2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Should Companies Increase Size or Improve their CSR Profile in order to Improve their Performance? Evidence from UK listed Firms Iordanis Kalaitzoglouο« Coventry University, Business School, Priory Street, Coventry CV1 5FB e-mail: iordanis.kalaitzoglou@coventry.ac.uk, Tel: (+)44 (24) 7688 8418 Lanre Fagbe Coventry University, Business School, Priory Street, Coventry CV1 5FB e-mail: fagbel@coventry.ac.uk Jacek Niklewski Coventry University, Business School, Priory Street, Coventry CV1 5FB e-mail: J.Niklewski@coventry.ac.uk, Tel: (+)44 (24) 7688 7187 June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 1 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Should Companies Increase Size or Improve their CSR Profile in order to Improve their Performance? Evidence from UK listed Firms ABSTRACT This study proposes an empirical model to investigate the inter-relations among Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR), Corporate Financial Performance (CFP) and size, while accounting for liquidity and exposure to financial default risk. The analytical focus lies on potential endogeneity issues, which are investigated employing a system of equations, estimated using the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) technique. A non-industryspecific sample is employed, consisting of 233 companies included in FTSE 250, from 2003 to 2010. In addition, a broad measure of CSR is employed to allow for generalization. The main findings strongly indicate that UK market is sensitive to firms’ social profiles, which are found to be endogenous related to both size and performance. CSR is asymmetrically related to performance, where excessive or no investment in CSR are the most rewarding financially. Larger and more profitable companies are more likely to invest in CSR, which in turns contributes to further to both, probably due to increased visibility. Finally, higher borrowing improves the financial profile, the size and the profitability of the companies in the pre-crisis period, while it has a rather decreasing impact in the post-crisis period. Key words: Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR), Corporate Financial Performance (CFP), Generalized Method of Moments (GMM), Endogeneity, Simultaneous Equations. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 2 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 1. INTRODUCTION After the introduction of Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) scheme in 2000 and its disclosure requirement, the impact of corporate profile on the value of listed companies is undeniable.i A positively regarded company, at least compared to its competitors, significantly increases its intangible assets. Cohen et al. (2011) emphasizes the importance of non-financial information on the long term. However, this definitely comes at a cost, either in the form of excessive liabilities or as a decrease in other assets. In addition, the funds required to create and sustain a socially responsible corporate profile are deprived from other investments that could create economic value. Therefore, the question that arises naturally in the literature (Barney (1991) & Barney et al. (2001) & Bragdon and Marlin (1972) & Moskowitz (1972) & Vance (1975)) is whether the value of these intangible assets is marginally higher than the marginal cost of their acquisition in the form of opportunity costs in order to enhance performance and create value. Naturally, the interest has focused on the sign and the direction of the relationship between CSR and performance.ii Several studies have empirically tested this relationship, providing conflicting results, both in terms of the sign and direction of causality, as well as in terms of market stylized facts. A significant branch of literature (Anderson and Frankle (1980) & Belkaoui (1976) & Bowman (1978) & Fry and Hock (1976) & Preston (1978)) reports that CSR has a positive impact on performance. According to Solomon and Hanson (1985), the cost of CSR is outweighed by the benefit from employee morale and productivity. On the contrary, several studies (Aupperle et al. (1985) & Freedman and Jaggi (1982) & Ingram and Frazier (1980)) argue that the marginal costs associated with CSR are higher than the benefits and therefore reduce firm’s performance. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 3 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Brammer and Millington (2008) maintain that these contradictions arise because of a non linear relationship. They purport that the positive association between CSR and performance follows diminishing and decreasing returns. Consequently, if the scope of social responsibility participation strays beyond the management in addressing the social concerns (e.g., with little or no impact with relation to stakeholders of the firm), the net effect is declining financial performance. They also argue that the correlation between CSR and performance is highest at the extremes, showing that financial performance is high at both very high and very low CSR levels. This is consistent with Porter (1980) who supports that low cost or differentiated strategies outperform mediocre approaches, as well as with Bhattacharya and Sen (2004) who show that price sensitive customers are not ready to pay the higher prices of more socially active responsible firms. However, these studies, although they partially explain variations in CSRperformance relationship, they do not examine potential endogeneity issues. Bragdon and Marlin (1972) Bowman and Haire (1975) and Heinz (1976) report that companies with higher performance invest more in CSR. More precisely, Bowman and Haire (1975) maintain that the U-shaped relationship holds on the opposite direction as well. However, their results are industry specific and they focus only on particular aspects of CSR, such as pollution or environmental index.iii According to Dean (1998) and Waddock and Graves (1997) there are two main approaches in describing the direction of causality between CSR and CFP. iv The slack resource hypothesis states that a company ought to maintain and sustain its financial performance first, before thinking of engaging into social responsibilities. The good management hypothesis supports that a company that is perceived to have good reputation and better association with its non financial stakeholders will find it easier to perform well. This is confirmed by Jackson and Apostolakou (2010) who show that CSR is now used as a strategic June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 4 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 tool to boost performance in Western Europe. This argument focuses on a marketing perspective, considering CSR as an intangible asset that impacts and enhances performance (Hillman and Keim (2001) & Orlitzky et al., (2003)). Surroca et al. (2010) provide evidence of endogeneity between CSR and performance, but it is rather direct through intangible assets of innovation, human capital, reputation and culture. This is a key idea further examined in this paper. In contrast, Makni et al. (2009) provide evidence of no significant association. Waddock and Graves (1997) maintain that financial performance and CSR are synergetic and that their interrelation is rather an empirical issue. Another branch of literature focuses on the relation between size and CSR. Chih et al., (2010) purports that firms with larger size tend to invest more in CSR, especially where there is an intrinsic value that increases their competitive advantage. Dierkes and Coppock (1978), Fombrun and Shanley (1990), Trotman and Bradley (1981) provide evidence of positive relationship between size and CSR, corporate reputation index. Watts and Zimmerman (1986) postulate that large firms are likely to be more affected by CSR performance impacts due to increased visibility. Adams et al. (1998), Clarke and Gibson-Sweet (1999), Gray et al. (1995) and Ness and Mirza (1991) argue that size related costs reduce by CSR disclosure, or that CSR disclosure is the outcome of increased social pressure (Aguilera et al. 2007). In addition, Orlitzky (2001) investigates whether companies that embrace CSR increase in size, suggesting an endogenous relationship between size, performance and CSR. In contrast, Stanwick and Stanwick (1998) maintain that size is exogenous to both CSR and performance. Furthermore, Artiach et al. (2010) investigate whether leverage is related to CSR and report that firms will prioritize financial stakeholder claims over social stakeholders. Therefore, highly leveraged firms should be less likely to improve their CSR profiles, even though it would further decrease their tax liability. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 5 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Most of the studies have been industry specific and that has also contributed to the inconsistencies in the relationship between corporate social responsibility and performance (Rowley and Berman (2000)). Empirical studies (e.g., Gray et al. (1995), (2001) & Hackston and Milne (1996)) have shown that CSR disclosure activism varies across companies, industries, and time. CSR is determined by the industry and firm characteristics (Reverte (2009)), while firms operating in the same industry develop common practices. In addition, Higgins and Currie (2004) argue that corporate social responsibility can be driven by ethical and legal matters that cannot be accurately measured.v Chih et al. (2010) and Margolis and Walsh (2003) suggest a parsimonious and an extended model, respectively. They provide contradicting results, confirming Ullmann (1985), who suggests that the relationship between CSR and performance of the firm is so complex and there is currently no true model that exhibits this relationship. Consequently, this study does not aim at an exhaustive investigation of the concept of CSR and its impact on financial performance. The analytical focus lies on the empirical investigation of the inter-relations between CSR, financial performance and size, on a non-industry-specific setting, defining CSR multi-dimensionally.vi In more detail, an empirical model of simultaneous equations is proposed, to empirically examine a non-asymmetric impact of CSR on performance. An endogenous relationship between CSR and performance is also investigated, taking into account variant effects due to size of the company. The sample selected, consists of 233 companies, included in FTSE 250 from 2003 till 2010. This constitutes a non-industry-specific setting that allows for generalization. Finally, a wider measure of CSR is employed in order to avoid sector-bias. The findings strongly indicate that UK market is sensitive to companies’ social profiles, to cost efficiency, and that CSR activities, performance and size are endogenously related. Companies June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 6 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 that are highly ranked in CSR index and companies that do not embrace CSR policies, consistently perform better than companies that are in between. This is further enhanced when companies are already performing well, probably because their liquidity allows them to invest more in CSR activities. In addition, large companies are found to invest more in CSR and they further increase their size because of a positive CSR impact. Large companies enjoy higher visibility and they are found to be more influenced by their social profiles. Finally, higher exposure to default risk seems to have a negative impact on CSR investments and consequently on profitability. Excessive borrowing, prioritize financial stakeholders’ needs over social stakeholders’ interests, and this seems to be a crucial factor in the UK, which is found to be socially sensitive market. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The following section presents the data collection process and the methodology employed. Empirical findings are discussed in Section 3, while Section 4 concludes. 2. METHODOLOGY 2.1. Data The aim of this study is to investigate the relationship between CSR, performance, size and leverage in UK companies. According to the literature, these inter-relations are more profound in large companies, due to increased visibility. Therefore, the sample employed, consist of all companies included in the FTSE 250 in the years from 2003 to 2010, subjected to availability of data and continuity of operation. The data set consist of 1762 observations. The variables under investigation are Return on Equity, Total Assets, liquidity, Debt to equity ratio and the CSR ranking on annual basis.vii June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 7 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 2.2. Model Foundations of the model Literature poses five key issues that are relevant to this study. First, the impact of CSR on CFP is extensively investigated, and empirical evidence suggests that the importance depends on country specific factors (see inter alia, Anderson and Frankle (1980) & Belkaoui (1976) & Bowman (1978) & Fry and Hock (1976) & Preston (1978)). Second, CSR might asymmetrically affect CFP (Bowman and Haire (1975)). Profitability is higher in cost efficient companies that do not invest in CSR activity, or in companies that score high in CSR indexes. In contrast, a mediocre approach seems is rather ineffective. Third, there is no clear indication on the direction of the relation, which again is found to be sample depended (Surroca et al. (2010)). Fourth, the impact of size on CSR and the direction of their relationship is not extensively incorporated and has not yet been studied simultaneously (Chih et al. (2010)). Finally, the relationship between financial exposure (i.e., excessive lending) should further be investigated (Artiach et al. (2010)). The model below, proposes an easy and flexible way to investigate the above issues. It provides the framework for an empirical investigation of the sign, the direction and the inter-relation of key variables related to CSR. It can also be further extended by introducing other factors that affect each individual relationship, or factors that might be endogenously related. In addition, it can be applied in different settings, either more specific (e.g., industry, sector, country), or more general (e.g., comparison between sectors, countries). The Model The econometric model proposed, can be summarized in the following three equations: June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 8 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 3 π ππΈππ‘ = πΌ0 + πΌ1 ππΌππΈππ‘ + ∑(πΌ2,π ∗ πΌπ,π,π‘ ) ∗ πΆππ ππ‘ + πΌ3 πΏπΈπππ‘ + πΌ4 πΏππππ‘ + π1π‘ (1) π=1 πΆππ ππ‘ = π½0 + π½1 π ππΈππ‘ + π½2 ππΌππΈππ‘ + π½3 πΏπΈπππ‘ + π½4 πΏππππ‘ + π2π‘ (2) ππΌππΈππ‘ = π0 + π1 π ππΈππ‘ + π2 πΆππ ππ‘ + π3 πΏπΈπππ‘ + π4 πΏππππ‘ + π3π‘ (3) where, α’s, β’s and μ’s are parameters to be estimated, π = 1,2, … , π refers to companies and t refers to time. πΆππ ππ‘ is the corporate social responsibility and is calculated as [ 100−π+1 100 ], where π is the rank number for the i-th firm at time t.viii π ππΈππ‘ is the return on equity, computed as net income over total equity, ππΌππΈππ‘ is the natural logarithm of total assets, πΏππππ‘ is liquidity, measured as total assets turnover and πΏπΈπππ‘ is leverage, measured by the Debt to Equity ratio, for firm i and at time t. ππ,π‘ π = 1,2,3 is the error term. Then I is a dummy variable that differentiates the level of CSR engagement and π = 1,2,3 πΌ1,π,π‘ = { πΌ2,π,π‘ = { 1 0 π€βππ πΆππ π,π‘ = 0 πππ ππ€βπππ (4) 1 π€βππ 0 < πΆππ π,π‘ ≤ 50% 0 πππ ππ€βπππ (5) 1 π€βππ πΆππ π,π‘ > 50% 0 πππ ππ€βπππ (6) πΌ3,π,π‘ = { This model examines the following issues. First, Eq. (1) investigates a potential asymmetric impact of CSR on performance. Coefficient πΌ2,1 captures the impact of non CSR policies on performance. A positive estimated would indicate that companies that do not engage on CSR policies perform better because of decreased costs. Coefficient πΌ2,2 captures the impact of CSR on CFP when companies embrace CSR practices, but it is not central to their financial management. A negative coefficient would indicate negative relation to CFP. Coefficient πΌ2,3 June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 9 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 captures the impact of CSR on CFP when the social profile is a main strategic objective for the company. In Eq. (1) and Eq.(2) Coefficients πΌ2,π and π½1 investigate whether there is any endogenous relationship between CSR and CFP. Coefficients π½2 and π½3 capture the impact of Size and Leverage on CSR. Eq. (3) examines potential endogeneity among CSR, CFP and Size, captured in coefficients π1 and π2 . The method chosen for estimation is the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM). In this method, the selection of appropriate orthogonality conditions is essential. ix 3. EMPIRICAL RESULTS Section 3 presents the empirical findings. Section 3.1 in particular focuses on non-parametric analysis, while section 3.2 discusses the estimation results. 3.1. Non Parametric Analysis UK is leading the initiative of incorporating CSR into strategic planning of the company, in order to increase the value of intangible assets. The contribution of the country to the total CSR activities is increasing over the years. ----------------------------Figure 1: about here ----------------------------Figure 1 presents the number of FTSE 250 companies that are included in the BITC index among the best 100 companies in terms of CSR policies. The number of UK companies that are included constantly (e.g., from 83 companies in 2003 to 91 companies in 2010) increases and it dominates the list. This high figure is an initial indication that UK is a sensitive market towards June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 10 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 corporate social profile. In addition, intangible assets appear to be an important part of corporate investments and that social responsibility is an integral part of financial management strategy. ----------------------------Figure 2: about here ----------------------------Figure 2 shows the best performing sectors in the UK in terms of CSR. The individual bars reveal that the best performing sectors are the Energy, Financial Services, Oil and gas and Real estate, with a 13%, 13%, 8% and 8% respectively. Furthermore, this figure shows that companies that are negatively regarded, due to various reasons, they try to compensate the negative impact with socially responsible policies. This is better shown in Figure 3. ----------------------------Figure 3: about here ----------------------------Figure 3 dissects the CSR performance of each sector into Community, Environment, Marketplace and Workplace activities. It is becoming obvious that each sector invests on improving its negatively regarded side, or to enhance its competitive advantage. For example, the Energy and the Mining sectors perform really well in Environment and Community. This way these companies probably try to improve their profile towards their major drawback, which is their environmental impact. In contrast, General retailers invest more on improving their network. They try to improve on the Community and Marketplace aspects of their activity. That could improve an aspect of their corporate activity that they already perform well. ----------------------------Table 1: about here --------------------------------------------------------Table 2: about here ----------------------------June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 11 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Furthermore, Table 1 and Table 2 report the basic descriptive statistics and the correlation of the variables employed in this study, respectively. In more detail Table 1 presents the median, the standard deviation, the mean, the quartiles and the minimum and maximum values of each variable over the years 2003-2008. One of the most profound results is that ROE consistently increases over the years, with an exemption of 2008 and 2009, when the collapse of Lehman Brothers triggered the current financial crisis. The average value is 18.69% in 2003 and it reaches 30.37% in 2010. However, this increase is followed by an increase (e.g., 54.50 in 2003 and 90.03 in 2010) in standard deviation as well. ROE appears to be over-dispersed (standard deviation is larger than the mean), and this effect worsens in 2008 (standard deviation is 84.51, compared to a mean of 9.34%). D/E ratio appears to be over-dispersed as well, and this becomes more obvious after 2008. The average value significantly increases over the years, especially after 2008. Given that financial institutions have been more reluctant to lend, this increase has probably been caused by a shrink of equity capital. Total assets consistently increase over the years and, similar to all other variables, standard deviation is larger than the mean (e.g., mean £860,614 and std £1,058,515 in 2003 and mean £2,064,216 and std £7,977,155 in 2010). In contrast, Liquidity decreases over the years, especially after 2008, while volatility does not significantly change (e.g., mean 1.92 std 5.58 in 2003 and mean 1.80 std 3.16 in 2010). Table 3 fails to report a significant correlation (i.e., in a degree that would cause multicollinearity problems) between the variables employed. 3.2. Estimation Results ----------------------------Table 3: about here ----------------------------- June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 12 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Finally, Table 3 presents the estimation results for the simultaneous equations model in Eqs (1), (2) and (3). The first panel reports the estimates, along with the associated t-statistics. The bottom panel reports the Adj.-R2 and the J-stats, along with the associated p-values. The estimates of Eq. (1), presented in the first column, reveal that CSR, Leverage and Liquidity have a significant impact on performance, while size fails to provide statistically significant results. In more detail, CSR appears to have an asymmetric effect on performance, similar to Bhattacharya and Sen (2004), Bowman and Haire (1975) and Brammer and Millington (2008). CSR appears to have a positive impact on performance when companies embrace social responsibility in their core strategies (0.3548, (3.92)) and when they ignore it (0.8357, (4.78)). A mediocre approach seems to have a negative (-0.1785), marginally significant (-1.97) impact on CFP. In addition, High D/E ratios seem to have a negative (-0.0692, (-4.08)) impact on performance. However, that can be compensated if they lead to higher liquidity, which is found to positively (0.0673, (2.54)) affect performance. The second column reports the estimates of Eq. (2). A profound finding here is the bidirectional relationship between CSR and CFP, which is consistent with Surroca et al. (2010). Coefficient β1 is positive (0.6636) and statistically significant (4.59). This means that, not only CSR increases CFP but, performance has a positive influence on CSR. Similar to Bowman and Haire (1975), Bragdon and Marlin (1972) and Heinz (1976) the investment in CSR depends on the profitability levels of the company. Firms that generate more cash can afford higher investments in CSR. This is consistent with Liquidity as well. An estimate of 0.7868 (2.73) shows that higher liquidity provides more opportunities for further investments in CSR. According to the findings from Eq. (1), this results in better performance. Consequently, liquidity is found to have an direct (Eq. (1)), as well as an indirect (Eq. (2)) positive impact on performance. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 13 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 In addition, larger firms tend to invest more in CSR. The positive estimate of 0.0566 (3.40) shows that companies with higher total assets, consistently perform better in CSR and the score higher in the comparative analysis. This is consistent with Chih et al. (2010), Dierkes and Coppock (1978), Fombrun and Shanley (1990) and Trotman and Bradley (1981), who provide evidence of positive relation and opposes to Stanwick and Stanwick (1998). However, considering the empirical findings in Eq. (1), large companies invest more in CSR and this increased investment further increases their profitability. Consequently, Size has an indirect positive impact on performance, although no direct impact can be identified. This finding is to be expected, since large companies have increased visibility, and according to Watts and Zimmerman (1986) are affected more by CSR. Therefore, they need to actively improve their social profile. A closer inspection of Table 3, and especially on the third column, where the estimation results for Eq. (3) are presented, reveals an endogenous relationship of Size with CSR and performance. Similar to Orlitzky (2001), both CFP (0.4956, (5.13)) and CSR (4.22, (6.91)) are found to increase the size of the company, but as Eq. (2) shows, size directly increases CSR and indirectly CFP. This adds to Ullmann (1985) who argues that the relation between CSR and performance is complex and it is rather an empirical issue. Consequently, large companies are more likely to invest in CSR. This investment increases performance, which increases the size of the firm (CSR increases Size both directly and indirectly through CFP). This way, firms that improve their social profile, seem to create an intangible asset that increases the value of the company. This is a strong indication of increased sensitivity of the market towards CSR. However, that does not appear to hold when the firm is heavily financed using external financing. Excessive borrowing seems to have a negative influence on both financial June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 14 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 performance and CSR (-0.0213, (-2.83)). In consistence with Artiach et al. (2010) highly leveraged firms should be less likely to improve their CSR profiles, even though it would further decrease their tax liability. According to Pecking Order theory financial shareholders’ needs are prioritized over social stakeholders’ interests. Consequently, excessive borrowing will decrease the value of intangible assets and CFP and indirectly the size of the company. Table 4 provides a further insight on the previous findings. The first panel reports the estimates of the models for the period 2003-2007, which corresponds to the pre-crisis period. The second panel reports the estimates for the post-crisis period, i.e. 2008-2010. One of the most profound findings is the reverse relation among leverage, size and profitability before and after the financial crisis following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in October 2008. A positive estimate (0.0124 (2.05)) shows that size has an increasing impact on profitability before 2008, revealing that larger companies could return higher profits to their shareholders. It appears that this was backed up by higher D/E ratios, since leverage seems to have an increasing effect on profitability (0.0161 (2.13)) and on size (0.0149 (2.85)). Companies appear to keep higher borrowing levels, which assists them in increasing their size and their profitability. On the contrary, in the period after 2008, leverage has a reverse impact. Companies that maintain higher D/E ratios appear to have lower profitability (-0.0772 (-4.11)), probably because of higher default risk. Although more profitable companies increase (0.4890 (4.99)) in size, larger companies do not appear to be more profitable. CSR policies appear to be affected as well. Following previous findings, before 2008, larger (0.1051 (3.49)), more profitable (0.8076 (5.49)) companies invest more in CSR activities, especially when they maintain high liquidity ratios (0.7764 (2.77)). Leverage further encourages (0.0012 (2.03)) improvements in CSR profiles, which in turn have a significant, positive impact June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 15 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 on size (4.77 (7.01)). Furthermore, the impact of CSR on performance appears to be non-linear and companies with significant resources invested in CSR appear to be significantly more profitable (0.6134 (4.17)). In contrast, companies with little or no engagement perform better (0.6315 (2.88)) than companies with mediocre policies (-0.1707 (-1.84)). In the period following the financial crisis, this relation weakens. Profitability is improved by significant CSR investments, but the impact is considerably smaller (0.2745 (2.45)). Companies with high D/E ratios reduce their investments in CSR (-0.1017 (-2.89)), probably due to higher financial distress, while companies that base their operations in high Assets Turnover, such as retailers, invest more (0.8011 (2.74), compared to 0.7764 (2.77)). Large (0.0531 (2.40)) and more profitable (0.3963 (3.19)) companies continue to invest in CSR activities, but their engagement seems to be constraint by higher financial costs. In contrast, companies that are not engaged in CSR activities appear to significantly outperform (0.8736 (5.02)) their counterparts, probably due to more cost efficient operations. However, higher investments in CSR still increases the size of operations (2.9500 (4.44)), but not as much as it used to before 2008. 4. CONCLUSION This study focuses on the potentially endogenous relationship among CSR, financial performance and Size, on a general setting that includes companies from FTSE 250 for a period of 8 years (i.e., 2003-2010). A broad measure of CSR is used to account for all major aspects of social profiles. Further, the inter-relations are investigated using a system of equations that are estimated using the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) method. This way the model addresses the following issues. First, the impact of CSR on CFP is examined. Second, the direction of the relationship (if any) is investigated. Third, the model accounts for size, which is allowed to endogenously affect both CSR and CFP. Finally, the impact of excessive borrowing June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 16 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 on performance, CSR and Size is taken into account. The proposed model, suggests an easy and flexible way to investigate the above issues. It provides the framework for an empirical investigation of the sign, the direction and the inter-relation of key variables related to CSR. It can also be further extended by introducing other factors that affect each individual relationship, or factors that might be endogenously related. In addition, it can be applied in different settings, either more specific (e.g., industry, sector, country), or more general (e.g., comparison between sectors, countries). The most profound finding is that UK market is very sensitive to CSR activities. Listed companies appear to be exposed to public and slight changes in their social profiles can significantly affect their performance and size, by creating or diminishing the value of intangible assets. In more detail large, profitable companies are more likely to invest in CSR activities, probably due to increased visibility, especially before the financial crisis in 2008. This investment increases significantly financial performance and size, indicating that these figures are endogenously related. This is a strong indication of market sensitivity towards CSR. This sensitivity decreases in the post-crisis period, but it is still present. In contrast, companies that do not engage in CSR activities seem to be more cost efficient and thus more profitable. This relation is stronger in the post-crisis period. Mediocre policies appear to be rather insignificant and negative. Finally, excessive borrowing is found to increase size, investment in CSR and performance before 2008, but it negatively affects investments in CSR and performance in the post crisis period. This indirectly results in size limitations, even if it reduces tax liabilities. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 17 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 REFERENCES Adams, C. A., & Hill, W. Y., & Roberts, C. B. (1998). Corporate social reporting practices in Western Europe: Legitimating corporate behaviour. The British Accounting Review, 30(1), 1-21. Aguilera, R., & Rupp, D., & Williams, C., & Ganapathi, J. (2007). Putting the s back in corporate social responsibility: A multilevel theory of social change in organizations. Academy of Management Review, 32(3), 836-863. Allouche, J., & Laroche, P. (2005). A meta-analytical investigation of the relationship between corporate social and financial performance. Revue de Gestion des Resources Humaines, 57, 1841. Anderson, J. G., & Frankle, A. W. (1980). Voluntary social reporting: An iso-beta portfolio analysis. Accounting Review, 55(3), 468-479. Artiach, T., & Lee, D., & Nelson, D., & Walker, J. (2010). The determinants of corporate sustainability performance. Accounting and Finance, 50(1), 31-51. Aupperle, K. E., & Carroll, A. B., & Hatfield, J. D. (1985). An empirical examination of the relationship between corporate social responsibility and profitability. Academy of Management Journal, 28(2), 446-463. Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120. Barney, J. B., & Wright, M., & Ketchen Jr., D. J. (2001). The resource-based view of the firm: Ten years after 1991. Journal of Management, 27(6), 625-641. Belkaoui, A. (1976). The impact of the disclosure of the environmental effects of organizational behavior on the market. Financial Management, 5(4), 26-31. Bhattacharya, C. B., & Sen, S. (2004). Doing better at doing good: When, why, and how consumers respond to corporate social initiatives. California Management Review, 47(1), 9-24. Bowman, E. H. (1978). Strategy, annual reports, and alchemy. California Management Review, 20(3), 64-71. Bowman, E. H., & Haire, M. (1975). A strategic posture toward corporate responsibility. California Management Review, 18(2), 49-58. Bradgon, J. H., & Marlin, J. T. (1972). Is pollution profitable?. Risk Management, 19(4), 9-18. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 18 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Brammer, S., & Millington, A. (2008). Does it pay to be different? An analysis of the relationship between corporate social and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 29(12), 1325-1343. Chih, H. L., & Chih, H. H., & Chen, T. Y. (2010). On the determinants of corporate social responsibility: International evidence on the financial industry. Journal of Business Ethics, 93(1), 115-135. Clarke, J., & Gibson-Sweet, M. (1999). The use of corporate social disclosures in the management of reputation and legitimacy: A cross sectoral analysis of UK top 100 companies. Business Ethics European Review, 8(1), 5-13. Cohen, J., & Holder-Webb, L., & Wood, D., & Nath, L. (2011). Retail investors’ perceptions of the decision-usefulness of economic performance governance, and corporate social responsibility disclosures. Behavioural Research in Accounting, 23(1), 109-129. Coombs, J. E., & Gilley, K. M. (2005). Stakeholder management as a predictor of CEO compensation: Main effects and interactions with financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 26(9), 827-840. Dean, K. L. (1988). The chicken and the egg revisited: Ties between corporate social performance and the financial bottom line. Academy of Management Executive, 2, 99–100. Dierkes, M., & Coppock, R. (1978). Europe tries the corporate social report. Business and Society Review, 25, 21-24. Fombrun, C., & Shanley, M. (1990). What’s in a name? Reputation building and corporate strategy. Academy of Management Journal, 33(2), 233-258. Freedman, M., & Jaggi, B. (1982). Pollution disclosures, pollution performance and economic performance. Omega, 10(2), 167-176. Freeman, R. E. (1984). Strategic management. A stakeholder approach. Marshfield, MA: Pitman. Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism and freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Friedman, M. (1970). The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. New York Times Magazine, September 13. Fry, F. L., & Hock, R. J. (1976). Who claims corporate responsibility? The biggest and the worst. Business and Society Review, 18, 62-65. Godfrey, P., & Hatch, N. (2007). Researching corporate social responsibility: An agenda for the 21st century. Journal of Business Ethics, 70(1), 87-98. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 19 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Gray, R., & Javad, M., & Power, D. M., & Sinclair, C. D. (2001). Social and environmental disclosure and corporate characteristics: A research note and extension. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 28(3/4), 327–356. Gray, R., & Kouhy, R., & Lavers, S. (1995). Corporate social and environmental reporting: A review of the literature and a longitudinal study of UK disclosure. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 8(2), 47-77. Griffin, J. J., & Mahon, J. F. (1997). The corporate social performance and corporate financial performance debate: Twenty-five years of incomparable research. Business & Society, 36, 5-31. Hackston, D., & Milne, M. J. (1996). Some determinants of social and environmental disclosures in New Zealand companies. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, 9(1), 77-108. Heinz, D. C. (1976). Financial correlates of a social measure. Akron Business Economic Review, 7(1), 48-51. Higgins, J. M., & Currie, D. M. (2004). It’s time to rebalance the scorecard. Business and Society Review, 109(3), 297-309. Hillman, A. J., & Keim, G. D. (2001). Shareholder value, stakeholder management and social issues: What’s the bottom line?. Strategic Management Journal, 22(2), 125-139. Ingram, R. W., & Frazier, K. B. (1980). Environmental performance and corporate disclosure. Journal of Accounting Research, 18(2), 614-622. Jackson, G., & Apostolakou, A. (2010). Corporate social responsibility in Western Europe: An institutional mirror or substitute?. Journal of Business Ethics, 94(3), 371-394. Jauch, L. R, & Osborn, R. N., & Glueck, W. F. (1980). Short term financial success in large business organization: The environment-strategy connection. Strategic Management Journal, 1, 49-63. Jones, M. T. (1999). The institutional determinants of social responsibility. Journal of Business Ethics, 20(2), 163-179. Jones, T. M. (1995). Instrumental stakeholder theory: A synthesis of ethics and economics. Academy of Management Review, 20(2), 404-437. Makni, R., & Francoeur, C., & Bellavance, F. (2009). Causality between corporate social performance and financial performance: Evidence from Canadian firms. Journal of Business Ethics, 89(3), 409-422. Margolis, J. D., & Walsh, J. P. (2003). Misery loves companies: rethinking social initiatives by business. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48(2), 268–305. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 20 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. (2000). Corporate social responsibility and financial performance: correlation or misspeciο¬ction?. Strategic Management Journal, 21(5), 603-609. McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. (2001). Corporate social responsibility: A theory of the firm perspective. Academy of Management Review, 26(1), 117-127. Moskowitz, M. R. (1972). Choosing socially responsible stocks. Business and Society Review, 1, 71-75. Ness, K., & Mirza, A. (1991). Corporate social disclosure: a note on the test of agency theory. The British Accounting Review, 23(3), 211–217. Orlitzky, M. (2001). Does firm size confound the relationship between corporate social performance and firm financial performance?. Journal of Business Ethics, 33(2), 167-180. Orlitzky, M., & Schmidt, F. L., & Rynes, S. L. (2003). Corporate social and financial performance: A meta-analysis. Organization Studies, 24(3), 403-441. Parket, I. R., & Eilbirt, H. (1975). Social responsibility: The underlying factors. Business Horizons, 18(4), 5-10. Pava, M. L., & Krausz, J. (1996). The association between corporate social-responsibility and financial performance: The paradox of social cost. Journal of Business Ethics, 15(3), 321-357. Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York: Free Press. Preston, L. (1978). Analyzing corporate social Performance: Methods and results. Journal of Contemporary Business, 7(1), 135-150. Reverte, C. (2009). Determinants of corporate social responsibility: Disclosure ratings by Spanish listed firms. Journal of Business Ethics, 88(2), 351-366. Roberts, P. W., & Dowling, G. R. (2002). Corporate reputation and sustained superior financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 23(12), 1077-1093. Rowley, T., & Berman, S. (2000). A brand new brand of corporate social performance. Business & Society, 39(4), 397-418. Simpson, W., & Kohers, T. (2002). The link between social and financial performance: Evidence from the banking industry. Journal of Business Ethics, 35(2), 97-109. Solomon, R., & Hanson, K. (1985). It’s good business. New York: Atheneum. Stanwick, P., & Stanwick, S. (1998). The relationship between corporate social performance, and organizational size, financial performance and environmental performance: An empirical examination. Journal of Business Ethics. 17(2), 195-204. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 21 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Surroca, J., & Tribo, J., & Waddock, S. (2010). Corporate responsibility and financial performance: The role of intangible resources. Strategic Management Journal, 31(5), 463-490. Tan, J. J., & Litschert, R. J. (1994). Environment-strategy relationship and its performance implications: An empirical study of the chinese electronic industry. Strategic Management Journal, 15(1), 1-20. Trotman, K., & Bradley, G. (1981). Associations between social responsibility disclosure and characteristics of companies. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 6(4), 355-362. Ullmann, A. (1985). Data in search of a theory: A critical examination of the relationships among social performance, social disclosure, and economic performance of U.S. firms. Academy of Management Review, 10(3), 540-577. Vance, S. G. (1975). Are socially responsible corporations good investment risks? Management Review, 64(8), 19-24. Waddock, S. A., & Graves, S. B. (1997). The corporate social performance-financial performance link. Strategic Management Journal, 18(4), 303-319. Walsh, J. P., & Weber, K., & Margolis, J. D. (2003) Social issues and management: Our lost cause found. Journal of Management, 29(6), 859-881. Watts, R., & Zimmerman, J. (1986). Positive accounting theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Weidenbaum, M., & Vogt S. (1987). Takeovers and stockholders: Winners and losers. California Management Review, 29(4), 57-168. Williamson, O. E. (1967). The economics of discretionary behaviour: Managerial objectives in a theory of the firm. Chicago: Markham. Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 22 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 APPENDIX Table 1: Basic statistics 2010 Median Std Average First quartile Second quartile Third quartile Lower Limit Upper Limit ROE 13.55 90.03 30.37 4.30 13.55 27.65 -27.10 991.34 D/E 48.94 116.02 83.16 16.42 48.94 100.23 0.62 872.14 TA 947,859 7,977,155 2,064,216 509,150 947,859 1,758,587 50,743 118,057,000 Liq 1.00 3.16 1.80 0.68 1.00 1.65 0.03 38.34 ROE D/E TA Liq Median Std Average First quartile Second quartile Third quartile Lower Limit Upper Limit 10.62 84.51 9.34 -14.23 10.62 29.29 -540.01 556.99 64.40 144.64 109.96 23.36 64.40 136.70 0.00 949.26 764,900 3,167,243 1,640,586 423,275 764,900 1,731,553 40,090 37,614,000 1.04 7.52 2.93 0.69 1.04 1.70 0.04 80.23 2006 Median Std Average First quartile Second quartile Third quartile Lower Limit Upper Limit ROE 23.45 65.79 33.69 14.60 23.45 32.89 -64.64 564.29 D/E 51.79 123.25 93.44 15.75 51.79 114.52 0.05 702.66 TA 663,198 1,761,452 1,212,301 295,190 663,198 1,430,750 0 13,434,000 2004 Median Std Average First quartile Second quartile Third quartile Lower Limit Upper Limit ROE 18.32 36.56 18.50 9.15 18.32 27.58 -274.60 198.26 D/E 43.88 108.23 82.72 14.88 43.88 114.60 0.08 725.69 TA 539,148 1,130,223 902,247 210,738 539,148 1,176,678 0 7,913,600 2008 2009 Median Std Average First quartile Second quartile Third quartile Lower Limit Upper Limit ROE 14.98 31.56 16.30 3.28 14.98 26.84 -132.40 190.96 D/E 51.37 147.31 104.88 18.43 51.37 122.26 0.07 995.86 TA 809,165 5,970,027 1,829,543 444,947 809,165 1,720,718 40,500 86,194,000 Liq 1.03 7.80 2.84 0.66 1.03 1.80 0.03 83.19 ROE D/E TA Liq Median Std Average First quartile Second quartile Third quartile Lower Limit Upper Limit 21.22 67.51 25.24 9.51 21.22 34.48 -692.60 354.23 56.96 129.83 96.11 16.40 56.96 115.33 0.04 815.28 747,007 2,310,039 1,483,071 401,279 747,007 1,496,850 34,221 19,553,000 1.04 8.33 2.81 0.70 1.04 1.64 0.12 76.88 Liq 1.10 6.56 2.37 0.73 1.10 1.72 0.03 78.26 2005 Median Std Average First quartile Second quartile Third quartile Lower Limit Upper Limit ROE 21.94 37.19 25.20 12.42 21.94 31.76 -182.24 289.19 D/E 64.69 132.88 106.11 17.41 64.69 140.73 0.02 659.20 TA 630,910 1,572,833 1,094,005 228,590 630,910 1,418,300 0 12,825,000 Liq 1.09 5.93 2.39 0.80 1.09 1.81 0.06 66.43 Liq 1.16 6.31 2.03 0.71 1.16 1.64 0.04 81.18 2003 Median Std Average First quartile Second quartile Third quartile Lower Limit Upper Limit ROE 18.62 54.50 18.96 6.09 18.62 29.31 -157.74 617.78 D/E 50.81 104.76 79.71 13.10 50.81 106.11 0.13 812.16 TA 501,906 1,058,515 860,614 205,395 501,906 1,064,900 4,979 6,651,700 Liq 1.07 5.58 1.92 0.67 1.07 1.53 0.10 67.47 2007 Table 1 presents the basic statistics for the variables employed. In more detail, the median, the standard deviation, the mean the quartiles, the maximum and the minimum values are reported. The table is dissected in 8 sections, one for each year. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 23 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Table 2: Correlation matrix Lev 1 ROE 0.473 1 Size 0.0036 0.0799 1 Liq 0.1304 0.231 -0.3019 1 Lev ROE Size Liq Table 3: Regression results-full sample Full Sample ROE α0 size α1 csr α 2,1 α 2,2 α 2,3 lev α3 liq α4 J-stats 0.0512 (0.17) -0.0072 (-0.55) 0.8357 (4.78) -0.1785 (-1.97) 0.3548 (3.92) -0.0692 (-4.08) 0.0673 (2.54) 8.32 (0.22) CSR β0 roe β1 size β2 lev β3 liq β4 0.0768 (2.01) 0.6636 (4.59) 0.0566 (3.40) -0.0213 (-2.83) 0.7868 (2.73) SIZE μ0 roe μ1 csr μ2 lev μ3 liq μ4 2.4551 (3.66) 0.4956 (5.13) 4.22 (6.91) -0.0482 (-0.29) 0.3008 (0.83) Table 3 presents the estimation results for the model in Eqs (1), (2) and (3) for the full sample. The first section presents the estimates for the parameters. The values in parentheses are t-statistics. The bottom section reports the Adjusted-R-squared and the J-statistics. The values in parentheses are the associated pvalues. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 24 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Table 4: Regression results-before and after 2008 Before 2008 ROE α0 size α1 csr α 2,1 α 2,2 α 2,3 lev α3 liq α4 J-stats 0.0491 (1.94) 0.0124 (2.05) 0.6315 (2.88) -0.1707 (-1.84) 0.6134 (4.17) 0.0161 (2.13) 0.0709 (2.58) 8.41 (0.21) CSR β0 roe β1 size β2 lev β3 liq β4 0.0809 (2.11) 0.8076 (5.49) 0.1051 (3.49) 0.0012 (2.03) 0.7764 (2.77) SIZE μ0 roe μ1 csr μ2 lev μ3 liq μ4 2.0755 (3.05) 0.5017 (5.01) 4.77 (7.01) 0.0149 (2.85) 0.2930 (0.88) After 2008 ROE α0 size α1 csr α 2,1 α 2,2 α 2,3 lev α3 liq α4 J-stats 0.0542 (0.10) -0.0047 (-0.51) 0.8736 (5.02) -0.1815 (-1.98) 0.2745 (2.32) -0.0772 (-4.11) 0.0666 (3.15) 8.30 (0.22) CSR β0 roe β1 size β2 lev β3 liq β4 0.0692 (1.81) 0.3963 (3.19) 0.0531 (2.40) -0.1017 (-2.89) 0.8011 (2.74) SIZE μ0 roe μ1 csr μ2 lev μ3 liq μ4 2.6146 (3.84) 0.4890 (4.99) 2.9500 (4.44) -0.0242 (-0.22) 0.3534 (0.99) Table 4 presents the estimation results for the model in Eqs (1), (2) and (3) for two sub-samples. The first panel (Before 2008) reports the estimates of the models for the period 2003-2007, while the second panel for the period 2008-2010). The first section of each panel presents the estimates for the parameters. The values in parentheses are t-statistics. The bottom section reports the Adjusted-R-squared and the Jstatistics. The values in parentheses are the associated p-values. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 25 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Figure 1: Number of FTSE 250 companies in the BITC index Number of FTSE 250 companies in BITC index 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Figure 1 shows the number of companies included in FTSE 250 that they are ranked among the first 100 companies that have embraced CSR practices, according to BITC index. Figure 2: Top 10 sectors in CSR Top 10 sectors in CSR Level of participation 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% Sector Figure 2 shows the 10 best performing sectors in terms of CSR performance, according to BITC index. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 26 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Figure 3: Top 10 Sectors in CSR detailed Performance Top 10 Sectors-Detailed 20% 18% 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% Community Environment Marketplace Workplace Figure 3 shows detailed CSR activities per sector, for the top 10 sectors in CSR, according to BITC index June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 27 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 ENDNOTES ο« Corresponding author. i CSR is used to measure how a firm embraces economic, environmental, social and governance factors into its operations and society at large. Godfrey and Hatch (2007) defines CSR as a concept of integrating social and environmental concerns in the business operations and their stakeholders on a voluntary basis. United Kingdom has been chosen because the European business network for CSR reports that 38% of CSR Europe’s web users identified the United Kingdom as the most progressive country in terms of CSR initiatives (followed by Sweden with 11%, the Netherlands with 7% and Denmark with only 6%) Source: <http:// www.csreurope.org/press_releases.php?action=show_press_release&press_id=5> [20.08.11] ii The majority of studies (Bragdon and Marlin (1972) & Heinz (1976) & Moskowitz (1972) & Parket and Eilbirt (1975) & Vance (1975)) uses Return on Equity (ROE) to measure performance, as opposes to Tobin’s Q and Market to Book ratio, which measure market value. However, several studies, although they examine the relationship between social corporate responsibility and performance (Coombs and Gilley (2005) & Griffin and Mahon (1997) & Hillman and Keim (2001) & McWilliams and Siegel (2000), (2001) & Pava and Krausz (1996) & Roberts and Dowling (2002) & Rowley and Berman (2000) & Simpson and Kohers (2002) & Waddock and Graves (1997) & Walsh et al. (2003)), Jones (1999) argues that they fail to systematically address the fundamental determinants of social responsibility. The index reported by “The Business in the Community” covers all aspects of social responsibility, such as community investments and noise pollution, and it is not restricted in terms of industrial or geographical aspects. iii iv Six main approaches have been developed. According to the Social Impact Hypothesis (Freeman (1984) & Jones (1995)), if a firm satisfies the needs and demands of its corporate stakeholders, a favourable financial performance will follow. According to the Slack Resource Hypothesis (Waddock and Graves (1997)), the direction is exactly the opposite, because only a company that generates profits can further invest in its social profile improvement. On the contrary according to the Trade-off Hypothesis increased CSR investments shrink investors wealth and therefore result in limited performance. Similar, according to Managerial Opportunism Hypothesis (Weidenbaum and Vogt (1987) & Willliamson (1967), (1985)), firms only invest in improving their social profile when they do not have other valuable intangible assets. Therefore a high performance negatively affects CSR. On the contrary the Positive (Allouche and Laroche (2005) & Waddock and Graves (1997)) and the Negative (Friedman (1962), (1970)) Synergy hypothesis recognize the endogenous relationship between CSR and performance, without though stating the facts that determine the positive or negative sign. v Jauch et al. (1980) and Tan and Litschert (1994) who assert that the institutional environment alone is becoming broader and more close to the stakeholder concept. It involves components like competitors, customers, suppliers, technology, regulatory bodies, economics, social-cultural and international. vi CSR is measured using the Business In The Community (BITC) index, which provides a ranking according to company’s engagement in various aspects of social responsibility. The data bases used are “FAME” and Business In The Community (BITC). BITC Corporate Responsibility Index is the leading UK voluntary benchmark for corporate responsibility. BITC Index was established in 1982 and now has 830 members. The index is a voluntary and self assessment survey providing an annual benchmark on the management, measurement and reporting of firms’ corporate responsibility. The index uses ranking from 1 to 100 where 1 denotes the worst corporate social responsibility attribution and values close to 1 denotes lower levels of CSR performance. A rank of 100 shows the best exhibition of corporate social responsibility. vii viii For example, a firm with a rank of 1, which is the best result, has a CSR of 100. The higher the ranking, the higher is the CSR Index. All companies that are not in the BITC index, are treated as being the last in the list. Consequently they have a score πΆππ = 1. June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 28 2012 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ix ISBN : 9780974211428 ′ First, let π½ = (πΌπ,π , π½π , ππ ) , where π = 0, … ,4 and π = 1,2, 3 in the special case of π2 , be a vector of the π Μπ‘ , πΏππ£ Μ π‘ , πΏππ Μ π‘ , πΌπ,π‘ ∗ parameters to be estimated, ππ,π‘ a vector of all variables of company π at time π‘, π§1,π‘ = (πππ§π ′ ′ π Μπ‘ , πΏππ£ Μπ‘ ) is a vector of Μ π‘ , πΏππ Μ π‘ , π ππΈ πΆππ π‘ ) is a vector of the instrumental variables for Eq. (1), π§2,π‘ = (πππ§π π Μπ‘ , πΏππ£ Μ π‘ , πΏππ Μ π‘ , πΆππ π‘ )′ is a vector of instrumental variables for Eq. instrumental variables for Eq. (2) and π§3,π‘ = (π ππΈ (3). The ^ sign indicates industry averages. This variables are correlated to the regressors but they are expected to be uncorrelated to the error term, since they are not company specific. π1,π‘ = π ππΈπ,π‘ − πΈ[π ππΈπ,π‘ |π»π,π‘ ] is the error term in Eq. (1), π2,π‘ = πΆππ π,π‘ − πΈ[πΆππ π,π‘ |π»π,π‘ ] is the error term in Eq. (2) and π3,π‘ = πππ§ππ,π‘ − πΈ[πππ§ππ,π‘ |π»π,π‘ ] is the error term in Eq. (3). π»π,π‘ is the available set of information. Then, the following moment conditions can be implied. First, π the forecasting error, er,t , r = 1, 2, 3 in Eqs. (1), (2) and (3), is assumed to have a zero mean (i.e., πΈ[ππ,π‘ (π½, ππ,π‘ )] = π πΈ[er,t ] = 0) and be uncorrelated (i.e., πΈ[ππ,π‘ (π½, ππ,π‘ )] = πΈ[ππ,π‘ ππ,π‘−1 ] = 0). Second, all independent variables are π π assumed to be uncorrelated with er,t (i.e., πΈ[ππ,π‘ (π½, ππ,π‘ )] = πΈ[er,t ∗ π§π,π‘ ] = 0). Summarizing, the joint model is estimated using the following moment conditions: er,t π π,π‘ πΈ { ππ,π‘−1 } = 0. π er,t π§π,π‘ ′ ′ ′ π π π The GMM disturbances are then gathered in a vector (π½, ππ,π‘ ) = [ππ,π‘ (π½, ππ,π‘ ) , ππ,π‘ (π½, ππ,π‘ ) , ππ,π‘ (π½, ππ,π‘ ) ]′. 11 πΌ π The sample means are defined as: π(π½; ππΌ,π ) = ∑π=1 ∑π‘=1 π(π½, ππ,π‘ ), where ππΌ,π contains the observations of ππΌ ππ,π‘−π , π = 1, … , π of a sample T. The idea behind GMM is to choose parameter values for π½, such that the sample moments, π(π½; ππΌ,π ), closely approximate the population moments, π(π½, ππ,π‘ ), or else to make π(π½; ππΌ,π ) as close to zero as possible. By the “Law of Large Numbers” π(π½; ππΌ,π ) ≈ π(π½, ππ,π‘ ) for large values of T, so an appropriate estimate, π½Μ , of the population parameter π½ makes π(π½; ππΌ,π ) ≈ 0. When the number of moment conditions, K, is larger than the number of parameters, L, then the GMM estimator can be written as: ′ Μπ‘ ∗ π(π½; ππΌ,π )) , π½Μ = πππmin (π(π½; ππΌ,π ) ∗ π π½ Μπ‘ is a πΎπ₯πΎ semi-definite “weighting” matrix, such as that lim π Μπ‘ → π (population). The approach where π π→∞ employed for the estimation of π½Μ is the “iterative” GMM, with a heteroskedasticity consistent covariance matrix Μπ‘ = Ω−1 (where Ω = lim π ∗ πΈ[π(π½; ππ ) ∗ π(π½; ππ )′]). (Newey and West, 1987), when computing an estimate for π π→∞ In the above specification, πΎ > πΏ and, therefore, the model is over-identified. Hansen (1982) proposes J-statistics to test the validity of the model, i.e., whether the implied moment conditions fit the data well. π»π is that they do. Jstatistic is asymptotically Chi-squared with πΎ − πΏ degrees of freedom. ′ 2 Μπ‘ ∗ π(π½; ππΌ,π )) → ππΎ−πΏ π½ ≡ (π(π½; ππΌ,π ) ∗ π . June 27-28, 2012 Cambridge, UK 29