The Cost of Conditional Risk Financing CAS Ratemaking Seminar March 11-12, 2004 Frank Schnapp National Crop Insurance Services, Inc. 1 Standard Approaches for Insurance Risk Pricing • Economic methods – Adopts Risk-taker’s perspective – Expected Utility Theory • Key concept: Preferences • Shape of utility function is unknown • Ignores the insurer’s ability to reduce risk through diversification • Financial methods – Takes Investor’s perspective – Net Present Value model • • • • Key concept: Cost of capital Capital is invested at the time an insurance policy is issued Focus is on timing of cash flows Ignores the uncertainty of the cash flows 2 Proposed Risk Pricing Model Basic Concepts • Adopts the Risk taker’s perspective • No capital is needed to issue an additional policy • Considers both the uncertainty and timing of cash flows • Based on real costs – Expected Utility Theory is preference based – Cost of capital represents a competitive return, not an actual cost • Risk diversification (pooling) – Reduces insurer’s risk – May (or may not) affect the price paid by policyholder • Insurer operates under a Capital Preservation Objective 3 Risk Taker’s Perspective • Return to the insurer Return to the investor • Company actions to provide an adequate return to investor: – Increase or decrease expenses • Commissions, salaries, bonuses – Portfolio selection • Pursue markets where Insurer has a competitive advantage • Higher risk markets producer higher returns – Increase or decrease amount of insurance or investment risk 4 Two Varieties of Pricing Model • Based on Actual costs Retroactive pricing • Based on Expected costs Prospective pricing 5 No Capital is needed to issue an additional policy • Capital is used when a claim is paid – And only if the Damages exceed the Premium • If Damages < Premium Insurer earns a profit • If Damages > Premium Insurer contributes capital – Capital contribution = max(Damages – Premium, 0) – Takes into account the uncertainty of the outcomes • Analysis is similar if expenses are included 6 Insurance as a Risk Financing Mechanism • Self-insurance – Self-insurer borrows funds to pay any deficit on policy – Repays the loan over time • Purchase of an insurance policy – Insurer provides funds as needed to pay any deficit on policy • Insurer functions as the “Bank” • Risk financing is treated as a loan, not as an investment – Insurer’s Capital Preservation Objective • Insurer needs to recover the borrowed funds – Loan can be repaid by: • Policyholder, or • All policyholders in the market segment • Policyholders in all market segments 7 Retroactive Pricing (Payback) Method 1st Example: Premium = Expected Damages Outcome Premium Damages Probability Return Deficit A 1000 0 .250 1000 0 B 1000 500 .500 500 0 C 1000 3000 .250 -2000 2000 Expected 1000 1000 1.000 0 500 • Return = Profit • Deficit = Amount of Capital consumed • Outcomes A & B – Insurer earns a profit – Premium in year 2 is $1000 = Expected damages • Outcome C – Insurer makes a capital contribution (loan) of $2000 – Loan must be repaid by next expected occurrence in 4 years = 1/.250 – Annual payment on loan = $500 – Premium in Years 2-5 = Expected Damages + Annual Payment on Loan = $1500 · Premium may change again if outcome C occurs in years 2, 3, or 4 · Long term average premium > $1000 8 Retroactive Pricing (Payback) Method 2nd Example: Premium = $1400 Outcome Premium Damages Probability Return Deficit A 1400 0 .250 1400 0 B 1400 500 .500 900 0 C 1400 3000 .250 -1600 1600 Expected 1400 1000 1.000 400 400 • Assume outcome C occurs every 4th year – Insurer makes $1600 capital contribution every 4th year – Policyholder contributes $400 expected profit every year – Total of $1600 over four years – Policyholder pays for the insurer’s capital contributions (over the long term) • Result represents the “optimal” retroactive premium – Premium will vary depending on the actual outcome 9 The “Optimal” Retroactive Price • Policyholder pays for potential use of the insurer’s capital – Pays the long term average cost • Premium = Expected Damages + Average cost of loan P = E(X) + xi>P (xi – P)sipi • Cost based surcharge si on loan of xi – P – – – – Term of loan is 1/pi si represents the interest charged on the loan si is reduced for the time value of money si >= 1 • Equivalent to the Prospective price for the exposure – Insurer charges for its expected, not actual, capital contribution – No recognition of the effect of Insurer’s risk diversification – Can be interpreted as the Self-insurance price 10 Retroactive vs. Prospective Pricing • Prospective method – Useful for small exposures – Used if Insurer is not permitted to recoup losses from policyholder – Cost of loan may be spread across all exposures in market segment • Retroactive pricing – For exposures large enough to be self-rated – Reinsurance and large accounts 11 Retroactive Pricing and the Insurance Market Pricing Cycle • Insurers raise prices to recoup underwriting losses • High prices would continue even if coverage is amended – Terrorism, toxic mold coverage • Enables insurers to “recoup” capital losses in subsequent years • Enhances long term solvency of the industry – Supports Capital Preservation Objective 12 Insurance Market Pricing Cycle Overview & Outlook for the Property/Casualty Insurance Industry. Dr. Robert P. Hartwig. July, 2003. Insurance Information Institute. http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/industryoutlook/ 13 Hard Markets Follow Years of Deteriorating Results Overview & Outlook for the Property/Casualty Insurance Industry. Dr. Robert P. Hartwig. July, 2003. Insurance Information Institute. http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/industryoutlook/ 14 The Effect of Risk Diversification (Pooling) on Price • Evaluate Risk from a portfolio perspective • Effect of Risk diversification within a market segment – Reduces an insurer’s average risk per exposure: • V(Ž) = V(Z) / n – Permits the insurer to reduce its risk margin on each exposure – Competition may prevent Insurer from pricing an exposure for its own risk • Price each market segment for its own risk instead • Effect of Risk diversification across market segments – No reduction in the insurer’s price (mostly) – Reduces the insurer’s risk instead 15 Example of Risk Diversification Across Market Segments (Without Price Reduction) • Assume Insurer prices each market segment for its own risk – Distribution A: Single market segment • Insurer frequently uses its own capital – Distribution B: Portfolio consisting of 5 market segments • Insurer occasionally uses its own capital – Distribution C: Portfolio consisting of 12 market segments • Insurer rarely, if ever, uses its own capital • A loss in one market segment is paid by the policyholders in other market segments • Affects si, the cost of borrowed funds • Helps satisfy the Insurer’s Capital Preservation Objective 16 Illustration of Risk Diversification without Price Reduction Figure 3 Distribution of the Insurer's Returns Probability C B A Insurer's Actual Return (Premium - Damages) as Percent of Premium 17 Prospective Pricing Model with Risk Diversification Across Market Segments • Risk Pricing Model – – – – Assumes insurer rarely, if ever, uses its own capital Allows insurer to use a uniform surcharge for si of a >= 1 For a very well-diversified insurer, a = 1 Select a to satisfy Capital Preservation Objective P – E(X) = a x>P (x – P) dF(x) • Price achieves a balance between Risk and Return – For outcome xi, define Return as P – xi – Define Risk as (xi – P)si or (xi – P)a for xi > P, else 0 – The premium P is the unique solution to: Expected Risk = Expected Return 18 Comparison to Expected Utility Theory • Risk Pricing Model is consistent with Utility pricing – Model is applied to market segments, not to individual exposures – Shape of Utility function: • Two rays with positive slope meeting at 0 • Concave downward – “Utility” is independent of wealth – Risk aversion parameter is a function of insurer’s diversification • Consistent with pricing formulas: – – – – – P(c) = c P(X + c) = P(X) + c P(aX) = aP(X) for a >= 0 P(X + Y) <= P(X) + P(Y) For X ~ N(m,s2), P(X) = m + ls (diversification property) (with l a constant) • Income taxes have little or no effect on price 19 The Mutually Acceptable Price • Insurer’s price declines as number of exposures increases – Enables Insurer to compete with self-insurance – Even if the Insurer is more “risk averse” than the Self-insurer – No mutually acceptable price exists if insurer’s expenses are too high Figure 4 Comparison of Certainty Equivalent Prices Price Self-insurance price Insurer's price Number of Exposures Insured 20 Competitive Market Pricing • Construct Supply and Demand curves for insurance • Limits on the Insurer’s ability to insure additional policies: – Quality of the Insurer’s book declines during rapid expansion – Staffing is insufficient to handle the work load – But: the amount of Capital held by Insurer is not a limitation • Intersection of Supply & Demand determines the market price – Low cost Insurers earn more than a “normal” profit – High cost Insurers earn less than a “normal” profit • Will continue to write insurance as long as variable costs are met • Decision to participate in market is unrelated to Cost of Capital 21 Is the Capital Preservation Objective Realistic? • U.S. P&C insurance industry is consistently profitable – Only one exception • 2001 (9/11 terrorist attack) – Sharp increase in insurance prices immediately afterward • Helped industry to recoup losses from event • Stability: Insolvency rate remarkably low – Ten year average = 0.72% – Most insolvencies are small, low rated companies • Industry structure – Unconcentrated, with a large number of competitors – Survival & profitability much better than auto, steel, & airlines 22 P&C Industry Profitability World Trade Center (9/11) Andrew Northridge $28 Billion full year Based on “Overview & Outlook for the Property/Casualty Insurance Industry.” Dr. Robert P. Hartwig. July, 2003. 23 Insurance Information Institute. http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/industryoutlook/ P&C Industry Insolvency Rates Overview & Outlook for the Property/Casualty Insurance Industry. Dr. Robert P. Hartwig. July, 2003. Insurance Information Institute. http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/industryoutlook/ 24 Summary • Retroactive Pricing – Reinsurance, large accounts, Insurance Market Pricing Cycle • Prospective Pricing – Without risk diversification • Each exposure is priced for its own risk (e.g., self-insurance) – With risk diversification • Insurer determines its price for each market segment, not each exposure • Diversification across market segments minimizes use of insurer’s capital • Price is determined from Risk-taker perspective – Cost of capital is not relevant to the model – Model accounts for: • Risk/Return tradeoff, Expenses, Taxes, Time value of money • Competition, Self-insurance, Heterogeneity of exposures • Investment Income on insurance cash flows • Unified treatment of insurance and investment pricing 25 Additional Topics 26 Pricing for Systematic Risk (Once the Insurer determines the premium it needs for a market segment, how does it determine its price for each policy?) • Let X1, … Xn be exposures in market segment W = Xi – Assume prices are additive: P(Xi+Xk;W) = P(Xi;W) + P(Xk;W) – Assume the price PW for the market segment W is known • Let Price be based on Xi’s contribution to systematic risk W – Xi can be uniquely decomposed as b W + Ui • • • • With b = cov(Xi,W) / V(W) Systematic risk component is b W Diversifiable risk component is Ui (since Ui = 0) Ui is uncorrelated with W • Systematic Risk Pricing Model: P(Xi;W) = E(Xi) + b (PW - E(W)) 27 Observations on Systematic Risk Pricing Model • Market segment premium PW can be selected arbitrarily – It need not be determined using the Risk Pricing Model – Restriction: E(W) <= PW <= P(Xi) • Application to Insurance pricing – Accounts for systematic risk – Price is unrelated to security market returns – Formula can be converted to a rate of return on price • Formula does not involve capital – Finding: Rate of return formula is identical to the CAPM formula 28 Application to Security Market Pricing • Model can be applied to determine security prices – Not rates of return – Price is tied to the underlying earnings of the business • Consistent with Dividend Discount Model • But, it recognizes the uncertainty of the dividends • Relationship to Rate of Return – Model determines rate of return on price, not on capital – Finding: The CAPM does not apply to security market pricing • Reason: A security is tied to the earnings of a business • But, a business need not have a fixed risk exposure over time • A company can enter or leave markets, change its pricing, etc. – CAPM is consistent with the model under narrow restrictions 29 Comparison of the Role of Capital • Risk Pricing Model – Capital expenditure is no different from any other cash flow • Purchase of productive goods: Capital investment = Up-front Expense (fixed) • Purchase of a security: Capital expenditure = Price (may be negotiable) – Analysis of an investment depends on the responsibility for losses • A business pays for operating losses out of its capital • A security holder has no obligation to use its capital to pay losses • Insurance: Other policyholders provide the capital needed to settle claims • Systematic Risk Pricing Model and the Revised CAPM – Capital has no bearing on price – Rate of return is defined in relation to price, not capital • Actuarial Pricing Models (per Standards of Practice) – Cost of Capital is fundamental 30 Pricing of Uncertain Future Damages • Assume stable risk aversion parameters over time: a1 = a0 – Justification: a = 1 for a well-diversified insurer • Given X0 and X1 with identical damage distributions – Damages are paid at times 0 and 1, respectively – Since a is constant, P1(X1) = P0(X0) • What is the price at time 0 for future damages X1? – – – – Let v be the discount factor corresponding to the risk-free rate Discount the future price for X1 to time 0 = vP1(X1) Or, discount each outcome to time 0 = P0(vX0) Both methods give the same price: • P0(vX0) = vP1(X1) 31 The Time Value of Money • Risk-free rate – Assume Lender’s objective is to maintain purchasing power • Purchasing power is affected by future inflation • Future inflation is uncertain • Define the risk-free rate as the price needed to offset the risk of future inflation • Apply risk vs. return analysis to future purchasing power – Example: model inflation as a Markov chain • Shape of yield curve: – Short term rate is similar to expected inflation rate – Increases as payment horizon increases – Long term rate stabilizes after several periods 32 End of Presentation 33