Valuing Mortgage Insurance Contracts with Counterparty Risk and Capital Forbearance Chia-Chien Chang and Min-Teh Yu* November 11, 2009 Abstract This study sets up a contingent-claim framework incorporating the counterparty default risk and capital forbearance to derive a closed-form solution of mortgage insurance contracts. This study further investigates how critical policy parameters such as capital requirements, prompt closure, and other policy-instrument parameters relate to the value of mortgage insurance by evaluating the partial derivatives of the closed-form expression. The numerical analysis indicates that default risk premium can be substantial in the presence of catastrophic risk of the housing price. Furthermore, forbearance threshold and time to delay effects could be more significant as initial leverage ratio increases. Key Words: Mortgage insurance, Counterparty default risk, Forbearance, Capital standard. * Chang: Department of Finance, National Kaohsiung University of Applied Science, Kaohsiung, 807, Taiwan. Email: u7501247@yahoo.com.tw. Yu: Department of Finance, Providence University, Taichung 43301, Taiwan. Fax: 886-4-26311170, Email: mtyu@pu.edu.tw. Corresponding author: Yu. 1 1. Introduction In view of the occurrence of subprime mortgage crisis in the United States, Mortgage Insurance Companies Association (MICA) reports that large mortgage insurers of its members have reported $2.6 billion in losses in 2008, sparking concerns that rising foreclosure rates of the borrowers could force the mortgage industry into a money crunch. For example, Shares of Radian Guaranty, Triad, and PMI Mortgage Insurance Group have lost 90 percent of their share value in 2007; Triad Guaranty Insurance Corporation fails to meet capital requirement1 in March 31, 2008 and even is going out of business. As a consequence, the phenomenon that the defaults of the borrower will spill over into the default probabilities of the mortgage insurer needs to be considered, and it is termed ‘counterparty default risk’. However, when the mortgage insurer fails to meet the risk-to-capital ratio and the government is forced to allow continuing their operations in order to avoid the systematic economic crisis, capital forbearance occurs.2 It is essential to incorporate the counterparty default risk and capital forbearance, generally not considered by the previous studies, into the pricing model of mortgage insurance-particularly in the case of a mortgage crisis. Mortgage insurance plays an important role in the functioning of housing finance markets since it transfers the risk exposures on borrowers’ defaults from lenders to mortgage insurers and facilitates the creation of secondary mortgage markets. Private mortgage insurance, known as mortgage guaranty insurance, guarantees that, in the event of a default, a mortgage insurer will pay the mortgage lender for any loss resulting from a property foreclosure up to the 20 to 30 percent of the claim amount 1 As of March 31, 2008, Mortgage Insurance Companies Association (MICA) reports that Triad's risk-to-capital ratio, 27.7-to-1, exceeded the maximum (25-to-1) generally permitted by insurance regulations and Illinois insurance law. 2 Capital forbearance has been recognized in the literature as a major determinant of deposit insurance (e.g. Kane (1986) and Nagarajan and Sealey (1995)) 2 (Canner and Passmore, 1994). Mortgage insurers operate under state insurance laws3 and most states regulate the industry in three special ways: (1) A contingency reserve equal to one-half of all premiums received must be maintained for 10 years; (2) A 4% capital ratio applies to risk in force; (3) A monoline requirement forces a firm to write only mortgage insurance. Due to the subprime mortgage crisis, the rising foreclosure rates of the borrowers results in the capital scarcity of some mortgage insurers. To help private mortgage insurers, some policies of capital injection are published. For instance, Freddie Mac announced that private mortgage insurers do not need to meet the increasing capital requirements when the credit ratings of mortgage insurers have been downgraded below AA. Moreover, on March 19, 2008, the regulator of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mae, the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO) agreed to reduce the existing 30 percent OFHEO-directed capital requirement to 20 percent. The OFHEO estimates that this reduction should provide up to $200 billion of immediate liquidity to the mortgage-backed securities market. The Housing and Economic Recovery Act enacted on July 30, 2008, is intended to ensure the safe and sound operation of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mae by injecting capital into the two large U.S. suppliers of mortgage funding. Furthermore, to solve the short of capital and ensure the operation, the Federal Reserve was forced to bail out American Insurance Group (AIG), the largest insurance company in the world, by providing an emergency loan of $85 billion for AIG to sell off assets to repay losses on September 16, 2008. Voluminous previous studies of the mortgage insurance contracts, such as Schwartz and Torous (1992), Dennis et al. (1997), and Bardhan et al. (2006), model 3 The chartering of the first post-Depression mortgage insurer, the Mortgage Guaranty Insurance Corporation is allowed when Wisconsin passed a mortgage insurance law in 1956. California followed with a comprehensive mortgage insurance act in 1961, and the California statute became the standard for the mortgage insurance laws that followed in other states (Rapkin, 1973). 3 the unconditional probability of default exogenously with a constant interest rate. On the other hand, Kau et al. (1992, 1993, 1995), and Kau and Keenan (1995, 1996) improve the literature by using a structural approach with two state variables, interest rate and housing price, to be more realistic to the market environment and to model defaults endogenously as a put option. This study extends Kau and Keenan (1995, 1996) and sets up an option-pricing framework to price mortgage insurance contracts with the considerations of counterparty default risk and regulatory (capital) forbearance. Our mortgage insurance valuation problem is further complicated by a number of practical considerations. The liabilities facing these mortgage insurers are mainly the premiums of mortgage insurance contracts that are interest rate and housing price sensitive. This fact makes the considerations of interest rate and housing price risks particularly important in modeling the insurer’s liability. This paper uses the square-root process of Cox et al. (1985) to describe the stochastic process of the interest rate and adopts a jump-diffusion model to describe housing price dynamics to reflect the catastrophic events of natural and financial disasters (such as subprime mortgage crisis). Our model and numerical analyses show that the intensity and severity of catastrophic events for the housing price have identified a significant impact on the default risk premiums of the mortgage insurance contract. The higher the mortgage insurer’s initial asset–liability structure is, the lower the default risk of the mortgage insurer and the higher the value of the mortgage insurance will be. Not surprisingly, interest rate risk management practice of a mortgage insurer will affect the mortgage insurance. Finally, we also demonstrate that a lower forbearance threshold increases the impact of delay on the mortgage insurance, and that a longer time of delay amplifies the impact of forbearance threshold on mortgage insurance. 4 The next section presents the model of interest rate, housing price, liability and asset dynamics of a mortgage insurer. Section 3 specifies the payoffs of mortgage insurance for various scenarios and derives closed-form formulae for the mortgage insurance contracts. Section 4 provides the numerical analyses and discussion of the results. The last section draws conclusions about our findings and their implications. 2. A model for the mortgage insurer This study adopts a structural approach to calculate the default probability of mortgage insurers issuing mortgage insurance contracts. Structural models provide a link between the credit quality of a firm and the firm’s economic and financial conditions such as the firm’s assets and capital structure. Hence, defaults are endogenously generated within the model. Specifically, our structural model follows from Cummins (1988), Duan et al. (1995), and Duan and Yu (2005), Lee and Yu (2002, 2007) and it allows for the dynamics of interest rates and liabilities. This structural model allows a mortgage insurer suffering from the default risk of borrowers to bear higher default risk of its own. Since the insurer’s asset–liability structure, interest rate and housing price specification are important factors in determining the values of mortgage insurance, this section begins by specifying the interest rate process, the borrower’s housing price process, and the insurer’s asset and liability dynamics. And then we show their corresponding processes under the risk-neutralized pricing measure. 2.1 The mortgage insurer’s liability process In the literature the liability process is typically modeled by a lognormal diffusion process, such as Cummins (1988) and Fries, et al. (1997). This modeling 5 fails to explicitly take into account the impact of stochastic interest rates and housing prices. This shortcoming is particularly important for modeling the liability value of the mortgage insurer, because falling house prices and rising interest rates are the precipitating factors for the catastrophic nature of mortgage insurance. Following Duan et al. (1995) and Lee and Yu (2007), we model the mortgage insurer’s total liability value as consisting of other two risk components –interest rate and house price risks captured by the Wiener components of the interest rate and house price processes. Hence, the liability value of the mortgage insurer is governed by the following process:4 dL(t ) dH (t ) L dt L ,r dr (t ) L , H L dWL ,t L(t ) H (t ) (1) where L is the instantaneous drift of the liability value at time t ; WL ,t is the Wiener process that pertains to idiosyncratic shocks to the capital market; L , r * L* Lr denotes the instantaneous interest rate elasticity, and L , H L LH H r (t ) represents housing price elasticity of the mortgage insurer’s liability. L L* , 1 Lr2 LH 2 , and L* is the volatility of the small shocks. From the Equation (1), the total liability risk can be expressed as L2,r 2 L2, H H2 2 . That is, the total instantaneous variance of mortgage insurer liabilities can be decomposed into three components: interest rate risk, housing price risk and credit risk. 2.2 The instantaneous interest rate process The instantaneous interest rate is assumed to follow the square-root process of 4 The similar detailed derivation may refer to Duan et al. (1995) and Lee and Yu (2007). 6 Cox et al. (1985). This setting avoids the negative interest rate that appears in Vasicek’s model (Vasicek, 1977). Thus, the instantaneous interest rate process can be written as follows: d r( t) ( r ( t ) )d t t v rr, ,td Z (2) where denotes the mean-reverting force measurement; presents the long-run mean of the interest rate, and is the volatility parameter for the interest rate. It is standard to use the device of risk-neutral pricing technique to price a derivative contract such as mortgage insurance contracts. According to the Girsanov’s theorem, * r , * r (t ) dt , , dZ rQ,t dZ r ,t r r where term r is the market price of interest rate risk and is a constant under the assumption of Cox et al. (1985), and ZrQ,t is a Wiener process under Q , then the dynamics of the interest rate process under the risk-neutralized pricing measure Q can be described as dr (t ) * ( * r (t ))dt v r (t ) dZ rQ,t . (3) 2.3 The housing price process We follow Kau and Keenan (1996) and describe the housing price dynamics for the borrower at time t as the combination of a Wiener process and a compound Poisson process in the following: dH (t ) = mH dt + s H dWH ,t + H (t ) é N (t ) ù êd ú, ( Y 1) l k dt n ê ú êë n= 0 ú û å (4) where H (t ) is the housing price at time t and mH is the expected growth rate of 7 housing price. H is the constant volatility of the Wiener component of the housing price process. Term WH (t ) : t 0 is a standard Wiener process. The role of WH (t ) is the unanticipated instantaneous change of housing price, which reflects normal events, but it may not work so well for abnormal events (such as the catastrophic events, the government policy, or the mortgage crisis). Here, Yn : n 1, 2,... are independent for the sequence and identically distributed nonnegative random variables representing the nth jump size. The jumps in housing prices correspond to the arrival of abnormal information, and this paper assumes that jump size is lognormally distributed with mean q and variance d 2 . The last term, dt , 1 compensates for the jump process, where E (Y 1) exp ( 2 ) , i.e., the 2 expected percentage changes in housing price if an abnormal event occurs. N (t ) : t 0 represents the total number of jumps during a time interval of (0, t ] and it is based on a Poisson process with a intensity parameter . Furthermore, all three sources of randomness, WH (t ) standard Wiener process, N (t ) Poisson process, and Yn the jump size, are assumed to be independent. By the Girsanov’s theorem, dWHQ,t dWH ,t H dt , where term H is the market price of housing price risk, and assuming that the jump risk is nonsystematic and diversifiable (i.e. a risk premium to the jump risk is unnecessary), we show that the dynamic process of housing price under the risk-neutral probability measure Q : dH (t ) = r (t )dt + s H dWHQ,t + H (t ) é N (t ) ù êd ú. ( Y 1) l k dt n ê ú ú ëê n= 0 û å (5) Based on the risk-neutralized results for the interest rate in the Equation (3) and housing price in the Equation (5), the dynamics of a mortgage insurer’s liabilities 8 under the risk-neutralized measure can be arranged as follows: dL(t ) r (t )dt L ,r r (t )dZ rQt, L H, dWHQ t , L dWLQt , , L(t ) (6) where WLQ,t is a Wiener process for the risk-neutral probability measure Q and is independent of ZrQ,t and WHQ,t . 2.4 The mortgage insurer’s asset process We assume that the asset dynamics of the mortgage insurer follows a lognormal diffusion process and consider the impact of stochastic interest rates on the asset value as follows: dA(t ) A dt A,r dr (t ) A dWA,t , A(t ) where A is the instantaneous drift of the asset value at time t ; (7) WA,t is the Wiener process that denotes the credit risk on the assets of the mortgage insurer; A,r *A Ar is the instantaneous interest rate elasticity of the asset of the mortgage r (t ) insurer; A *A , 1 Ar2 , and *A is the volatility of the credit risk. In a risk-neutral world, the asset of the mortgage insurer can be risk neutralized as follows: dA(t ) r (t )dt A,r r (t )dZ rQt, AdWAQt ,, A(t ) (8) where the term WAQ,t is the Wiener process under the risk-neutral measure and is independent with ZrQ,t . 9 3. Valuation of Mortgage insurance Once the risk-neutral processes of interest rate, housing price, liability, and asset dynamics are known, one can value the mortgage insurance by discounting expected payoffs in the risk-neutral world. This section specifies the payoffs of mortgage insurance under alternative considerations. We first present the base case, in which mortgage insurers will not default (i.e., no counterparty risk exists), and then look into the mortgage insurance with counterparty default risk. Finally, we evaluate how regulatory actions and capital forbearance affect the values of mortgage insurance. 3.1 Payoffs of mortgage insurance At time t 0 , i.e., at origination, the lender issues a T month mortgage, secured by the housing, for the amount of B(0) LV H (0) . Let LV be the initial loan-to-value ratio and H (0) is the initial housing price. We assume that the mortgage loan has a fixed interest rate c (risk-free interest rate plus a spread, r (t ) spread ) and that installments y are paid monthly. Hence, with no prepayment or default prior to time t , the loan balance B (t ) at time 0 t T is given by the following expression: B(t ) y 1 1 c (1 c)T t . (9) In addition, at time t 0 , the mortgage insurer writes a mortgage insurance that promises to compensate the lender only when the borrower defaults. The following section presents the payoffs of mortgage insurance under alternative considerations. 10 3.1.1 Without counterparty default risk In the case where the mortgage insurer will not default, we follow Kau and Keenan (1995, 1996) and model mortgage insurance as a portfolio of American put option. Thus, the payoffs of mortgage insurance contact without counterparty risk at time t , M ND (t ) , is given as follows: LR B(t ) M ND (t ) ( B(t ) H (t )) 0 if H (t ) (1 LR ) B(t ) if (1 LR ) B(t ) H (t ) B(t ) (10) if H (t ) B(t ) where LR denotes the coverage ratio. Equation (10) implies that if the housing price H (t ) exceeds the remaining loan balance B (t ) at time 0 t T , it implies that the borrower would not default at time 0 t T and thus the loss of the mortgage insurer is zero. On the other hand, if (1 LR ) B(t ) H (t ) B(t ) or H (t ) (1 LR ) B(t ) at time 0 t T , it shows that the housing price is not sufficient for a full repayment of the loan balance, and the possibility that the borrower defaults increases such that the mortgage insurer cover the remaining loan balance up to some maximum coverage LR in return for receiving the defaulted housing H (t ) . 3.1.2 With counterparty default risk Given the each time interval is a month, the payments of the borrower must be made at each month and the borrower has the opportunity to default at those times. When the mortgage insurer itself is default-risky, the payoffs of mortgage insurance at time t , M D (t ), is given as follows: 11 LR B(t ) L B(t ) A(t ) R L(t ) M D (t ) ( B(t ) H (t )) ( B(t ) H (t )) A(t ) L(t ) 0 if H (t ) (1 LR ) B(t ) and A(t ) L(t ) if H (t ) (1 LR ) B(t ) and A(t ) L(t ) if (1 LR ) B(t ) H (t ) B(t ) and A(t ) L(t ) (11) if (1 LR ) B(t ) H (t ) B(t ) and A(t ) L(t ) otherwise The first and third terms of Equation (11) represent the loss of the mortgage insurer when the borrower default at time 0 t T and the mortgage insurer does not default during the remaining life of the mortgage insurance; namely, during the remaining life of the mortgage insurance, the value of the mortgage insurer’s total asset A(t ) is greater than the expected default trigger L (t ) , and thus the default of the mortgage insurer does not occur. The second and fourth terms of this equation presents recovery values of the mortgage insurance when the mortgage insurer defaults at time 0 t T , i.e., A(t ) is less than L (t ) , and the borrower also default at time 0 t T during the remaining life of the mortgage insurance. The recovery value is, therefore, equal to the nominal claim of the mortgage insurance multiplied by the recovery rate, A(t ) L(t ) . Therefore, the setup of Equation (11) indicates that our mortgage insurance contract embeds a portfolio of vulnerable American puts that may be exercised not only when the mortgage borrowers default but also when the contract is forced to be terminated by the default of mortgage insurers. 3.1.3 With counterparty default risk and capital forbearance In the previous section, we assume an insolvent mortgage insurer will liquidate its assets to meet its obligations. The mortgage insurance contact will be terminated and the insurer will not be in operation. In reality, however, undercapitalized mortgage insurers are not closed immediately and insolvent insurers are still allowed to operate. 12 This phenomenon resembles the capital forbearance observed in the banking industry. We model capital forbearance along the line of Ronn and Verma (1986) and Duan and Yu (1994). At the time 0 t T , a mortgage insurance institution cannot be taken over unless its asset value falls below the forbearance threshold, L(t ) , where is the forbearance parameter and is taken to be less than or equal to one. Even if its asset value of the mortgage insurer cannot meet the capital standard, as long as it does not fall below the forbearance threshold, the mortgage insurer will not be forced to face an immediate intervention and can indeed extend its operation until t . Although capital forbearance alters the conditions for triggering a resolution, the resolution will, if it takes place, fully restore the asset value to the mortgage insurer’s outstanding liabilities, L (t ) . Hence, the cash flow of the mortgage insurance with the counterparty default risk and capital forbearance at time t , M C (t ) , can be characterized as: LR B(t ) F (t ) LR B(t ) A(t ) L(t ) M C (t ) ( B(t ) H (t )) G (t ) ( B(t ) H (t )) A(t ) L(t ) 0 if H (t ) (1 LR ) B(t ) and A(t ) qL(t ) if H (t ) (1 LR ) B(t ) and L(t ) A(t ) qL(t ) if H (t ) (1 LR ) B(t ) and A(t ) L(t ) if (1 LR ) B(t ) H (t ) B(t ) and A(t ) qL(t ) (12) if (1 LR ) B(t ) H (t ) B(t ) and L(t ) A(t ) qL(t ) if (1 LR ) B(t ) H (t ) B(t ) and A(t ) L(t ) otherwise where the parameter q reflects the capital standard set by the regulatory authority, which is the lower bound of the asset value of the mortgage insurer. Generally, mortgage insurer must operate within a 25-to-1 ratio of risk to capital, which means they set aside $1 of capital for every $25 of risk they insure. Insured risk is defined as the percentage of each loan covered by an insurance policy. This capital standard can be translated into q (25 1) / 25 1.04 in our model. Furthermore, F (t ) and 13 G (t ) are the value from the extended operation under forbearance, and their cash flow at the time of (t ) can be described as: if A(t ) L(t ), LR B(t ) F (t ) LR B(t ) A(t ) otherwise. L(t ) (13) if A(t ) L(t ), ( B(t ) H (t )) G (t ) ( B(t ) H (t )) A(t ) otherwise. L(t ) 3.2 Valuation of mortgage insurance contracts To understand the effect of capital requirement and capital forbearance on the mortgage insurance premiums, in this section, we consider a single-period case of the mortgage insurance (single payment loans, i.e., t T ) with the following simplifications. The interest rate simplifies to be constant, and the housing price of the borrower and the liability of the mortgage insurer are independent. Based on these conditions, we intend to ascertain the exact relationship of the mortgage insurance premium under capital standard and forbearance. Based on Equation (10), using Merton’s (1976) pricing results for European put options with constant interest rate, the closed-form formula of mortgage insurance can be represented, DL1 , as follows: ¥ DL1 = å e x p- (l k (+ m= 0 m T1 )(l k) + ( T ) 1 ) [P( K 1 )- P K( 2],) m! where P( Ki ) = Ki exp(- rm T ) N (- d2m ( Ki )) - H (0) N (- d1m ( Ki )), i = 1, 2, ln( H (0) Ki ) + (rm ± d1m,2 m ( Ki ) = s m2 T s m2 )T 2 , K1 = B(T ), K2 = (1- LR ) B(T ), 14 (14) rm = r - l k + m q + 0.5m d2 md 2 , s m2 = s H2 + . T T DL1 , can be duplicated by a long position in a European put option with a strike price K1 and a short position in a European put option with a strike price K 2 , both with the time to maturity equal to the time T . If l = 0, it means that no abnormal shock event occurs, and so the volatility of housing price process only captures the normal volatility. Furthermore, to derive the closed-form formula of the mortgage insurance in response to considering the counterparty default risk and capital forbearance, we directly assume that the asset-debt ratio of the mortgage insurance company A(t ) L(t ) follows a geometric Brownian motion, which replaces the setup of A(t ) and L (t ) in Equations (5) and (7). Thus the dynamics of the asset-debt ratio of the mortgage insurance company under the risk-neutrality are given as: dR(t ) rt dt R dWRQ,t , R(t ) where R denotes the constant volatility of the instantaneous rate of return of R (t ) , which represents the uncertainty sources of both the mortgage insurer’s total asset value and total liability value. Hence, when involving counterparty default risk and capital forbearance, the pricing formula of the mortgage insurance, DL2 , can be described as follows: é æ ö æ ö DL2 = DL1 êR(0) ççN (a2 ) - N (b 1 )÷ + R(0) ççN (d1 ( K3 ), a2 , m) - N (d1 ( K3 ), b2 , m )÷ ÷ ÷ ÷ ÷ ê èç ø èç ø ë + N ( d2 ( K3 ) , a1 , m - ) where 15 ù N (2d (3K )1,bú ,m(15) ) ú û 1 2 s R (T + t ) 2 ,m= s R2 (T + t ) ln(1 R (0)) ± d1,2 ( K 3 ) = T T+ t 1 1 ln( q R (0)) m s R2 T ln(r R(0)) m s R2 T 2 2 a1,2 = , b1,2 = . 2 2 sRT sRT We observe that the values of mortgage insurance under forbearance DL2 are greater than those of a portfolio of Merton's put DL1 and the excess premiums are the forbearance costs. The above closed-form solution can in fact be considered a general form of mortgage insurance pricing under capital forbearance and one with a number of special cases. For example, it yields the case of Bardhan et al. (2006) when we set R(0) = ¥ , 0 , q 1 and l = 0 . Capital forbearance The immediate impact of granting capital forbearance is best demonstrated by the following derivative property: n b1 DL2 DLC DL ( R(0) 1) N dk 2 N d k1 0, (16) DL2 R2 T where n b1 DLC DL2 ( R(0) 1) 0 or 0; R2 T n b1 DL DL2 N dk 2 N dk1 0; R2 T d k1 ln R2 R2 2 , d k 2 d k1 R2 ; and n denotes the probability density function of a standard normal variable. The 16 sign of DL2 is negative indicating that a higher value of makes less undercapitalized insurers will be forborne and then this will reduce the cost of mortgage insurance. We also note that the impact of the forbearance on the mortgage DLC insurance includes a positive (or negative) capital-component effect and a DL negative time-component effect . In other words, when the asset value is larger (or less) than the liability value of the mortgage insurer, the positive (or negative) capital-component effect reflects that less (or more) insolvencies will be resolved at T , whereas the negative time-component effect shows that more insolvencies will be resolved at T . The negative aggregate effect indicates that the time component dominates the capital component. This shows that the forbearance policy can save the loss of mortgage insurer temporarily by delaying closures, but the future resolution cost dominates the loss savings and rises up the cost of mortgage insurer. Capital Requirements The impact of adjusting capital requirements is demonstrated by the following derivative property: DL2 1 DL2 R( 0 n) a(2 q q R2 T )(N 1 d k 3 ( qn ) )a 2 N (d k )4 ( )(17)0 , where dk 3 The positive sign of ln q R2 R2 2 , d k 4 d k 3 R2 . DL2 indicates that the higher level of required capital q 17 increases the cost of mortgage insurance. This property makes intuitive that higher capital requirement may let more undercapitalized, but solvent, insurers to extend their coverage to time T . The extension of coverage will increases the value of mortgage insurance. The mortgage insurance value is expected to be positively related to time delay, and can be shown by the following equation: æ a - md ( K ) s R2 b - md1 ( K3 ) ¶ DL2 1 3 = R(0) n(d1 ( K3 )) çççN ( 2 )- N( 2 ) ¶t 4 (T + t ) èç 1- m 2 1- m 2 +N( a1 - md 2 ( K3 ) 1- m 2 )- N( b1 - md 2 ( K3 ) ö ÷ )÷ > 0. ÷ ÷ 2 ø 1- m This result indicates that extending the time delay to resolve the undercapitalized mortgage insurer raises the cost of mortgage insurer, and the longer the time delay, the higher the cost of the mortgage insurer. Cross Effect of Forbearance and Time of Delay The two key policy parameters of capital forbearance are the forbearance threshold parameter and the time of delay parameter . We find that the forbearance parameter is negatively related to the delay parameter based on the following partial differential: n b1 n d k1 DL22 DL2 0. 2 T The negative relation interprets that a lower capital forbearance threshold allows more undercapitalized mortgage insurer to extend their operations, and increases the DL2 positive impact of delay on the mortgage insurer cost . Meanwhile, it shows that a longer time of delay permits the undercapitalized mortgage insurer to operate 18 over a longer period of time, and therefore lengthens the negative impact of the capital DL2 forbearance threshold on the cost of mortgage insurer . 4. Numerical Analysis This section estimates the values of mortgage insurance for alternative scenarios using the least-squares approach provided by Longstaff and Schwartz (2001). This method is simple, but powerful, for valuing American-style options. To consistent with the fact that payments must be made each month in practice, the simulations are run on a monthly basis with 50,000 paths and then the mortgage insurance premiums are monthly premiums. A base set of parameters is established and summarized in Table 1. [Table 1 is here] Deviations from the base values provide insights into how changes in the characteristics of the asset–liability structure of mortgage insurer, the frequency and severity of catastrophe events of housing price, interest rate process and capital regulatory policy affect the mortgage insurance values. We first consider the case where the mortgage insurer may default, i.e., with counterparty default risk, and then report the default free and default risky mortgage insurance premium rates for alternative sets of catastrophic intensity of housing price and the mean and variances of jump size of housing price. The mortgage insurance premium rates are calculated by prices of mortgage insurance premium as a percentage of the initial loan value. The differences between the default free and 19 default risky mortgage insurance premium rates are the default risk premiums, which are shown in Table 2. As expected, default free mortgage insurance premium rates are more valuable to the mortgage insurer and have higher values than their corresponding default risky mortgage insurance premium rates. The higher the mortgage insurer’s initial asset–liability structure is, the lower the default risk and the higher the mortgage insurance premium rates will be. [Table 2 is here] Furthermore, observe that the default risk premiums increases with the catastrophic intensity and the mean and variance of jump size of housing price. For instance, in the case where the mortgage insurer’s initial asset–liability structure ( A L) is 1.3, mean of jump size ( ) is -0.01 and variance of jump size ( 2 ) is 1, the default risk premium increases from 0.088 basis points to 0.136 basis points when the catastrophic intensity ( ) increases from 0.5 to 1, and rises to 0.360 basis points when the catastrophic intensity increases to 2. The default risk premium increases with catastrophic intensity and the mean of jump size and volatility of housing price, and the premium can be substantial in the presence of jump risk of housing price and should not be neglected in the valuation of mortgage insurance policy. For example, in the case where ( , , 2 ) (2,0.01,0.2) , the default risk premium goes from 0.405 basis points to 0.551 basis points when ( A L) decreases from 1.5 to 1.1, an increment of 14.6 basis points. The increment of default risk premium drops down to about 7 basis points for the case of ( , , 2 ) (0.5,0.01,0.05) . Table 3 reports the premium rate of mortgage insurance contract while fixing 20 ( , , 2 ) (1, 0.01,1). We set (L , H ) 2, 1, 0 to measure different scenarios of housing sensitivity of asset, and set the interest rate elasticity pair to ( A,r , L ,r ) (2, 1) , ( A, r , L , r ) (1 L / A, 1) and ( A,r , L ,r ) (0, 0) , respectively to measure different scenarios of interest rate elasticity gaps. We find that the housing sensitivity of asset is an increasing function of mortgage insurance premium rate. Moreover, in the case of ( A,r , L ,r ) (0, 0) , both assets and liabilities are interest rate insensitive, whereas the scenario of (A, r , L, r ) (1 L / A, 1) has a zero size-adjusted interest rate elasticity gap, which can be regarded as an active interest rate risk management practice that strives to eliminate the interest rate risk facing the mortgage insurer by adjusting the asset–liability mix. The case of ( A, r , L , r ) (2, 1) presents a positive duration gap on the asset–liability structure. The difference in the premium rates for ( A, r , L , r ) (2, 1) and that for (A, r , L, r ) (1 L / A, 1) reflects the interest rate risk. The interest rate risk effect is quite substantial and is more obvious for a lower leverage mortgage insurer. It is also not surprising to see no effect caused by the interest rate risk premium when both assets and liabilities are interest rate insensitive, i.e., for the case of ( A,r , L ,r ) (0, 0) . Note that the mortgage insurance premium rates for the zero-gap and insensitivity scenarios are very similar. This indicates that active interest risk management can achieve the same effect as sticking exclusively to interest rate insensitive assets and liabilities, regardless of the housing price sensitivity of asset. This indicates that a mortgage insurer that employs interest rate management can effectively have a much lower interest rate risk and can increase the values of its mortgage insurance contracts. [Table 3 is here] 21 The premium rate of mortgage insurance under alternative levels of the forbearance threshold , capital requirement q and time to delay are reported in Table 4. As forbearance extends the insurance coverage to the undercapitalized mortgage insurer, the premium rate of mortgage insurance increases with a lower forbearance threshold. For example, under the situations of ( , 2 , ) =(2,0.2,6) and A / L =1.3, the premium rate of mortgage insurance increases from 323.7 basis points to 359.0 basis points when the forbearance threshold decreases from 100% to 95%, and rises to 39.73 basis points when the forbearance threshold decreases from decreases to 90%. In addition, the sensitivities of the forbearance threshold effect increase with their initial levels of leverages. For instance, the mortgage premium rate for a borrower with initial leverage ratio at 1.1 increases by 52.6 basis points when the forbearance threshold reduces from 100% to 90%, and the changes are more substantial (86.5 basis points) for mortgage insurers with a leverage at 1.5. Meanwhile, it shows that the premium rate of mortgage insurance can be saved by delaying resolution of undercapitalized mortgage insurers, which ultimately raises the cost of mortgage insurance. And the time to delay effect could be more substantial as initial leverage ratio increases. For instance, the mortgage premium rate with initial leverage ratio at 1.1 increases by 85 basis points when the time to delay rises from 4 to 6 months, whereas the changes goes up to 103.4 basis points for mortgage insurers with a leverage at 1.5. Moreover, increased capital requirement will result in increased mortgage insurance premium rates. In brief, counterparty default effect, forbearance threshold effect, time to delay effect, and capital requirement effect are critical factors in the premium of mortgage insurance. [Table 4 is here] 22 5. Conclusions We have developed a model for measuring the mortgage insurance premium rate by taking into account the default risk of the mortgage insurer, interest rate risks, catastrophic intensity and severity of the housing price, and capital regulatory policy. We treat forbearance as an option to delay the resolution of undercapitalized mortgage insurer in the current regulatory framework and then derive a closed-form solution with some specific conditions, to examine and measure its impacts, and to discuss its possible implications. The results indicate that the default risk premium can be substantial in the presence of catastrophic risk of the housing price and should not be neglected in the valuation of the mortgage insurance policy. Our results have interesting implications for forbearance policy. We show that the forbearance policy can save the loss of mortgage insurer temporarily by delaying closures, but the future resolution cost dominates the loss savings and rises up the cost of mortgage insurer. Furthermore, time to delay effects is positive related by the value of mortgage insurance. And a lower forbearance threshold increases the impact of delay on the mortgage insurance value, and that a longer time of delay amplifies the impact of forbearance threshold on mortgage insurance value. And forbearance threshold and time to delay effects could be more significant as initial leverage ratio increases. This implies that it would raise the loss of mortgage insurer ultimately, instead of saving the cost of mortgage insurer, when the capital forbearance policy is considered. In sum, counterparty default effect, forbearance threshold effect, time to delay effect and capital requirement effect are all critical factors on the mortgage insurance valuation. 23 References 1. Bardhan, A., R. Karapandža, and B. Urošević, 2006, Valuing Mortgage Insurance Contracts in Emerging Market Economies, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 32, 9–20. 2. Canner, G. B., and W. Passmore, 1994, Private Mortgage Insurance, Federal Reserve Bulletin, 9, 883-899. 3. Cox, J., Ingersoll, J., and S., Ross, 1985, The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Econometrica 53, 385–407. 4. Cummins, J. D., 1988, Risk-Based Premiums for Insurance Guaranty Funds, Journal of Finance 43, 593–607. 5. Dennis, B., C., Kuo, and T., Yang, 1997, Rationales of Mortgage Insurance Premium Structures, Journal of Real Estate Research, 14(3), 359-378. 6. Duan, J. C., Moreau, A., and C.W., Sealey, 1995, Deposit Insurance and Bank Interest Rate Risk: Pricing and Regulatory Implications, Journal of Banking and Finance, 19, 1091–1108. 7. Duan, J. C., and M. T., Yu, 1994, Forbearance and Pricing Deposit Insurance In a Multiperiod Framework, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 61(4), 575-591. 8. Duan, J. C., and M. T., Yu, 2005, Fair Insurance Guaranty Premia in the Presence of Risk-Based Capital Regulations, Stochastic Interest Rate and Catastrophe Risk, Journal of Banking and Finance, 29 (10), 2435–2454. 9. Fries, S. M., P. Mella-Barral and W., R. M. Perraudin, 1997, Optimal Bank Reorganization and the Fair Pricing of Deposit Guarantees, Journal of Banking and Finance, 21, 441-468. 10. Hendershott, P., and R., Van Order, 1987, Pricing Mortgages: Interpretation of the Models and Results, Journal of Financial Services Research, 1(1), 19-55. 11. Kane, E. J., 1986, Appearance and Reality in Deposit Insurance-The Case for Reform, Journal of Banking and Finance, 10, 175 -188. 12. Kau, J. B., and D. C. Keenan, 1995, An Overview of the Option-Theoretic 24 Pricing of Mortgages, Journal of Housing Research, 6(2), 217-244. 13. Kau, J. B., and D. C. Keenan, 1996, An Option-Theoretic Model of Catastrophes Applied to Mortgage Insurance, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 63(4) 639-656. 14. Kau, J., B., D. C. Keenan, and J. E. Epperson, 1992, A Generalized Valuation Model for Fixed-Rate Residential Mortgages, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 24, 280-299. 15. Kau, J. B., D. C. Keenan, and W. J. Muller, 1993, An Option-Based Pricing Model of Private Mortgage Insurance, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 60(2), 288-299. 16. Kau, J. B., D. C. Keenan, W. J. Muller, and J. E. Epperson, 1995, The Valuation at Origination of Fixed-Rate Mortgages with Default and Prepayment, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 11, 3-36. 17. Longstaff, F., and E., Schwartz, 2001, Valuing American Options by Simulation: A Simple Least-Squares Approach, Review of Financial Studies, 14, 113-147. 18. Lee, J. P., and M. T., Yu, 2007, Valuation of Catastrophe Reinsurance with Catastrophe Bonds, Insurance Mathematics and Economics, 41(2), 264-278. 19. Merton, R. C., 1976, Option Pricing when Underlying Stock Returns are Discontinuous, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 125–144. 20. Merton, R. C., 1977. An analytic derivation of the cost of deposit insurance and loan guarantee, Journal of Banking and Finance, 1, 3–11. 21. Nagarajan, S., and C., W. Sealey, 1995, Forbearance, Prompt Closure, and Incentive Compatible Bank Regulation, Journal of Banking and Finance, 19, 1109-1130. 22. Rapkin, C., 1973, The Private Insurance of Home Mortgages. Revised Edition. 23. Ronn, E. I. and A. K. Verma, 1986, Pricing Risk-Adjusted Deposit Insurance: An Option-Based Model, Journal of Finance, 41, 4, 871-895. 24. Schwartz, E., S. and W., N. Torous, 1992, Prepayment, Default, and the Valuation of Mortgage Pass-Through Securities, Journal of Business, 65(2):221-239. 25 25. Vasicek, O.A., 1977, An Equilibrium Characterization of Term Structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 177–188. 26 Table 1 Parameters definitions and base values Asset parameters Values A(0) Mortgage insurer’s asset A/L=1.1,1.3 and 1.5 A, r Interest rate elasticity of asset -1, 0 A Volatility of credit risk 5% Liability parameters L(0) Mortgage insurer’s liability 100 L , r Interest rate elasticity of liability -1, 0 L , H Housing price elasticity of liability -1, 0 L Volatility of credit risk 5% Interest rate parameters r (0) Initial instantaneous interest rate 5% Magnitude of mean-reverting force 0.2 Long-run mean of interest rate 5% Volatility of interest rate 10% r Market price of interest rate risk -0.01 Housing price parameters H (0) Borrower’s housing price 200,000 sH Volatility of housing price risk 5% f Interest rate elasticity of housing price -1, 0 Mean of jump size -1% and 1% Variance of jump size 5%, 10% and 20% Jump intensity 0.5, 1 and 2 H ,r q d 2 Other parameters LR Insurance coverage level 25% y Installments monthly 500 c r spread Contract rate Spread=2% T Loan maturity 360 months Forbearance parameter 100%, 95% and 90% The time of delay 2, 4 and 6 months q Capital standard 1.04, 1.05 and 1.06 27 Table 2 The mortgage insurance premium rates with counterparty default risk but no capital forbearance ( , , 2 ) Default risky MI rate Default risk premiums A/ L A/ L Default free MI rate 1.1 1.3 1.5 1.1 1.3 1.5 (0.5,-0.01, 0.05) 0.811% 0.686% 0.723% 0.756% 0.125% 0.088% 0.055% (0.5, -0.01, 0.1) 0.864% 0.698% 0.755% 0.785% 0.186% 0.109% 0.079% (0.5, -0.01, 0.2) 1.567% 1.197% 1.273% 1.359% 0.370% 0.294% 0.208% (1, -0.01, 0.05) 0.915% 0.718% 0.779% 0.814% 0.197% 0.136% 0.101% (1, -0.01, 0.1) 1.086% 0.688% 0.765% 0.833% 0.398% 0.321% 0.253% (1, -0.01, 0.2) 1.912% 1.480% 1.587% 1.644% 0.432% 0.325% 0.268% (2, -0.01, 0.05) 1.193% 0.752% 0.833% 0.953% 0.441% 0.360% 0.240% (2, -0.01, 0.1) 1.647% 1.180% 1.251% 1.360% 0.467% 0.396% 0.287% (2, -0.01, 0.2) 2.980% 2.519% 2.562% 2.593% 0.461% 0.418% 0.387% 0.871% 0.706% 0.777% 0.796% 0.165% 0.094% 0.075% 0.934% 0.738% 0.797% 0.845% 0.196% 0.137% 0.089% 1.637% 1.258% 1.293% 1.419% 0.379% 0.344% 0.218% 0.975% 0.758% 0.801% 0.845% 0.217% 0.174% 0.130% 1.146% 0.738% 0.785% 0.855% 0.408% 0.361% 0.291% 1.982% 1.540% 1.611% 1.705% 0.442% 0.371% 0.277% 1.273% 0.812% 0.893% 1.015% 0.461% 0.380% 0.258% 1.737% 1.240% 1.311% 1.427% 0.497% 0.426% 0.310% 3.030% 2.479% 2.582% 2.625% 0.551% 0.448% 0.405% (0.5,0.01, 0.05) (0.5, 0.01, 0.1) (0.5, 0.01, 0.2) (1, 0.01, 0.05) (1, 0.01, 0.1) (1, -0.01, 0.2) (2, 0.01, 0.05) (2, 0.01, 0.1) (2, 0.01, 0.2) This table presents mortgage insurance premium rates and default risk premiums with counterparty default risk but no capital forbearance. This table also presents the default risk premium for alternative interest rate and housing sensitivity structure. The mortgage insurance premium rates are calculated by prices of mortgage insurance premium as a percentage of the initial loan value and reported for alternative sets of catastrophe intensities ( ) and catastrophe loss mean and volatilities ( , 2 ) . A / L represents the initial asset–liability structure of the mortgage insurers. All estimates are computed using 50,000 sample paths. Other parameter values are specified in Table 1. 28 Table 3 The mortgage insurance premium rates with counterparty default risk for alternative interest rate and housing sensitivity structure A/ L 1.1 L , H 1.3 1.5 ( A, r , L , r ) (0, 0) 0 1.498% 1.564% 1.789% -1 0.709% 1.061% 1.341% -2 0.228% 0.616% 0.918% L , H ( A, r , L , r ) (1 L / A, 1) 0 1.505% 1.514% 1.768% -1 0.694% 1.011% 1.311% -2 0.208% 0.566% 0.885% L , H ( A, r , L , r ) (2, 1) 0 1.225% 1.304% 1.629% -1 0.514% 0.891% 1.231% -2 0.112% 0.486% 0.834% This table presents the mortgage insurance premium rates with counterparty default risk for alternative interest rate and housing sensitivity structure. The mortgage insurance premium rates are calculated by prices of mortgage insurance premium as a percentage of the initial loan value and reported for alternative sets of housing sensitivity ( L , H ) of the mortgage insurer’s liabilities, interest rate sensitivities ( A, r , L , r ) of the mortgage insurer’s assets and liabilities. A / L represents the initial asset–liability structure or capital position of the mortgage insurers. All estimates are computed using 50,000 sample paths. Other parameter values are specified in Table 1. 29 Table 4 The mortgage insurance premium rates with counterparty default risk and capital forbearance Capital 1.04 requirement Capital forbearance ( , 2 , ) 100% 1.05 1.06 95% 90% 100% 95% 90% 100% 95% 90% A / L 1.1 (0.5, 0.05, 2) 0.185% 0.221% 0.299% 0.204% 0.261% 0.330% 0.231% 0.290% 0.369% (0.5, 0.1, 4) 0.194% 0.236% 0.310% 0.217% 0.279% 0.349% 0.244% 0.308% 0.379% (0.5, 0.2, 6) 0.202% 0.255% 0.324% 0.219% 0.290% 0.368% 0.250% 0.321% 0.399% (1, 0.05, 2) 0.281% 0.329% 0.386% 0.300% 0.358% 0.427% 0.317% 0.377% 0.458% (1, 0.1, 4) 0.594% 0.686% 0.801% 0.650% 0.715% 0.796% 0.667% 0.730% 0.812% (1, 0.2, 6) 0.924% 1.026% 1.147% 0.994% 1.125% 1.267% 1.107% 1.337% 1.579% (2, 0.05, 2) 1.491% 1.594% 1.747% 1.590% 1.733% 1.892% 1.685% 1.868% 2.090% (2, 0.1, 4) 2.514% 2.693% 2.900% 3.174% 3.354% 3.590% 3.434% 3.654% 3.924% (2, 0.2, 6) 3.224% 3.477% A / L 1.3 3.750% 3.413% 3.680% 3.976% 3.630% 3.860% 4.170% (0.5, 0.05, 2) 0.204% 0.258% 0.319% 0.231% 0.289% 0.361% 0.254% 0.317% 0.399% (0.5, 0.1, 4) 0.207% 0.262% 0.327% 0.224% 0.292% 0.362% 0.257% 0.321% 0.398% (0.5, 0.2, 6) 0.216% 0.273% 0.342% 0.230% 0.296% 0.379% 0.263% 0.345% 0.429% (1, 0.05, 2) 0.304% 0.361% 0.424% 0.317% 0.378% 0.449% 0.340% 0.405% 0.487% (1, 0.1, 4) 0.607% 0.699% 0.818% 0.667% 0.733% 0.820% 0.680% 0.810% 0.842% (1, 0.2, 6) 0.997% 1.099% 1.240% 1.007% 1.147% 1.298% 1.121% 1.419% 1.749% (2, 0.05, 2) 1.506% 1.647% 1.879% 1.603% 1.749% 1.911% 1.738% 1.919% 2.140% (2, 0.1, 4) 2.527% 2.750% 2.977% 3.187% 3.402% 3.627% 3.854% 4.067% 4.292% (2, 0.2, 6) 3.237% 3.590% A / L 1.5 3.973% 3.429% 3.699% 4.007% 3.915% 4.112% 4.430% (0.5, 0.05, 2) 0.219% 0.275% 0.345% 0.242% 0.307% 0.386% 0.269% 0.336% 0.425% (0.5, 0.1, 4) 0.224% 0.285% 0.364% 0.236% 0.307% 0.379% 0.274% 0.340% 0.425% (0.5, 0.2, 6) 0.233% 0.298% 0.372% 0.247% 0.333% 0.420% 0.271% 0.357% 0.449% (1, 0.05, 2) 0.321% 0.389% 0.461% 0.334% 0.399% 0.473% 0.360% 0.432% 0.519% (1, 0.1, 4) 0.624% 0.721% 0.845% 0.684% 0.775% 0.881% 0.700% 0.772% 0.869% (1, 0.2, 6) 1.050% 1.161% 1.301% 1.034% 1.189% 1.370% 1.148% 1.518% 1.899% (2, 0.05, 2) 1.523% 1.674% 1.996% 1.720% 1.883% 2.055% 1.869% 2.070% 2.335% (2, 0.1, 4) 2.544% 2.788% 3.095% 3.204% 3.492% 3.786% 3.899% 4.111% 4.354% (2, 0.2, 6) 3.264% 3.637% 4.129% 3.486% 3.838% 4.299% 4.149% 4.312% 4.899% This table presents the mortgage insurance premium rates with counterparty default risk and capital forbearance for alternative capital parameters. The mortgage insurance premium rates are calculated by prices of mortgage insurance premium as a percentage of the initial loan value and reported for alternative sets of capital requirement ( q ), capital forbearance ( ) and time to delay ( ). A / L represents the initial asset–liability structure or capital position of the mortgage insurers. All estimates are computed using 50,000 sample paths. Other parameter values are specified in Table 1. 30