Displacement and Densification: Tracing Spatial Impacts of Migration Inflows to London Ian Gordon Geography Department, LSE London and Spatial Economics Research Centres London School of Economics LSE London/RUPS MSc seminar series February 17th 2014 Introduction • Suzi Hall (last week) presented a street level study of migrant diversity in one London ocality • This talk by contrast uses quantitative evidence for a few broad groups of migrants/natives in areas across the GSE to find spatial impact of flows into London • Reflects view that central problem for understanding / planning metro regions lies in the interlocking chains (often of displacements) linking local behaviour to impacts on the range of localities / populations • It is also about densification (as complement to displacement) and how far London’s recent growth has depended on dense packing-in of poor migrants Growing Research Interest in Displacement Effects of Migration • Talk of displacement often suggests a use of force: – but here just implies some causal link between growth/ entry of one group and shrinkage/ exit of another (inc. earlier entrants) • A very old story, in terms of ‘invasion/succession’, but rediscovered in late 1990s for big new waves of migration: – Larger gains from overseas correlated with larger domestic losses • Cross-sectional spatial evidence for US metro areas (W.Frey) • Time series evidence for London (and southern regions in Hatton/Tani) • Maybe reflecting competition for limited opportunities – In terms of housing and/or jobs or maybe some qualitative impact, disliked by earlier settlers - Generating ‘flight’ by whites – or some other old guard - Literature tends to focus either on labour market or white flight – but my hypothesis is that competition for limited housing is key. London’s ‘Mirror Image’ Migration Trends 150 Net International Migration 100 Net Migration with Rest of UK 50 0 -50 -100 -150 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Outline 3 substantive sections: A. What we might reasonably expect B. What time series evidence suggests – in the London/Greater South East case C. What spatial patterns of change across the GSE suggest – for the decade between the last two Censuses. A. What We (Should) Expect • Approach is shaped by ideas from 3 sources – Classic urban land-use theory / social ecology – Lessons from empirical research on population movement in London’s extended region – LSE London research on economic aspects of post 1980s international migration to London From Classic (Old) Urban Theory • With free property markets, patterns/density of land-use (and rents) shaped by competition between users: – Who give different priorities to accessibility, living/operating space + (maybe) proximity to desired/similar kinds of neighbour – In cities with a dominant centre this produces a basic ring pattern of resident differences (and densities) + some specialised clusters • Cities expand spatially by: attracting new people; &/or effects of residents’ income growth – Increased attraction also increases densities • But higher average incomes lower them – Unless many richer people value access because of ‘urbane’ leisure tastes • In either case, expanding the width of rings ⇨ some displacement – painlessly in the case of owner-occupiers at least • Green Belts interrupt this and raise densities – until leapfrogging starts – Except for new arrivals & those with big changes in income/family status, re-locations are likely to be short distance • But contribute to large scale growth/re-shaping of metropolitan regions From Household Movement Studies • People tend to move for multiple reasons (inc. e.g. ‘white flight’) – But a few basic ones shape overall pattern of change: new job/retirement; larger dwelling; better dwelling/area • London’s population ‘loss’ (1939-87) driven by de-densification – Inner area residents seeking separate/larger houses – Others seeking more spacious environment – Within the metro region (GL + OMA) at least hardly anyone moving for/in expectation of a job change (though happened eventually) • Some groups are consistently more likely to choose core area – Notably single people, graduates and 1st/2nd generation migrants • with more urban leisure tastes – This bias has scarcely changed since 1970s – But size of each group has grown enormously – With predictable implications for trends in density/concentration – espacially near the core. Major Planning Constraints in/around the GSE : Green Belts and AONB/National Parks From LSEL Migrant Impact Work • A key distinction between migrants : – Expecting generally better prospects for someone like them • Typically from significantly poorer countries (e.g. LDC/EU_A10) • Likely to stay indefinitely – Pursuing specific (current) opportunity – work/training, private • Mostly from other ‘rich’ countries (W. Europe, N. America, ANZA, Japan) • Very likely to move on/back subsequently • Only former face serious barriers to access good jobs • Despite comparable levels of education • Notably in first 3 years or so – but long term convergence – Housing implications include more crowding • But evidence that gap in headship rates closed after 20 years • So recency of arrival is a second key variable B. What Trends at Regional Level Suggest • Looking at evolution /fluctuations in net intraUK migration for GL and RGSE – as the scale with long data series • In relation to factors conditioning: – demand for additional space (UK-wide) • Changes in rate of private housing completions – Relative attractiveness of GL /RGSE/RUK • Differences in unemployment and house prices + Net international migration – as poss. ‘displacer’ ? Findings • The size of London’s outflow varies strongly with national housing demand (as does RGSE’s net inflow) consistent with income-elastic space demands being the driver – though about half the positive effects appear beyond the GSE; • The housing/labour market relativities that matter for London migration are those between the GSE and the UK – not within the GSE – consistent with singular GSE housing/labour markets; • International migrational gains into London appear to be 40% displaced into other areas – though primarily beyond the GSE – i.e. the chain of displacements stretches right through the GSE, ending up outside (perhaps in Peter Hall’s larger version) – NB no evidence of displacement from (less constrained) RGSE • But how is the other 60% accommodated ? By stimulating growth of extra housing space in London ? Or more crowding? C. What Spatial Patterns of Inter-Censal Change Suggest • Aim is to answer those questions by looking at 2001-11 Census evidence on: – spatial variations in : • housing market areas where more rooms have been added to occupied housing stock ; and • neighbourhoods where most densification of room use has taken place – and how these connect with our four groups of migrant: • rich/poor country x old/new Broad Tendencies in Location/relocation • Though particular national concentrations (old & new) are still clear – at broader richC/poorC level see: – Rich C: new/recent arrivals tend partic to be in: areas of previous (2001) concentration and/or good job accessibility • Previous waves now simply drifting away from areas of concentration – though not far (e.g. Outer London) – Poor C: recent arrivals tend partic to be in: areas of previous concentration and/or low rents • Previous waves areas shifting toward with more UK-born pop – over wider territory – including right beyond the GSE • UK born Pop. (including 2nd gen ‘migrants’) static overall : rising/falling in about equal no. of localities – except in Outer London where falling in 2/3 of LSOA Accommodating Growth 1 • Comparisons of growth rates for major ‘rings’ show: – Strong population growth in each but much faster inside London, especially IL (+15%) – Substantial room growth too, especially in IL & OGSE (9-10%) – But London alone had notable increase in persons per room (5%) • Accounting for all of its higher population growth relative to the RGSE – London’s higher population growth was entirely among foreign born (UK born nos. fell especially in OL) – Biggest contributory factor was new arrivals from poor countries • though numbers from earlier cohorts fell, reflecting dispersal as well as ‘exits’ • How may these be linked causally ? Accommodating Growth 2 • The possible impact of new migrant inflows (from outside housing system) on dwelling growth rates was examined in regressions with an array of contextual factors (mostly relating to land supply potential) • At LHMA level the latter clearly dominated and there was no sign of a positive effect from poor or rich country arrivals – but, with a limited number of units (73) estimates of these coefficients were very imprecise • At LSOA level, significant effects were found, suggesting a 10% population growth via rich country migrants might induce a 2% increase in the room stock – with a smaller impact (of 0.7%) for those from poor countries. Accommodating Growth 3 • Finally, local (LSOA) level room density changes were analysed within an ‘accounting’ type model in relation to numeric changes in all 5 of our population sub-groups – with job accessibility and the 2001 ppr rate as controls • In this case, the scale of new arrivals from poor countries emerged as the strongest influence - with 55 of each 100 apparently being accommodated through denser occupation of existing rooms • This compared with just 10 in the case of the UK born, and around 30 for those who had been in the country over 10 years • For new arrivals from rich countries the average effect seemed insignificant – but this reflected great disparities between arrivals to IL whose impact was as low as for the UK born, whereas in the RGSE it was much stronger (45 per 100) • BUT: densification also being driven by demand for accessibility Conclusions – Accommodating migrants involves some combination of : (a) induced additions to local room stock; (b) denser occupation of those rooms; and (c) displacement elsewhere: – For migrants to London (with its constrained space): • (c) seems to account for 40%; • for poor country migrants (a) accounts for ,10%, (b) for 55% leaving perhaps 35% for displacement • For rich country migrants: (a) accounts for 20% and (b) about 12% - leaving perhaps 68% for displacement [to be tested ] • Densification effects for poor country migrants clearly reduce over time – implying the likelihood of substantially more displacement in the long run (as well as dispersal) – Displacement effects of London immigration clearly spread well beyond the GSE (further than income growth effects?) – Within London poor country migration is major factor in densification – but so is growing demand for accessibility.