Intergovernmental Relations and Carbon Pricing:

advertisement
Intergovernmental Relations and Carbon Pricing:
Carbon Taxes vs Cap and Trade
by
Thomas J Courchene
And
John R Allan
IIGR Queen’s
Power Point Presentation to the Conference
Carbon Pricing and Environmental Federalism
October 17-18, 2008
Four Points Hotel, Kingston, ON
iigr@queensu.ca
TC-083
Story Line





In both Canada and the US it is the sub-national governments that are
driving the carbon-pricing agenda while their respective national
governments are either politically or ideologically unwilling to assume
leadership on this file.
While this creativity on the part of the provinces is welcomed, the
reality is that for reasons relating to constitutionality, efficiency, equity
and preserving the internal environmental union (IEU), Ottawa needs to
assume the mantle of leadership.
The analysis will attempt to buttress this assertion which, in turn, will
elaborate on what federal leadership might mean.
We then assess how C&T and carbon tax regimes can accommodate
an increased federal presence while still respecting the reality that the
provinces cannot and should not be left out of the picture.
Finally, we focus on the Western Climate Initiative (WCI), i.e., the
proposed C&T system embracing several Western US states and four
Canadian provinces (BC, MB, ON, QB) and whether this has the
potential to keep the provinces in the driver’s seat.
TC-083
Role of Provinces in Climate Change



Great source: Building on our Strengths (Jillian Bollinger
and Kari Roberts: Canada West Foundation 2008).
Emission Reduction Targets (see chart at end of deck
Carbon pricing:
 C&T:
(Alberta; and 4 provinces in WCI: BC,MB,ON, QB),
 Carbon tax: (BC, QB)





Carbon sinks and carbon capture (all provinces)
Alternative Energy (Barry Rabe captures this with RPS –
Renewable Portfolio Standards); all provinces, especially
as this relates to electricity and biofuels
Other: command and control mechanisms, e.g., appliance
standards; conservation, etc
Bravo!
But our focus here will only be on carbon pricing
TC-083
Carbon Pricing and the fed-prov tug-of-war
Heading for a re-run of the NEP?






While the provinces deserve our thanks for their creative proposals for
reducing GHGs, there is a potential downside: e.g., with Alberta
imposing an origin-based emissions charge (essentially a tax on
production of carbon) and with BC among others imposing a
destination-based carbon tax (essentially a tax on consumption), and
with Ottawa likely apply to a centralized scheme, the stage is set for a
repeat of an NEP-type federal-provincial and inter-provincial
donnybrook.
The issues in play are highly explosive:
Political/Constitutional: Who can (ought to) tax/regulate carbon?
Competitiveness: Who can we level the playing field for industry,
domestically and internationally?
Fiscal/Financial: Who should receive the revenues from carbon
abatement?
Unfortunately for the provinces, they may have to reconcile themselves
to three inconvenient truths relating to these three challenges ......
TC-083
The First Inconvenient Truth:
Constitutional Jurisdiction



S.92A gives the provinces primary control over their resources, but
pricing carbon may not be viewed by the courts as equivalent to
pricing/taxing resources.
Provinces can also rely on s.92(2) “direct taxation”: and s.109 (“ All
Lands, Mines, Minerals and Royalties ...shall belong to the several
provinces”); and s.125 (essentially, the crown cannot tax the crown).
Peter Hogg (2008 C D Howe Backgrounder) notes:
 It
is clear that [the provinces] have the constitutional authority to regulate emissions
from industries within their borders. All provinces have in fact announced plans to
introduce controls on greenhouse gas emissions, and Alberta has actually enacted a
regime of control.

However, he then adds: But it is obvious that air is not confined by provincial
borders, nor is competitive economic activity, so some form of national regime is
required, which does not necessarily exclude a role for the provinces.


The conference papers by Elgie and Chalifour provide corroborating
and convincing evidence that Ottawa has the right of way in terms of
carbon pricing, both C&T and carbon taxation
But Ottawa may have to tolerate some form of joint occupancy
TC-083
The Second Inconvenient Truth:
Competitiveness





There are at least two aspects to competitiveness – levelling the
playing field in terms of free riding, domestically and internationally,
and ensuring the internal environmental union (IEU).
Since provinces cannot levy “tariffs” they may not be able to deliver
export-import neutrality or even cross-province neutrality. Beyond
competitiveness concerns, this will likely lead to “emissions leakage”
as production moves to avoid provincial carbon pricing regimes
C&T systems that limit trading and offsets to occur within-province
create further inefficiency issues, and may not be constitutional.
Perhaps the provinces, acting together (via the Council of the
Federation or with a federal imprimatur) could mount a national C&T or
latch on to an international C&T.
Whereas the previous slide agued that Canada can tax and regulate
carbon, the above analysis of the concerns relating to preventing
Balkanization of the IEU and to securing efficiency and
competitiveness (x-m neutrality and a single national price for carbon)
provides the case that Ottawa ought to tax/regulate carbon emissions
TC-083
The Third Inconvenient Truth:
Who Should Get Carbon-Abatement Revenues?




The costs of GHGs are allocated rather equally across all citizens.
The revenues arising from carbon abatement should also be shared
rather equally across all citizens (or perhaps all consumers since they
will presumably bear the carbon price). Therefore revenues should be
allocated broadly, probably on the basis of consumption
If one used production, rather than consumption, as an allocator, this
would mean that not only would the energy provinces be receiving
huge rents/royalties, but they would also receive the bulk of revenues
from carbon abatement policies. Since the monies involved are large,
this would dramatically exacerbate the already huge fiscal imbalances
across provinces. Again, a potential argument for federal leadership.
This is not meant to be a federal revenue grab. For example, under a
national carbon tax, there is no reason for Ottawa not to share carbon
tax revenues with the provinces (on, say, an equal-per-capita basis)
who can then use them as they wish (e.g., to make their portions
revenue neutral via tax cuts or incentives for low-GHG technologies)
TC-083
Interim Conclusion:

We have attempted to show
 That
Ottawa has a constitutional right to pursue carbon pricing
 This is necessary in order to level the playing competitive playing field (e.g.,
X-M neutrality and for preserving and promoting the IEU)
 This implies a single national carbon price (either via a carbon tax or C&T)
 Revenues from a carbon tax should be allocated on a consumption, not
production, basis.
 It seems appropriate for a significant portion of these revenues to be shared
with the provinces on an equal per capita basis.

Two Questions/Issues arise and will be the focus of the
remainder of the presentation
1. How do the various carbon tax and C&T regimes accord with the
above presumed principles? and relatedly
2. How can C&T and carbon tax regimes be altered to accommodate an
increased federal presence while still respecting the reality that the
provinces cannot and should not be left out of the picture?
TC-083
Carbon Taxes:
A Carbon-Added Tax/Tariff (CATT): I







From Courchene & Allan (Policy Options, March 2008)
A CATT is the carbon equivalent of our GST (i.e.,VAT) )
Would be a tax on the carbon emissions added at each
stage. As the product moves through the supply chain, the
carbon taxes accumulate. (At each stage, the carbon tax on
inputs is rebated, so that the net tax to the agent at this
stage will only be on the carbon added.)
When the product reaches the final stage, the tax is on the
cumulative value of carbon emissions.
This is identical to the way in which the GST works.
The full carbon tax is ultimately paid largely by consumers
As with the GST, the tax accumulated at the point of export
is rebated, so that the CATT is export neutral. Continued...
TC-083
Carbon Taxes:
A Carbon-Added Tax/Tariff (CATT): II






A carbon tax will be assigned to all imports, equal to the accumulated
carbon footprint.
Therefore the CATT is export-import neutral, it does not affect our
domestic or international competitiveness
Since a CATT would be an indirect tax, Ottawa has jurisdiction, and in
any event the provinces could not manage (practically or
constitutionally) the interprovincial and international entries required
of a VAT or CATT (except via delegation).
The resulting revenues can be shared with the provinces, as with the
Atlantic HST.
The CATT should be WTO compatible in the same way as the VAT.
CATT is a tax on carbon, not on imports, per se.
Achilles Heel? – measurement challenges. But much is afoot here.
The Carbon Disclosure Project has the support of 3,000 of the world’s
largest corporations, Loblaw’s is undertaking carbon labelling, Japan
has told us that there are 75 grams of carbon in a small bag of chips
TC-083
CATT : III
Assigning Carbon Footprints






Suppose Alberta produces X barrels of oil, which creates 1 tonne of
GHGs, and then it exports this to China?
Whose carbon footprint is this 1 tonne of GHGs?
Kyoto says it is Canada’s . Canada also says it is ours!
But this is surely wrong. The footprint should be China’s
In other words, the locus of consumption (demand), not production,
should be the allocator of the carbon footprint.
 Under Kyoto, if country A imports its energy/resources while country
B produces its own, country A will have a much lower GHG footprint.
 Thus, resource exporters like Australia and Canada are allowing
importing countries to appear to be better environmental citizens
than they actually are: the UK GHGs would be above its Kyoto target
under a consumption assignment. This is going to be an enormous
problem for Canada, domestically (fed-prov) and internationally. This
is especially so if the developing countries expand rapidly
CATT would assign this carbon footprint to China!
TC-083
Carbon Taxes;
Non-VAT Versions






The dominant version of carbon taxes (Mintz-Olewiler model, BC tax,
QB tax, Green Shift) are non-VAT and more like sales-type taxes on
fossil fuels or taxes targeted on big emitters of GHGs
They should be made X-M neutral, although this is more problematic in
the WTO context than it is under a CATT
The revenues can be made revenue neutral (typically including funding
for low-carbon research and renewable energy).
The huge advantage here is on the implementation front, especially if
the tax is on producers and distributors since both collection and
measurement issues are much less problematic than for a CATT.
Relatedly, it is much easier for provinces to become players here
(because of implementation ease), as BC and Quebec have revealed.
Revenue sharing with the provinces becomes rather inevitable since it
is difficult (politically and even constitutionally) to prevent the
provinces from imposing carbon taxes, as Green Shift has realized
when it offered to integrate the BC tax into it plan (with obvious but
unmentioned implications for Green Shift’s revenue neutrality).
TC-083
C&T Systems:
Pros and Cons

A pure C&T system would: i) set the cap; ii) auction this amount of
emission permits; and iii) allow permit trading which would set the
carbon price. Efficiency would increase the larger is the trading area.

This pure system is probably a null set. Rather we tend to see
intensity caps, soft price caps, and no auctioning (all are in the AB and
Ottawa models) and often Offsets that may be hard to verify. This may
be appropriate for a phasing-in period, but the real and political
“property rights” that are created may make evolution difficult.
C&T systems can be very complex to implement and manage. This is
because a veritable bureaucracy has to be put in place: bankers,
brokers, lawyers, insurers, auditors, regulators and regulations , as
well as an enforcement mechanism for violations of the C&T
In a C&T where government gets no revenues, a concern is to manage
price spikes and aid to at-risk citizens. This provides some rationale
for auctioning and for price caps, and it moves C&T toward carbon tax
regimes with “double dividend” possibilities. Indeed a C&T with a
binding price cap is, at the margin, equivalent to a carbon tax.


TC-083
Carbon Taxes vs. Cap and Trade Systems:
Some Speculative Comments





Economists in both Canada and the USA favour carbon taxes over
C&T, but elected officials tend otherwise.
This may be because the public tends to believe that the costs of
carbon taxes are borne by consumers whereas the costs of C&T are
borne by the polluters. There is little recognition that without an
increase in carbon prices, a C&T will do little. Indeed, the carbon price
under a C&T will ramify through the economy as the same way as the
carbon price under a carbon tax. This reality needs to be made public
With admittedly some degree of representation, for carbon taxes the
higher price for carbon products can be offset with equivalent tax cuts
or tax expenditures, whereas for C&T the higher prices for carbon are
offset by the higher value of the non-auctioned permits held by
corporate Canada. Auctioning permits would allow C&T to also have
the carbon tax “double dividend”
Would industry be more in favour of a carbon tax if they knew that the
permits issued under C&T would be auctioned?
Assertion: A tax on the carbon content of fuels is not a tax on GHGs
TC-083
The Provinces and Carbon Pricing:
Carbon Sinks




It seems to us that command/control policies relating to carbon sinks
fall rather naturally under provincial jurisdiction, e.g., carbon capture
and storage (CCS) for electricity plants, and reforestation policies.
(Note that Freeman Dyson believes that genetically engineered carboneating trees will appear within two decades.)
These and other carbon sinks will be obvious offsets under C&T. And
they will come into play under carbon tax systems if they are cheaper
than paying the tax. But might it also make sense to have a these
activities qualify for a carbon subsidy or for incentive programs under
any revenue-neutral schemes. This provides a further rationale for
sharing any carbon pricing revenues with the provinces.
Harvesting forests decreases carbon sinks. Should forestry activities
(harvesting/ reforestation) be integrated more fully into carbon pricing
schemes (with appropriate intergenerational discounting).
The relevance of this is two fold: i) that carbon pricing schemes need
to be cast more widely, and ii) they need to fully engage the provinces
since many key aspects of climate change need provincial approval
TC-083
C&T with Provincial Allowances/Targets:
Carbon Assignments and Auctioning






Although the ETS has a single international price, it sets its overall
target as the sum of national targets. It will abandon this over time and
move to ETS targets. The WCI also has state and provincial targets.
Should our carbon pricing targets also come initially from provincial
allocations? If so, two challenges may arise :
1. Continued growth in developing nations can drive up energy and
resource prices, so resource firms will be able to afford to drive up
carbon prices and crowd out production elsewhere. Part of the
problem here is that the carbon footprint associated with these exports
will be assigned to our provinces rather than to the importers.
2. Under full information, etc, carbon auctioning will not affect the
allocative outcome of a C&T. However, it will have income distribution
effects, again with crowding-out implications. This could argue for a
gradual introduction of auctioning to soften the impact of point 1.
Moreover, Kyoto assignments ignore population growth (see chart 2)
Recommendation: Canada should publish results for all 3 approaches:
absolute, per capita and consumption-based targets.
TC-083
The WCI Cap and Trade System;
The Provinces End-Run Ottawa?




In September 2008, seven states and four provinces agreed to an
international C&T.
This is as close to a model C&T as currently exists.
There will be state/province targets, permit auctioning, rigorous (and
international) offsets, a single international price across participating
states and provinces, and platform that may be extended to embrace
an integrated Canada-US C&T regime.
This is truly remarkable in its own right, and in the present context:
Whereas constitutional, efficiency, equity and fiscal considerations
may assign the trump cards to Ottawa in terms of designing and
operating national carbon pricing schemes, the exceptional reality
where 4 provinces with over 75% of our population have embarked on
the creative cross-border C&T means that federal inaction on the
climate change file may well have served to abdicate leadership and
moral authority to the provinces.
Welcome to Environmental Federalism!
TC-083
Thank You For Your Attention
Comments Welcomed
tom.courchene@queensu.ca
John.Allan@queensu.ca
TC-083
Download