insofar heavily resembles the delegative democracies in the member states (cf. Malamud 2003, 2005). 23 This means that the formation of a parliamentary body did not signify a change of identity on the part of the ruling elites. The delegative democracies that replaced the authoritarian predecessor regimes throughout the 1980s are characterized by weak and dysfunctional institutions, which are often substituted by informal practices, and the delegation of political power to the top of the state. As a consequence, “whoever wins election to the presidency is thereby entitled to govern as he or she sees fit, constrained only by the hard facts of existing power relations and by a constitutionally limited term of office” (O'Donnell 1994: 59). The presidential leader is conceived of as the embodiment of the nation and the sole actor capable of uniting the dispersed fragments of society into a whole (Ibid.: 60). Parliaments and other institutions of horizontal accountability do not fit well with such an idea of paternalistic leadership. In fact, they are regarded “as a mere impediment to the full authority that the president has been delegated to exercise” (Ibid.: 60). The delegative democracy practiced in South America’s new democracies may thus be regarded as a cognitive adjustment of conservative elites to the challenges of democratization. It tallies well with South America’s powerful organicist and corporatist “cognitive prior” (Acharya 2004, 2009). The region’s longstanding tradition of corporatism reached its peak between the end of the nineteenth and the second half of the twentieth century, but its origins can be traced back to the colonial period (Wiarda 2001). Corporatist ideas have thrived under different political regimes. In the Southern Cone they were particularly influential during the populist rule of Peron and Vargas and the subsequent military regimes (Malloy 1977). Shortly after democratization, paternalistic thinking and corporatist views of state-society relations were still prevalent in the mind-set of South American political elites. Some authors even argue that civic inclusion is still impeded by a “long-standing and deep-seated hostility towards ‘ordinary people’ on the part of the governing elites” (Grugel 2006: 212). These residues of authoritarian and corporatist ideas can explain the creation of the CPC as a fig leaf for the democratic representation of Mercosur’s citizens. And it also explains why the CPC, despite its pro- 24 active engagement in issues of regional integration, has never been regarded as a serious interlocutor by the national elites within Mercosur’s decision-making bodies (Vazquez 2001). While the organicist and corporatist normative orthodoxy markedly shaped regional governance in Mercosur’s formative years, at the level of member countries corporatist modes of interest representation have come under increasing pressure in the 1990s. State reform and structural adjustment measures have largely eroded corporatist institutions throughout the decade (Oxhorn 1998; Hagopian 1998). This has strengthened a new type of political leadership that is less attached to corporatist institutions. Challenges of corporatism came in particular from neo-populist leadership and proliferating grass-roots mobilization through civil society organizations. Populism usually stands for widespread sentiments in society that government is elitist and corrupt and that the political system is in a state of representational and legitimacy crisis (Canovan 1999:2; Taggart 2002:65). It thrives under conditions of profound social change, social insecurity and growing societal complexities as brought about in South America by economic liberalization and the increasingly felt onslaught of accelerating globalization. Civil society organizations, on the other hand, could flourish in the less repressive political climate of the region’s new democracies and they could, in view of the plight inflicted by the financial crises of the 1980s and late 1990s on the less affluent sections of society, vociferously demand more participatory rights for the people. In the process, this debate about more popular participation spilled over from the domestic domains to the regional arena. In contrast to the creation of the CPC, in the case of Parlasur the adoption of new ideas went beyond mere mimesis. Since the end of the 1990s discussions about the shortcomings of Mercosur’s institutional structure and the future outlook for regional integration gained momentum. Civil society organizations had become far more entangled with issues of regional integration than in the early 1990s. To be sure, most NGOs targeted their protests first and foremost against the idea of a Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) that would comprise all American countries including the members of Mercosur. Whereas many organizations rejected the 25 idea of hemispheric integration under the lead of the United States, they still endorsed regional integration in the South. Discussions in these groups circled around the establishment of a “different model” of regional integration. Amongst others they involved demands about a democratization of Mercosur and a stronger participation of civil society in the integration process (Grugel 2006). The idea to enhance Mercosur’s democratic profile through the creation of a regional parliament thus gained prominence in certain segments of society. The CPC had promoted its own conversion into a parliamentary body from the very beginning of its existence (Vazquez 2001; Konrad-AdenauerStiftung & Comisión Parlamentaria Conjunta del Mercosur 2004). These claims were actively endorsed by the EU through financial support and the transfer of knowledge (Dri 2010: 59-62). Donor organizations such as political foundations organized discussions or generated information on the role of parliaments in regional integration processes. In this context of an increasing public awareness of the democratic deficits of Mercosur and intensifying discussion about the pros and cons of a regional parliament, the political leaders from Brazil and Argentina presented their initiative for the installation of a Mercosur Parliament. In contrast to the establishment of the CPC this did not happen in isolation from society. Moreover, the expert group (Grupo Técnico de Alto Nivel, GTAN) that elaborated the first draft of the Constitutive Protocol of the Mercosur Parliament was largely composed of well-renowned experts that had actively participated in the preceding discussions and embraced the idea of a strong representative body. Provisions like the decreasing proportional representation of the member states’ population, the decision-making procedures with different forms of majorities, the organization of the parliament along political groups instead of national sections, the permanent character with regular sessions and last but not least the election of its delegates by universal, direct and secret vote are substantial qualitative improvements . These institutional reforms suggest at least a partial identity change among the elites which in the wake of external normative pressures and a vocal domestic discourse have little choice than to make normative concessions to their critics. But they stand in sharp 26 contrast to the Parliament’s lack of any substantial legislative power, which reflects the unchanged attitudes of the national elites represented in the regional organization’s decision-making bodies towards the Parliament. While these attitudes may today be less undergirded by corporatism, they reflect the ambiguous nature of populism. On the one hand, populism expresses popular desires for greater participatory spaces in society, but on the other it also fosters the rise of charismatic leaders whose paternalistic notions of leadership tally perfectly with the concept of delegative democracy. Although the institutional reform of Mercosur may have gone far and even foreshadow supranational elements, greater regional democracy is curtailed by the grafting and pruning of the new ideas to make them compatible with the region’s cognitive prior. Mercour’s parliamentary reforms are thus little more than a strategy of providing legitimacy to a form of rule deeply entrenched in the region’s political cultures. Conclusion In this paper we have explained the establishment of legislative bodies in ASEAN and Mercosur by concepts derived from sociological institutionalism. We have shown how isomorphism and the localization of external norms have transformed the institutional design of both regional organizations without significantly altering the norms and procedures upon which these organizations rest. Both the establishment of AIPO and the subsequent renaming into AIPA and the creation of the CPC and its transformation into Parlasur have neither contributed to a democratization of these organizations nor to a deepening of regional integration. Quite to the contrary, elites in both regions succeeded in preserving their organizations’ cognitive prior. Cultural differences between Southeast Asia and Latin America notwithstanding, there is a common denominator of those norms, ideas and values that undergird cooperation in both regions. 27 This common denominator rests upon corporatist conceptions of state and society and a paternalistic view of political leadership. On the other hand, differences between ASEAN and Mercosur emerged regarding the local responses to external norm pressures. Whereas both ASEAN and Mercosur initially merely copied European institutions in an act of mimetic or coercive isomorphism, the further path of both integration schemes varied to a considerable degree. Even though ASEAN and Mercosur shared the experience of increasing domestic pressures on regional governance, in ASEAN’s case they did not target the regional legislative body. ASEAN could thus confine AIPO to minor rhetorical and symbolic changes. In South America, on the other hand, democratic pressures did not exclude the regional parliament. Unlike ASEAN, Mercosur thus responded with localization to these pressures, which brought about at least partial identity change among Mercosur decision-makers and much more far-reaching institutional changes than in ASEAN’s case. Parlasur meets more frequently, it is more representative, entails interaction with civil society groups and by allowing the formation of regional party factions and introducing qualified majority decisions even moves cautiously towards a supranationalist structure. Yet, as the legislature exerts if legislative and oversight functions only very marginally, a sizeable rhetoric-action gap remains, with the effect of retaining the grouping’s elitist cognitive prior and delegative model of democracy. Parliamentarizing regionalism has thus hardly been a driving factor for greater legalization and constitutionalization in ASEAN and Mercosur. References Acharya, Amitav (2004): “How Ideas Spread: Whose Norms Matter? Norm Localization and Institutional Change in Asian Regionalism,” in: International Organization, Vol. 58, No. 2, pp. 239-275. Acharya, A. (2009) Whose Ideas Matter. Agency and Power in Asian Regionalism, Ithaca/London: Cornell University Press. Anderson, B.R.O’G. (1972): “The Idea of Power in Javanese Culture,” in: C. Holt (ed.) Culture and Politics in Indonesia, Ithaca/London: Cornell University Press, pp. 1-70. 28 Caetano, Gerardo (2006): Parlamento Regional y Sociedad Civil en el Proceso de integración. Una nueva oportunidad para 'otro' Mercosur?, Montevideo: Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung. Canovan, Margaret (1999): Trust the People! Populism and the Two Faces of Democracy, in: Political Studies, Vol. XLVII, pp. 2-16. Casal, Oscar (2005), El Camino Hacia el Parlamento del Mercosur, Montevideo: Friedrich-EbertStiftung. Cohen, J.M. & Uphoff, N.T. (1980): Participation’s Place in Rural Development: Seeking Clarity through Specificity, in: World Development, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 213-235. DiMaggio, P.J. & Powell, W.W. (1983): The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields, American Sociological Review, Vol. 48, No. 2, pp. 147160. Dreyzin de Klor, Adriana (2004): La necesidad de un Parlamento para el Mercosur, in: KonradAdenauer-Stiftung & Comisión Parlamentaria Conjunta del Mercosur (eds.): Hacia el Parlamento del Mercosur, Montevideo: Mastergraf, pp 23-39. Dri, Clarissa F. (2010): Limits of the Institutional Mimesis of the European Union: The Case of the Mercosur Parliament, in: Latin American Policy, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 52-74. Grugel, Jean (2006): Regionalist Governance and Transnational Collective Action in Latin America, in: Economy and Society, Vol. 35, No. 2, pp. 209-231. Hagopian, Francis (1998): Democracy and Political Representation in Latin America in the 1990s: Pause, Reorganization, or Decline?, in: Felipe Agüero & Jeffery Stark (eds.), Fault Lines of Democracy in Post-Transition Latin America, Miami: North-South Center Press, pp. 99-143. He, Kai (2008): Institutional Balancing and International Relations Theory: Economic Interdependence and Balance of Power Strategies, in: European Journal of International Relations, Vol. 14, No. 3, pp. 379-404. Jetschke, A. (2009): Institutionalizing ASEAN: Celebrating Europe through Network Governance, in: Cambridge Review of International Relations, Vol. 22, No. 3, pp. 407-426. Jetschke, Anja & Rüland, Jürgen (2009): Decoupling Rhetoric and Practice: The Cultural Limits of ASEAN Cooperation, in: The Pacific Review, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 179-203. Jones, L. (2009): Democratization and Foreign Policy in Southeast Asia: the Case of the ASEAN InterParliamentary Myanmar Caucus, Cambridge Review of International Affairs, Vol. 22, No. 3, pp. 387406. Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung & Comisión Parlamentaria Conjunta del Mercosur (eds.): Hacia el Parlamento del Mercosur, Montevideo: Mastergraf. 29 Malamud, Andrés (2003): Presidentialism and Mercosur: A Hidden Cause for a Successful Experience, in: Finn Laursen (ed.): Comparative Regional Integration. Theoretical Perspectives, Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 53-73. Malamud, Andrés (2005): Presidential Diplomacy and the Institutional Underpinnings of MERCOSUR: An Empirical Examination, in: Latin American Research Review, Vol. 40, No. 1, pp. 138-164. Malloy, James M. (ed.) (1977): Authoritarianism and Corporatism in Latin America, Pitt Latin American Series, Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. Manea, M.-G. & Rüland, J. (2010): How much an Actor and under which Logics of Action? Parliament in the Democratic Control of the Armed Forces in Indonesia and Nigeria. Osnabrück: German Foundation of Peace Research (unpublished research report). Meyer, J.W. & Rowan, B. (1977); “Institutionalized Organizations. Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony,” American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 83, No. 2, pp. 340-363. O'Donnell, Guillermo (1994): Delegative Democracy?, in: Journal of Democracy, Vol. 5, No. 1, pp. 5569. Oxhorn, Philip D. (1998): Is the Century of Corporatism Over? Neoliberalism and the Rise of Neopluralism, in: Philip D. Oxhorn & Graciela Ducatenzeiler (eds.), What Kind of Democracy? What Kind of Market?, University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press, pp. 195-217. Rudolph, L.I. & Hoeber-Rudolph, S. (1967): The Modernity of Tradition. Political Development in India, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Schimmelfennig, F. (2003): The EU, NATO and the Integration of Europe: Rules and Rhetoric, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Taggart,Paul (2002): Populism and the Pathology of Representative Politics, in: Yves Mény & Yves Surel (eds.), Democracies and the Populist Challenge, Houndmills: Palgrave, pp. 62-80. The House of Representatives of the Republic of Indonesia and AIPO Secretariat (2003): ASEAN InterParliamentary Organization, Jakarta. Vázquez, Mariana (2001): La Comisión Parlamentaria Conjunta del MERCOSUR. Reflexiones sobre su trayectoria político-institucional, Paper prepared for delivery at the 2001 meeting of the Latin American Studies Association, Washington, D. C., 6-8 September 2001. Wiarda, Howard J. (2001): The Soul of Latin America. The Cultural and Political Tradition, New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press. 30