Does bundling matter? Zachary Kaplan* University of Chicago Booth School of Business zkaplan@chicagobooth.edu February 2014 * I thank the members of my dissertation committee for their invaluable support and help: Phil Berger (Chair), Christian Leuz, Haresh Sapra and Sarah L.C. Zechman. I thank Joseph Gerakos, Xiumin Martin, Gerardo Perez, Douglas Skinner and Andrew Sutherland for helpful comments. Does bundling matter? Abstract Firms often release disclosures to investors at the time of the pre-scheduled earnings announcement (“bundling”), then provide relatively few disclosures during the course of the quarter. I investigate the trade-offs of bundling. Consistent with bundling improving investor processing, bundling increases immediate reactions to disclosures and lowers drift. Firms that bundle have lower bid-ask spreads, consistent with bundling improving price efficiency. Firms more frequently bundle more significant disclosures, consistent with firms bundling when there are greater price efficiency benefits to improving information processing. Overall, the evidence suggests the practice of bundling evolved to improve investor processing of information. Does bundling matter? 1. Introduction An important question to understanding how investors’ process disclosures is how combining a second disclosure with an initial disclosure affects investors’ perception of the initial disclosure. Firms release managerial forecasts, dividend declarations, merger announcements, executive changes and buyback updates more frequently on days when they announce earnings than on days when they do not. I investigate whether the practice of bundling disclosures with earnings (“bundling”) evolved to affect the attention disclosures receive from investors. Given the ease with which firms could release disclosures a few days from the earnings announcement relative to at the earnings announcement, the effect of bundling on investor attention has implications for our understanding of whether managers disclose to make information more accessible for investors. I expect bundling affects investor attention by affecting an investor’s cost of valuing a company. Higher processing costs discourage participation in the firm’s equity market, by increasing rational inattention (Sims 2003). Releasing information at the pre-scheduled earnings announcement can decrease the cost of processing a disclosure because when investors do not know when a firm will disclose, the cost of processing a disclosure includes the cost of searching for disclosures when the firm does not release information. Wasted effort can cause investors to be rationally inattentive to non-pre-scheduled disclosures. The high activity level of information intermediaries and the prevalence of conference calls to provide context could also reduce the cost of processing bundled disclosures (Kimbrough 2005; Zhang 2008; Bushee et al. 2010). Alternatively, if investors are over-loaded with information around earnings announcements, and the marginal cost of processing a disclosure increases with the amount of information disclosed, 1 bundling could increase rational inattention (Li 2008; Taylor 2009). Disclosing separately could also increase the extent to which investors fixate on a disclosure when valuing the firm. To study the effect of bundling on investor attention, I assume any increase in attention will increase the rate at which disclosure becomes impounded into price. Prior research demonstrates that markets under-react to disclosures during the announcement window.1 Prior empirical and theoretical research has linked the under-reaction to inattention (Dellavigna and Pollett 2009; Hirschleifer et al. 2009).2 A challenge to studying how bundling affects the rate at which disclosure becomes impounded into price is that firms select when to bundle disclosures (Waymire 1984), so differences in market reactions to bundled and non-bundled disclosures could result from either selection or investor processing. To separate the selection effect from the processing effect, I need an instrument which shifts the probability of the firm bundling. I study how bundling affects the market reaction to dividend announcements, because disclosure precedent creates exogenous variation in the extent to which firms release dividends with the pre-scheduled earnings announcement (Kalay and Lowenstein 1985; Graham et al. 2005; Einhorn and Ziv 2008). Prior bundling increases the probability of the firm subsequently bundling, yet is plausibly unrelated to the content of the current quarter's dividend news. After instrumenting for the endogenous decision of the firm to bundle this quarter using the exogenous (relative to this quarter's news) decision to bundle a prior quarter’s earnings, I find that bundling increases the immediate reaction to dividend news. I also find bundling lowers drift. In addition, the comparability of dividend payments across firms and 1 For papers on the incomplete reaction to disclosure see (Ball and Brown 1968; Bernard and Thomas 1990; Michaely et al. 1995; Bernatzi et al. 1997; Ng et al. 2008). 2 If inattention causes under-reaction, and investors can become informed (or attentive) at some cost, evidence of increased under-reaction can be interpreted as evidence of higher processing costs because when fewer investors process a signal markets will less completely incorporate the signal (Grossman and Stiglitz 1980; Kim and Verrecchia 1994; Hong and Stein 1999). 2 across time – dividend payments are cash – enables me to rule out the alternative explanation that bundled dividend changes have greater implications for future dividends. To ensure my results are not specific to the setting of dividends and earnings announcements, I also investigate the effect of bundling on immediate market reactions and drift for a second disclosure, seasoned equity offering registrations (SEOs). Unlike dividend changes, which contain information about the persistence of the current quarter’s earnings change (DeAngelo et al. 1996), firms registering SEOs tend to miss future earnings targets and these misses are not related to the current quarter’s earnings change (Loughran and Ritter 1997). Investigating the effect of bundling on market reactions for a second disclosure helps to rule out the possibility that the increased immediate market reactions to bundled dividend changes occur because of the complementarity of dividends and earnings. Consistent with bundling causing increased market reactions because of a general information processing effect, I find larger immediate reactions and less drift for bundled SEOs. My second set of hypotheses focuses on understanding whether benefitting investors and their information processing is a key determinant of a firm’s choice to bundle information. Although firms bundle and bundling improves information processing firms could still bundle to lower their own costs of producing information and improving investor processing could be an externality rather than a determinant of that choice.3 Two aspects of bundling suggest the practice cannot be explained by production costs alone. First, pre-scheduling the time at which the firm will release the bundle implies a concern 3 I find firms bundle managerial forecasts 77% of the time they issue a managerial forecast (Anilowski et al. (2007) and Rogers and Van Buskirk (2013)) and 22% of the time they issue a dividend declaration (Kane et al. (1984) and Leftwich and Zmijewski (1994)). I also find firms bundle 22% of buyback updates, 9% of merger announcements, 6% of debt issuances, 10% of announcements of CEO and CFO changes and 7% of announcements of board and other executive changes. 3 for the ease with which investors can acquire information within a reasonable time period of its release. Second, while firms may find their own earnings to be a useful input to their own decisions, which ultimately become disclosures, the decision usefulness of earnings can only explain firms’ making more disclosures around the time of the earnings announcement rather than at the exact time of the announcement. For many disclosures if firms did not wish to bundle, they could simply issue an additional press release at an earlier or later time, and still comply with regulation 8-K, which requires disclosure within five days of a material event. To more formally differentiate an investor processing motivation for bundling from a production cost motivation, I test if the frequency of bundling increases when the investor processing benefits to bundling are greater. First, I test whether firms bundle more significant news more frequently. Conditional on firms attempting to improve processing by bundling, the improvement in processing will be greater for more significant news. To attempt to rule out production costs as an explanation for increased bundling of more significant news, I study how bundling varies with the significance of disclosed news in settings where 1) the process of producing the disclosure remains similar as the significance of the news changes and 2) the timing of the disclosure does not affect the operations of the firm (bundling involves disclosing on a different day). Finally, I also include firm-fixed effects to control for disclosure precedent. I argue dividend changes (compared to non-changes) and CEO/CFO changes (compared with other executive changes) satisfy the above criteria. In each setting I find firms bundle more significant news 3-5% more frequently. Second, I examine whether bundling frequency varies with the firm’s investor base. Transient investors trade more frequently than non-transient investors (Bushee 2001). If part of that trading frequency arises because transients are better able to process disclosures without interme4 diation or better able to search for disclosure, the benefits of bundling will be lower for firms with more transient investors. Assuming firms bundle to decrease rational inattention, firms with more transient investors will have less incentive to bundle. Consistent with bundling clienteles existing, I find the percentage of transient investors declines with the frequency of bundling. To better understand why a majority of firms choose not to bundle in spite of the price efficiency benefits, I informally explore the trade-offs of bundling by surveying investor relations professionals (IR). IR professionals at firms that do not bundle suggest they declare their dividends at board meetings, which they argue is a transparent policy (Graham et al. 2005). IR professionals at firms that bundle suggest they bundle because investors “want” information around the earnings announcement. A potential cost of bundling dividend declarations may arise because audit committees rather than the full board tend to meet around earnings announcements. Although no investor relations professional explicitly acknowledged this concern, deciding the dividend amount without having the entire board present may result in sub-optimal decision making.4 My paper makes several contributions. First, I contribute to the literature on disclosure strategy. While prior literature investigates the extent to which firms disclose strategically depending on the sign of news unconditionally (Damodoran 1989; Patell and Wolfson 1982) or conditional on trading incentives (Cheng and Lo 2006; Brockman et al. 2008), few papers investigate the extent to which managers disclose strategically to affect the accessibility of information. Prior literature demonstrates that firms attempt to make information more accessible by meeting with investors (Solomon and Soltes 2013) and responding to investor questions (Heinrichs 2013). We 4 A survey of investor relations professionals at seven S&P 500 firms indicates that six of the seven hold board meetings more than one week from the earnings announcement and the seventh hold the board meeting more than a day before the announcement. 5 have limited knowledge of the way firms attempt to affect investor processing of disclosures, although the link between drift and investor inattention suggests firms have the potential to do so. My joint findings that bundling improves investor processing and firms bundle more significant news more frequently suggest the practice of bundling has evolved to improve investor processing of information. Second, I contribute to the literature on bundling by demonstrating disclosures have larger immediate reactions when firms release them with the earnings announcement. Prior bundling papers have been primarily concerned with trying to better understand disclosure in the presence of the confounding earnings announcement event (Leftwich and Zmijewski 1994; Anilowski et al. 2007, Rogers and Van Buskirk 2013), rather than investigating the economic consequences of bundling itself. One exception is Waymire (1984), who demonstrates firms bundle good news managerial forecasts with bad news earnings forecasts and concludes bundling arises to at least some extent to dampen the volatility associated with the release of transient bad earnings news. A limitation of this explanation is that time-varying factors such as the sign of the news explain little of the variation in bundling (Rogers and Van Buskirk 2013). I find evidence consistent with a time-invariant concern for investor processing explains some percentage of bundled disclosures. Third, I contribute to the literature on investor processing costs. A lengthy literature suggests 10-K disclosures both respond to change in investors’ processing cost technology (Blankespoor 2011) or affect investors’ processing (Miller 2010; DeFranco et al. 2011; Lawrence 2013). Demonstrating bundled disclosures receive greater attention from investors broadens our understanding of investors’ processing cost technology and extends this understanding beyond the 10-K. 6 The paper proceeds as follows: Section two reviews the literature and develops hypotheses. Section three estimates the impact of bundling on the immediate and subsequent market reactions to information. Section four examines when managers switch from bundled to not bundled dividend declarations and vice-versa. Section five concludes. 2. Related Literature and Hypothesis Development 2.1 Inattention and the timing of disclosure Research assuming market efficiency has struggled to explain the pervasive evidence that markets initially underreact to news (Fama and French 1996). The theoretical literature responded to this failure by introducing market frictions which can generate predictable returns over short windows. Hong and Stein (1999) introduce a model where a limited number of newswatchers observe and react to firm disclosures. They find the speed with which prices adjust to news increases with the number of news watchers, demonstrating that limited attention combined with either risk-aversion or wealth constraints generates momentum. Two recent empirical studies confirm the intuition of this model by documenting that the immediate response to an earnings surprise decreases and drift increases when investors’ opportunity cost of attention is higher (Dellavigna and Pollet 2009; Hirshleifer et al. 2009). Dellavigna and Pollet (2009) demonstrate lower immediate reaction to Friday earnings surprises, which they attribute to a decrease in market participation on Fridays. Hirshleifer et al. (2009) demonstrate lower immediate reaction to earnings surprises on days when many firms release earnings, where the ability to trade in response to other announcements increases the opportunity cost of attention. These studies link the market price’s initial under reaction to volume, further suggesting that the failure of price to fully reflect information arises because of a dearth of investors valuing the firm. If market frictions such as inattention or processing ability affect the market reaction to 7 information, we might expect different market reactions to the same disclosure when that disclosure is released with earnings compared to at another time. A number of studies indicate the firm’s information environment changes around earnings announcements. Managers hold conference calls at earnings announcements, creating an opportunity for investors to extract additional details about the disclosure (Bushee et al. 2003). As studies have linked the credibility of disclosure to market reactions (Hutton et al. 2003; Ng et al. 2013), timing disclosures to coincide with earnings announcements enables firms to respond to investor questions and offer additional credible information. In addition, information intermediaries such as analysts and media outlets more intensively cover the news firms disseminate at the time of earnings announcements (Bushee et al. 2010). If some subset of investors do not search for firm disclosures, but instead rely on intermediaries to provide the information they use to trade, the greater activity of intermediaries will increase the number of investors valuing the firm (Zhang 2008; Soltes 2009). Information disseminated through more accessible channels can be thought of as being processed at lower cost. A rational investor will monitor a specific channel when the benefits to doing so exceeds the costs in terms of time and money. Certain channels, such as reading news wires, impose high costs investors. In contrast, reading the Wall Street Journal may be pleasant for investors, and thus impose a low cost on them. In this sense, dissemination may decrease rational inattention (Wiederholt 2010). Hypothesis 1: Bundling will increase the immediate market reaction to disclosure and decrease drift. 2.2 Firm preference for complete market reactions If a benevolent social planner determined the timing of disclosure, he would select the time which minimized the joint cost of the firm producing the disclosure and investors processing 8 the disclosure.5 In reality, firms select the timing of their disclosure, so firms will only choose the socially optimal time if the benefits they realize from doing so exceed their costs. If investors react to the inaccessibility of information by not valuing the firm, increasing the accessibility of information will increase the number of investors participating in the share market. The effect of increased participation will depend on the structure of the share market, although generally I expect increased participation to have a positive effect on valuation. In complete markets where uninformed investors condition their demand on their expectations of the number of informed investors, increasing the number of informed investors will increase price efficiency (Kyle 1985). Price efficiency has been linked to liquidity (Glosten and Milgrom 1985; Kelly and Ljundquist 2012), cost of capital (Amihud and Mendehlson 1986; Lambert et al. 2012) and investment efficiency (Fishman and Haggerty 1989; Kumar et al. 2012), which have obvious links to firm value. The firm’s benefit to increasing the number of investors may be even greater in markets with short-selling constraints where uninformed investors do not form rational expectations for the number of informed investors (Merton 1987). Miller (1977) models an environment in which investors value the firm with error, do not form rational expectations for the number of other investors valuing the stock and cannot short-sell. In such an environment increasing the number of investors who value the firm will increase the average price of a share of stock, holding constant the mean and variance of valuations. The positive relationship between expected price and participation holds even in markets where investors are risk-neutral and have infinite horizons. When there are agency conflicts, increased awareness may have negative consequences for 5 I assume that larger immediate reactions and lower drift is evidence of lower processing costs. 9 managers even when awareness has a positive effect on price. If more limited monitoring enables managers to increase perquisite consumption (Nagar et al. 2003) or limit the threat of investor activism, managers may benefit from making information less accessible. The empirical literature documents that firms incur incremental expenses to assist investors in processing information. Heinrichs (2013) finds that 58% of companies contacted by an investment manager offer to help interpret the MD&A section of their 10-K. Another stream of literature documents that senior executives routinely meet with investors, even though regulation FD prohibits the disclosure of material non-public information at these meetings (Bushee and Miller 2012; Solomon and Soltes 2013; Bushee et al. 2013). One interpretation of these studies is that by incurring expenses to improve investor processing, firms reveal a preference for better processing. Hypothesis 2A: Firms will disclose strategically to lower investors’ processing costs. Another disclosure strategy managers may follow is to vary the timing of disclosure to increase attention to good news and decrease attention to bad, in order to maximize the share price (Dye 1985; Shin 2003). One constraint which may limit strategic disclosure is that it may influence the manager’s reputation for transparent reporting, a reputation which Graham et al. (2005) suggest 92% of managers wish to establish. Hypothesis 2B: Preferences for lowering investor processing costs will vary with the sign of the news. 3. How does bundling affect the immediate market reaction to news? 3.1 Data sources and descriptive statistics I obtain the dates of all dividend declarations from the CRSP events database. I select all declarations where the firm made a declaration in the previous quarter beginning in 1994 and 10 ending in 2011. I require the firm declare the dividend no more than 130 days after the prior dividend declaration and no less than 50 days after the prior dividend declaration date. Ensuring that the firm did not delay or accelerate its dividend announcement increases the comparability of bundled and non-bundled dividend declarations. I omit firms that stop paying dividends from the sample, as CRSP does not identify a declaration date for these firms and firms who stop paying dividends frequently indicate at the time of the stoppage when they plan to resume paying a dividend, complicating any analysis. I require that the firm have data on CRSP beginning one trading day before the dividend announcement and ending one trading day after. To identify whether the firm bundled its earnings announcement with the dividend declaration, I require that the firm have actual earnings reported on I/B/E/S for an earnings announcement within ninety days of the declaration date. I define a dividend declaration as bundled if the dividend declaration occurs within one calendar day of the earnings announcement. After imposing the sample selection criteria above, I retain 95,355 dividend declarations. In 2.7% of observations the firm decreased their dividend. In 17.8% of observations the firm increased their dividend. In 79.5% of observations the firm did not change their dividend. I find firms bundle 22.6% of dividend declarations. The percentage of bundled declarations is higher for firms that change their dividend (25.3%) than those that do not (21.9%), and higher for those that decrease their dividend (26.2%) than those that increase it (25.1%). While dividend increases are around eight times more frequent than decreases, the economic magnitude of the median increase is much smaller than the median decrease. Only onequarter of increases change the dividend by at least twenty percent, while three-quarters of dividend decreases change the dividend by at least twenty percent. The distribution of dividend increases is highly right-skewed as one-percent of dividend increases at least triple the size of the div11 idend. The frequency of bundling has increased slightly over time, from 19.4% in 1994 to 23.6% in 2011. To investigate the characteristics of firms that bundle, I first rank all the firms on Compustat from zero-to-one on the basis of four characteristics, market value of equity, total assets, book-to-market and return on assets. I present the average percentile rank for firms that bundle and do not bundle in Table I Panel A. I find that the difference between bundling and non-bundling firms is not statistically significant for any of the four characteristics, when I compute the difference clustering standard errors by firm. I also present the percentage dividend yield computed by scaling the previous quarter’s dividend amount by the price one week before the firm declares this quarter’s dividend. The yields for both bundled and non-bundled firms are around 0.75% per quarter which equates to an annual yield of around 3%. In Table I Panel B, I present descriptive statistics by both the sign of the dividend change and bundling. Column (1) demonstrates that as a percentage of the prior dividend, bundled increases are economically larger than non-bundled increases (statistically insignificant). Firms that bundle their dividend decrease also tend to decrease their dividend more than those that do not (statistically significant). Column (2) demonstrates these differences are similar if I scale the dividend change by price rather than the prior quarter’s dividend. Column (3) demonstrates the previous dividend yield is similar for bundled and non-bundled firms, within a dividend change category, but higher for firms decreasing their dividend. Column (4) presents market-adjusted returns from the day before the dividend change to the day after the dividend change. Returns for bundled dividend increases (decreases) are significantly higher (lower) than non-bundled changes. Column (5) adjusts the returns for bundled dividend declarations for the difference between the 12 earnings reported this quarter and the earnings reported the same time last year.6 I find adjusted returns for bundled decreases (increases) are significantly (insignificantly) different from nonbundled returns. Finally, one motivation for believing that bundling increases awareness of a dividend change is that many investors trade around earnings announcements. In column (6), I demonstrate that abnormal volume increases for bundled declarations, irrespective of the sign of the dividend change. 3.2 Does bundling dividends affect the immediate price response to dividend changes? The null hypothesis that bundling does not affect the market reaction to dividend changes, predicts bundled announcements will have a similar market reaction as non-bundled announcements. To test this hypothesis I regress returns on a dummy indicating the firm bundled its dividend announcement with earnings (“bundle”), controls for the dividend change, and my variable of interest, the percentage dividend change interacted with bundle. As controls for the direct effect of the dividend change on returns, I include the percentage dividend change, a dummy indicating an increase, a dummy indicating a decrease and the dividend change scaled by price. The extensive controls for dividend news should allow the interaction to capture any incremental effect of the dividend change on returns as a result of bundling. The hypothesis that bundling increases the immediate market reaction to dividend news predicts a positive coefficient on this interaction. , %∆ ∗ %∆ 1 In Table II column (1), I report results of estimating model (1) using market-adjusted returns from the dividend announcement window beginning one trading day before the dividend 6 I explain in section 3.3 the exact procedure I follow to adjust returns of bundled dividend changes for earnings news. 13 announcement and ending one trading day after. I include firm-fixed effects to control for the dividend policy of the firm. The significant coefficient estimate on the variable of interest ∗ %∆ ( ) suggests the dividend change has a significantly larger effect on announce- ment window returns for firms that bundle their dividend and earnings announcements. A potential challenge interpreting this result is that for bundled announcements the earnings surprise may be a correlated omitted variable, as the earnings surprise is correlated with the sign of the dividend change and causally related to returns. To adjust announcement window returns for the earnings news released simultaneously, I follow Rogers and Van Buskirk (2013). I first pool all earnings announcements between 1994 and 2011 with available data for the actual value of earnings one-year prior. I then calculate the earnings surprise as the difference between this quarter’s earnings and split-adjusted earnings reported one year prior. I then regress marketadjusted returns from the earnings announcement window on the sign of the earnings surprise, the winsorized earnings surprise scaled by price and the winsorized earnings surprise scaled by price multiplied by the winsorized absolute value of the earnings surprise scaled by price: 2 , I then extract the residual from model (2) for all bundled dividend announcements, to obtain a measure of dividend announcement returns adjusted for the expected effect of the earnings surprise. I use this residual as my dependent variable for bundled announcements. For nonbundled observations I continue to use simple market-adjusted returns as the dependent variable. I report results with the dependent variable computed as described above in column (2) (“seasonally adjusted returns”). The value of the coefficient of interest ( ∗ %∆ ) sug- gests doubling the dividend will have on average a 1.5% larger effect on returns over the announcement window when the firm bundles the dividend announcement with an earnings an14 nouncement than when it does not.7 This estimate implies that a firm with a 3% annual dividend yield who cuts their dividend by 50%, on average would have a -2.1% announcement window return when the firm bundles the dividend decrease with earnings compared to a -1.4% announcement window return when the firm does not. I find similar results in column (3) when I adjust returns using an analogous procedure as that described to calculate seasonally adjusted returns, except I compute the earnings surprise by subtracting the average of the most recent analyst forecast on the I/B/E/S detail file from actual earnings. This significantly reduces the size of my sample, as only about one-half of all dividend change firms have analyst following (I require non-bundled firms to have analyst following as well). I continue to find a statistically significant coefficient on the variable of interest, which is nearly identical to the one obtained after controlling for earnings news by seasonally adjusting the dependent variable. To address the possibility that firms with more significant dividend news choose to bundle more frequently, in column (4) I re-estimate model (1) after inserting a separate firm fixed effect for dividend increases, dividend decreases and declarations which do not change the dividend amount. This design should control for any correlation between the market reaction to dividend changes and the time-invariant probability a firm will bundle. I continue to find a statistically significant coefficient of interest.8 7 When I adjust announcement window returns for the earnings surprise, I estimate the average effect of the earnings surprise pooling all earnings announcements, including both dividend payers and non-payers. Independently examining results using only dividend payers, dividend changers and non-dividend payers, I find similar coefficient estimates for model (2). I conclude the sample selected to estimate the average effect of the earnings surprise on returns does not affect the results in Table II. 8 In untabulated analysis, I compare the immediate market reaction to dividend declarations not bundled with earnings or any other disclosure to the immediate market reaction to dividend declarations not bundled with earnings but bundled with another non-earnings disclosure. I find similar immediate market reactions to both sets of dividend changes not bundled with earnings. 15 A concern with the test results reported in columns (1) – (4) is that firms choose to bundle more significant dividend news (not bundle less significant news) and that selection rather than processing explains the increased market reaction to bundled dividend changes. To design a test robust to this possibility, I need a variable which shifts the probability of the firm bundling the dividend with earnings, which is plausibly uncorrelated with the news the firm will disseminate at the time of its subsequent dividend declaration. The bundling of previous dividend declarations affects the probability of the firm bundling a subsequent dividend declaration.9 I argue that the time between dividend declarations limits the ability of managers to select to bundle based on unobservable news (news after controlling for the sign and magnitude of the dividend change), making this assumption plausibly valid. In model (1), the variable of interest is an interaction between the potentially endogenous choice to bundle and the percentage change in the dividend. To instrument for this interaction, I multiply the exogenous prior quarter’s bundling with the percentage change in dividend. I also instrument for bundling using the prior quarter’s bundling, so I have two endogenous variables ( & ∗ %∆ and two instruments & ∗ %∆ I report results of the first stage, in which I regress all control variables and the two instruments on each endogenous variable in columns (5) – (6) of Table II. I find bundling last quarter shifts the probability of bundling this period by 56% (t=61.16). The percentage change in the dividend interacted with the prior quarter’s bundling also has substantial explanatory for this quarter’s interaction, ruling out concerns of a weak instrument. 9 Surveys and theoretical studies provide a rationale as to why the timing of disclosure may be sticky from quarter to quarter. Graham et al. (2005) survey managers and find that past disclosure choices set a precedent and investors expect similar disclosure choices in the future. Einhorn and Ziv (2008) suggest in an environment where investors react skeptically to changes in disclosure, firm’s disclosure policy will be sticky. 16 In column (7), I report instrumental variable (IV) estimates of the incremental effect of bundling on the market reaction to dividend changes using seasonally adjusted returns as the dependent variable. I find the interaction of interest remains statistically significant and its magnitude increases slightly compared to estimates in columns (1) – (4). In column (8), I report IV estimates using only the sample of firms with recent analyst forecasts, adjusting returns for the earnings surprise computed using analyst forecasts. I continue to find significant results.10 In columns (9) – (10), I report results using a sample of dividend declarations where dividend expectations likely equal the prior dividend amount. I explain these results in a robustness section. 3.3 For which firms does bundling increase the magnitude of the reaction? If a less active information environment during non-earnings announcement windows causes the increased reaction to bundled dividend news, the incremental effect of bundling will decrease with the amount of interest the firm attracts from investors during non-earnings announcements. I use two proxies for this level of attention 1) size and 2) analyst following. Larger stocks tend to attract more attention from investors and information intermediaries, so more investors watch the stock during non-earnings announcement periods. Financial analysts assist investors in processing information and as a result aid the efficiency of the price response to disclosure (Zhang 2008). To examine the incremental effect of firm size on the incremental reaction to bundled dividend changes, I augment model (1) by including interactions between size, %∆ ∗ %∆ and , . I retain all control variables from model (1). %∆ ∗ %∆ 10 ∗ %∆ ∗ %∆ ∗ 3 In untabulated analysis, I compute instruments using bundle from the same quarter the prior year & ∗ %∆ and I continue to find statistically significant estimates. 17 I report results of estimating model (3) in Table III. I find that is significantly negative suggest- ing large firms have a significantly smaller incremental reaction to bundling than smaller firms. The estimated incremental reaction to doubling the dividend for a bundled dividend declaration falls from 2.7% for the smallest firm in my sample to 0.2% for the largest. When I use analyst following in place of size to estimate model (3), I obtain similar, although slightly smaller and statistically insignificant coefficient estimates. 3.4 Does the complementarity of dividends and earnings cause larger market reactions? Dividend changes have implications for the persistence of earnings (DeAngelo et al. 1992) and market reactions to non-bundled dividend changes indicate the market recognizes this complementarity (Koch and Sun 2004). If the time between the dividend change and the earnings announcement limits the number of investors who recognize the dividend change has implications for earnings persistence, bundling could generate larger market reactions to dividend changes by increasing the number of investors who recognize the complementarity of dividends and earnings. Alternatively, disclosing into a more active information environment could affect the number of investors who process the disclosure during the announcement window (Zhang 2008; Soltes 2009; Bushee et al. 2010; Drake et al. 2012). If bundling dividend announcements with earnings announcements increases the immediate market reaction because earnings news complements dividend news, I would expect the results in this paper only to have external validity to considering pairs of disclosures which complement one another. In contrast, if bundling elicits more complete market reactions by increasing awareness, I would expect the results in this paper to have external validity to considering a broad number of disclosures. 18 To distinguish between the information environment and complementarity explanations, I examine how the immediate market reaction and drift vary with bundling, for dividend initiations and SEO registrations, two disclosures with a different relationship with future earnings. Dividend changes have implications for the persistence of current earnings (Kane et al. 1984; DeAngelo et al. 1992; Koch and Sun 2004; Skinner and Soltes 2011), but do not signal future earnings changes independently of current earnings (DeAngelo et al. 1996; Bernatzi et al. 1997; Grullon et al. 2005). In contrast, SEO registrations (dividend initiations) signal future earnings decreases (increases) relative to expectations (Healy and Palepu 1988; Loughran and Ritter 1997). At the same time, both SEOs and dividend initiations generate substantial drift, suggesting the market does not completely impound the implications of the disclosure into price during the announcement window (Loughran and Ritter 1995; Michaely et al. 1995). 3.4.1 Does bundling affect the timing of the market response to SEOs? Approximately 5.7% of firms that register to issue equity do so within one trading day of an earnings announcement. I test whether bundling affects the immediate reaction to the registration. In Table IV, column (1), I demonstrate that bundled registrations have significantly lower (-1.4%) seasonally adjusted returns. In column (2) I find that market reactions remain more negative after controlling for the year of the offering, the marketplace of the offering, a series of firm characteristics, the size of the offering relative to shares outstanding as well as a dummy variable indicating the firm issued the securities on the day on which it registered the offering.11 In columns (3) and (4), I demonstrate that this larger initial market reaction translates into less drift both with and without control variables. 11 The marketplace of the offering includes U.S. Public, U.S. Private, Euro Private, Euro Public, Shelf-registered and withdrawn. 19 3.4.2 Does bundling affect the timing of the market response to dividend initiations? To examine the effect of bundling on the initial and subsequent market reaction to dividend initiations, I select all firms that declare a quarterly dividend and have not declared a quarterly dividend in the previous two years (Healy and Palepu 1988). Approximately 26% of firms bundle their dividend initiation with an earnings announcement. In column (5), I demonstrate that seasonally adjusted returns are on average 1.1% higher when the firm bundles the dividend initiation. In column (6), I demonstrate that this result is robust to including year fixed effects, firm characteristics and the dividend yield as control variables. In columns (7) – (8), I demonstrate that this larger initial market reaction translates into less drift (-1.7%) both with and without control variables. 3.5 Robustness 3.5.1 Do bundled dividends have different implications for future performance? In this section, I examine future firm performance to validate that bundled and nonbundled dividend changes have similar implications for future performance. If inattention affects the timing of the price response to dividend changes without affecting future performance, the larger immediate effect of bundled dividend changes on returns should translate into lower drift. In addition, bundled and non-bundled dividend changes should have similar implications for future dividends and future earnings. 3.5.1.1 Returns Prior research suggests changes in dividend policy affect returns for a period of three years (Michaely et al. 1995). However, as long-window returns are a noisy variable and the effect of bundling on the immediate response to dividend changes is fairly modest, even if returns fully reverse over the period I would not have statistical power to identify the effect. As a result, I ex20 amine subsequent returns over both the sixty days after the dividend declaration (Dellavigna and Pollett 2009; Hirschleifer et al. 2009) and at specific times when I expect subsequent events will resolve the initial inattention (Bernard and Thomas 1990; Madsen 2013). To estimate the effect of bundling on subsequent returns I modify model (2) by replacing announcement window returns with subsequent returns. I report results in Table V. In column (1), when I use returns for the sixty days following the dividend announcement window as the dependant variable I find insignificant return reversals for bundled dividend declarations (t=0.3) equal to about 25% of the incremental immediate return response. It is worth noting that many of the control variables indicate there is substantial drift in returns during this window. I expect rational inattention to dividend changes would lead to predictable returns at future dividend announcements, when investors learn the previously overlooked information (Madsen 2013). Examining returns over narrower announcement windows has an advantage of eliminating some of the noise which can affect the precision of estimates of long-window returns. In column (2), I show that the interaction of bundle with the percentage dividend change loads with a negative statistically insignificant coefficient (t=1.57) when I estimate subsequent returns over the three-days around the subsequent dividend change. In column (3), I show that when I sum returns over the subsequent four dividend change announcements the estimated reversals increase in magnitude and become marginally significant (t=1.70).12 3.5.1.2 Dividends and earnings If dividend changes for bundled firms are more economically meaningful, bundled dividend changes would have a greater impact on subsequent dividend changes and earnings changes. 12 In untabulated analysis, I investigate whether bundling dividends with earnings affects post-earnings announcement drift. I find no difference in post-earnings announcement drift between firms that bundle their dividend declarations and those that do not. 21 To examine the impact of bundled dividend changes on future dividend changes, I modify equation (1) by replacing the dependant variable returns, with the split-adjusted difference between the dividend declared this quarter and the split-adjusted two-year ahead dividend amount. I find the interaction of interest enters with a statistically insignificant negative coefficient. I find similar results when I conduct an identical procedure using earnings in place of dividends. Overall, I conclude bundled dividend changes do not better forecast future earnings changes or future dividend changes, suggesting bundled changes and non-bundled changes are comparable. 3.5.2 Do smaller pre-announcement returns explain the increased reaction to bundled dividend changes? If the market expects the firm to change its dividend, it may react less to the announcement of the change because the implications for future value have already been impounded into returns. To investigate this possibility, in untabulated analysis, I compute average market-adjusted returns for the period beginning sixty-one days before the dividend declaration and ending two trading days before. Among firms that decrease their dividend, returns before the declaration are slightly more negative for firms that bundle compared to those that do not. If dividend expectations are a function of pre-market returns, then holding all else constant firms that bundle would have higher announcement window returns because more of the negative news has already been impounded into returns. Pre-announcement returns are similar across bundled and non-bundled observations for firms that increase their dividends and firms that keep the dividend constant. Overall, it does not seem that the increased reaction to bundled dividend changes can be explained by the market better anticipating non-bundled dividend changes. 3.5.3 Does variation in dividend expectations explain the larger market reactions to bundled dividend changes? 22 In columns (1) – (8) of Table II, I follow the prior literature and compute dividend news using a random walk model. . However, for some dividend changes, the market will expect a dividend amount which differs from the amount declared last quarter. Michayluk et al. (2011) demonstrate that firms tend to increase their dividends in the same quarter each year. The return response to successive dividend increases decreases with the length of the streak, suggesting that when the firm increased the dividend in the same quarter the prior year market participants expect a dividend declaration greater than the one declared the prior quarter. Prior research has dealt with this concern by either requiring the firm to pay the same dividend amount for two to four quarters (Koch and Sun 2004; Kothari et al. 2009) or eliminating small dividend increases from the sample of dividend changes (Dhillon and Johnson 1994). In columns (9) – (10) I limit my sample to firms where dividend expectations are more likely equal to the prior dividend amount, although I note this concern is unlikely to affect my results as firms with successive dividend increases do not appear more likely to bundle. In column (9), I include only dividend changes where the firm declares the same dividend for a period of five quarters before changing the dividend.13 I find a slight increase in the coefficient of interest. In column (10), I retain all dividend decreases but only increases larger than 30%, under the intuition that large increases will be less expected and less likely to be a part of a streak (Dhillon and Johnson 1994). I find similar results to those reported in columns (1) – (9). 4. When do firms bundle? 13 This is similar to the requirement in the prior literature that firms maintain a stable dividend policy (Koch and Sun 2004; Kothari et al. 2009). However, the string of identical dividend declarations these papers require is insufficiently long to eliminate dividend declarations in which the firm changed the dividend the same quarter of the prior year. 23 4.1 What disclosures do firms bundle with earnings? Firms incur production costs preparing disclosures and investors incur processing costs incorporating disclosed information into their valuations (Fischman and Haggerty 1989), so firms could bundle either to minimize production costs or processing costs. In this section, I present descriptive evidence on the frequency of bundling across a number of types of disclosures. These descriptive statistics provide some preliminary evidence on the importance of understanding the practice of bundling. I obtain all data from the Capital IQ key developments database. I define a disclosure as bundled with earnings if the disclosure occurs within one calendar day of an earnings announcement. In Table VI, I present results for six disclosures: (1) buyback updates, (2) M&A transaction announcements, (3) debt issuances, (4) managerial forecasts, (5) CEO/CFO changes and (6) Executive/Board Changes – Other. In column (1), I find the percentage of disclosures bundled varies from 77% for managerial forecasts to 6% for debt issuances. If firms produced disclosures randomly during a quarter with sixty-three trading days, I would observe slightly less than five percent of disclosures bundled. For all six disclosures I find the frequency of bundling significantly exceeds five percent. The most bundled disclosure, managerial forecasts, is also a voluntary disclosure. As a result, the firm has complete discretion over the time they will release a managerial forecast. The incremental cost of not bundling a managerial forecast would likely be as small as writing a second press release and remembering to release it a couple of days subsequent to the earnings announcement. Other disclosures are at least to some extent affected by regulation 8-K, which limits, but does not eliminate, the discretion firms have over the timing of disclosure. I further investigate the extent to which production cost explanations affect the timing of 24 disclosure, by tabulating a histogram of dividend declarations by the number of trading days between the earnings announcement and the dividend declaration. Figure I indicates a large spike in dividends declared around the earnings announcement. Dividend declarations also occur more frequently than average the day before the earnings announcement as well as the day after the earnings announcement. In Figure II (Figure III), I observe similar patterns for merger announcements (executive changes). If firms find earnings to be a useful input to decision making, this would explain why firms make disclosure around earnings announcements. However, the data indicates a spike at the exact date of the earnings announcement rather than a mound around the time of the earnings announcement. 4.2 What disclosures do firms bundle with dividends? In Table VI, column (2), I examine the disclosures firms release with the dividend declaration when the firm does not bundle the dividend declaration with earnings. I present results for six disclosures: (1) buyback updates, (2) M&A transaction announcements, (3) debt issuances, (4) managerial forecasts, (5) CEO/CFO changes and (6) Executive/Board Changes – Other. The disclosure firms bundle most with the dividend declaration are updates concerning the firms repurchase program. As these disclosures typically reveal the shares the company has repurchased in the past, the company could make the disclosures at any time during the quarter. So production costs would be unlikely to explain firms grouping buyback updates and dividend declarations together. However, both buybacks and dividends relate to the company’s payout policy, so concerns for investor processing could explain firms systematically bundling these disclosures. 4.3 Do firms bundle significant news more frequently? To differentiate an investor processing motivation for bundling from a cost motivation, I test if firms bundle more significant news more frequently, when improved processing will have a 25 larger effect on price efficiency. To attempt to rule out production costs as an explanation for increased bundling, I study how bundling varies with the significance of disclosed news in settings where 1) the process of producing the disclosure remains similar as the significance of the news changes and 2) the timing of the disclosure does not affect the operations of the firm (bundling involves disclosing on a different day). Finally, I also include firm-fixed effects to control for disclosure precedent. 4.3.1 Do firms bundle significant dividend news more frequently? Exchange regulations suggest (require) firms declare dividends a minimum of seventeen (thirteen) days before they pay the dividend to investors. However, firms declare their dividends an average of 41 days before the dividend declaration date providing most firms substantial flexibility to change their declaration date, without altering the payment date.14 I assume, firms produce more significant news when they change their dividend compared to when they maintain it. To test the hypothesis firms bundle more significant news, I estimate model (4) by regressing a dummy variable set equal to one if the firm bundles the dividend on a dummy variable set equal to one if the firm changes the dividend. I include all payment dates which occur between twenty-three days and sixty-nine days after the dividend declaration date, so that the firm could bundle the dividend declaration while retaining the same payment date.15 In all analysis I include a firm-year fixed effect to control for variation in disclosure precedents which could be correlated with the frequency of dividend changes (Graham et al. 2005; Einhorn and Ziv 2008). 14 The NYSE requires firms declare the dividend a minimum of ten days before the record date, which is the date on which the dividend becomes payable to the shareholder of record. The NYSE further suggests (requires) the record date occur seven (three) days before the payment date (http://nysemanual.nyse.com/lcm/). Ninety-five percent of firms pay the dividend on the same date in consecutive years. 15 I choose twenty-three days and sixty-nine days because these are the tenth and ninetieth percentile difference between the declaration date and payment date. The assumption is that if the earnings announcement occurs within this interval, the firm could have bundled the declaration. 26 ∆ 4 The hypothesis that firms disclose strategically to improve processing combined with the evidence in section 3 that bundling improves investor processing predicts will have a positive coefficient estimate. In Table VII, column (1) I estimate that changing the dividend shifts the probability of the firm bundling the dividend 4.1% (t=6.38). In column (2), I include a dummy variable for declarations which decrease the dividend. The positive coefficient on this variable suggests dividend decreases are slightly more likely to be bundled although the coefficient is not statistically significant. In column (3), I demonstrate this result is robust to including a dummy for whether the firm bundled its dividend declaration in the same quarter the previous year. In column (4), I drop the firm-year fixed effect and run a horse race between disclosure precedent (proxied by lagged bundling), the significance of the news (proxied by a dividend change dummy) and the sign of the dividend news (the dividend decrease dummy). I find lagged bundling explains thirteen times more of the variation in bundling than the significance of the news. I find essentially no evidence that firms bundle dividend increases or decreases more frequently. In untabulated analysis, I find no evidence that firms bundle dividend news more frequently when earnings news has a similar or dissimilar sign as dividend news. I conclude that firms bundle more significant news more frequently, but that disclosure precedent explains significantly more of the variation in bundling. I find the sign of the news explains almost none of the variation in bundling, either unconditionally or conditional on the sign of earnings news. 4.3.2 Do firms bundle significant executive change news more frequently? Firms typically announce executive changes before the new executive replaces the old. This gives firms flexibility to vary the timing of executive changes without the variation having economic consequences. When firms change the CEO or CFO, they create more significant 27 news than when they change a board member or other executive. To test whether firms bundle more significant news I first select the sample of all executive changes in the Capital IQ key developments database. In untabulated analysis, I regress bundle on a dummy variable indicating the executive change was a CEO or CFO. I find firms bundle CEO or CFO changes 2.8% more frequently (t=11.59). I find similar results after including firm fixed effects. 4.4 Are there bundling clienteles? Transient investors trade more frequently than non-transient investors (Bushee 2001). If a portion of that trading frequency arises because transients are better able to process disclosures without intermediation or better able to search for disclosure, the benefits of bundling will be lower when a firm has a large transient investor base. Assuming firms bundle to decrease rational inattention, firms with more transient investors will have less incentive to bundle. To test whether firms with fewer transient investors bundle more frequently, I regress the percentage of disclosures firms bundle on the percentage of shares held by transient investors. I measure the percentage of transactions firms’ bundle, by measuring the percentage of total disclosures which the firm releases within one day of the earnings announcement. As my measure of disclosures, I use the number of Capital IQ key developments. Capital IQ staff reviews firm disclosures and classifies significant disclosures as belonging to one of 97 different key developments, providing a broad measure of disclosure. In Table VIII, column (1), I report results of regressing the percentage of bundled disclosures on firm characteristics, size, book-to-market, return on assets and total assets. I rank all firm characteristics from zero to one in each fiscal year, so the reported coefficient is the average difference in bundling between the lowest and highest firm for each characteristic. I find a statistically 28 significant negative coefficient on size, suggesting that larger firms bundle less frequently. In section 3.3 I find that larger investor processing benefits exist for smaller firms, suggesting these firms should also select to bundle more frequently. I also find a statistically significant positive coefficient for return on assets. This suggests more profitable firms choose to bundle more frequently because they would like for their other disclosures to be interpreted alongside their robust earnings reports. In column (2), I include the percentage of shares held by institutional investors classified by Bushee (2001) as transient investors, quasi-indexers and dedicated investors. I find that firms with a high transient investor base bundle significantly less frequently. In column (3) I demonstrate the relationship between transient investor base and bundling is robust to the inclusion of firm and year fixed effects. In untabulated analysis, I regress the change in bundling on the change in the percentage of transient investors. I compute the change in transient investors as the percentage of transient investors at the 13-F filing date closest to the end of the fiscal year minus the percentage of transient investors at the 13-F filing date one year prior. I compute the change in percentage bundling as the difference between bundling for the current fiscal year minus bundling for the fiscal year prior. I find a significant negative coefficient (t=8.29), which indicates a 10% increase in the transient investor base translates into a 2.7% decrease in bundling. The results from the changes analysis reduce concerns an omitted variable causes both variation in bundling and the transient investor base. 4.5 Does bundling affect the cost of capital? I speculate that one channel through which firms may benefit from bundling is by lowering their cost of capital. I proxy for cost of capital using the bid-ask spread (Amihud and 29 Mendehlson 1986; Leuz and Verrecchia 2000). A challenge in testing how bundling affects bidask spreads is that bundling involves combining other disclosures with the earnings announcement. As earnings announcements affect both spreads and liquidity, this will confound attempts to test the effects of bundling using changes in spreads (Lee et al. 1993). As a result, to examine the linkage between bundling and cost of capital, I examine whether firms who bundle have lower average bid-ask spreads. Bundling firms having lower average bid-ask spreads would be consistent with either bundling lowering bid-ask spreads or with firms who bundle making other disclosure choices to lower informational rents. To test whether firms that bundle disclosures have lower bid-ask spreads, I regress the average closing bid-ask spread during the fiscal year on the variable of interest, the number of Capital IQ key developments which the firm releases within one day of the earnings announcement. To control for the level of disclosure, I also include the total number of key developments in all regressions. Under the hypothesis that bundling improves investor processing, I would expect the number of bundled disclosures to have an effect on bid-ask spreads even after controlling for the level of disclosure. In column (2), Table IX I find that the number of bundled disclosures has a significantly negative effect on bid-ask spreads after controlling for the number of disclosures. In column (3), I demonstrate that this result is robust to including controls for firm characteristics and industry fixed-effects. In untabulated analysis, I find that firms who bundle dividends have lower bid-ask spreads, but that the average effect is much smaller than the estimated effect considering all disclosures on the Capital IQ key developments database. 5. Conclusion In this study I examine the benefits of bundling information releases with the earnings 30 announcement. I document that bundling increases immediate reactions and reduces drift. I also find managers more frequently bundle more significant news, consistent with managers attempting to improve investor processing of information. Although this study focuses on the benefits to bundling disclosure, if delaying disclosure allows investors to trade profitably on their private information, bundling may also create costs. I leave it to future research to investigate these costs. 31 References Amihud, Yakov, and Haim Mendelson. "Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread." Journal of financial Economics 17.2 (1986): 223–249. Anilowski, Carol, Mei Feng, and Douglas J. Skinner. "Does earnings guidance affect market returns? The nature and information content of aggregate earnings guidance." Journal of Accounting and Economics 44.1 (2007): 36–63. Aharony, Joseph, and Itzhak Swary. "Quarterly dividend and earnings announcements and stockholders' returns: An empirical analysis." The Journal of Finance 35.1 (1980): 1–12. Ball, Ray, and Philip Brown. "An empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers." Journal of accounting research (1968): 159–178. Bayless, Mark, and Susan Chaplinsky. "Is there a window of opportunity for seasoned equity issuance?" The Journal of Finance 51.1 (1996): 253–278. Bernard, Victor L., and Jacob K. Thomas. "Evidence that stock prices do not fully reflect the implications of current earnings for future earnings." Journal of Accounting and Economics 13.4 (1990): 305–340. Benartzi, Shlomo, Roni Michaely, and Richard Thaler. "Do changes in dividends signal the future or the past?" The Journal of Finance 52.3 (1997): 1007–1034. Blankespoor, Elizabeth. The impact of investor information processing costs on firm disclosure choice: Evidence from the XBRL mandate. (2012). Brockman, Paul, Inder K. Khurana, and Xiumin Martin. "Voluntary disclosures around share repurchases." Journal of Financial Economics 89.1 (2008): 175–191. Bushee, Brian J. "Do Institutional Investors Prefer Near‐Term Earnings over Long‐Run Value?*." Contemporary Accounting Research 18.2 (2001): 207-246. Bushee, Brian J., et al. "The role of the business press as an information intermediary." Journal of Accounting Research 48.1 (2010): 1–19. Bushee, Brian, Michael Jung, and Gregory Miller. "Do Investors Benefit from Selective Access to Management?." Available at SSRN 1880149 (2013). Bushee, Brian J., Dawn A. Matsumoto, and Gregory S. Miller. "Open versus closed conference calls: the determinants and effects of broadening access to disclosure." Journal of Accounting and Economics 34.1 (2003): 149–180. 32 Bushee, Brian J., and Gregory S. Miller. "Investor relations, firm visibility, and investor following." The Accounting Review 87.3 (2012): 867–897. Cheng, Qiang, and Kin Lo. "Insider trading and voluntary disclosures." Journal of Accounting Research 44.5 (2006): 815–848. Damodaran, Aswath. "The weekend effect in information releases: A study of earnings and dividend announcements." Review of Financial Studies 2.4 (1989): 607-623. DeAngelo, Harry, Linda DeAngelo, and Douglas J. Skinner. "Dividends and losses." The Journal of Finance 47.5 (1992): 1837–1863. DeAngelo, Harry, Linda DeAngelo, and Douglas J. Skinner. "Reversal of fortune dividend signaling and the disappearance of sustained earnings growth." Journal of Financial Economics 40.3 (1996): 341–371. De Franco, Gus, S. P. Kothari, and Rodrigo S. Verdi. "The benefits of financial statement comparability." Journal of Accounting Research 49.4 (2011): 895-931. DellaVigna, Stefano, and Joshua M. Pollet. "Investor inattention and Friday earnings announcements." The Journal of Finance 64.2 (2009): 709–749. Dhillon, Upinder S., and Herb Johnson. "The effect of dividend changes on stock and bond prices." The Journal of finance 49.1 (1994): 281–289. Drake, Michael S., Darren T. Roulstone, and Jacob R. Thornock. "Investor information demand: Evidence from Google searches around earnings announcements." Journal of Accounting Research 50.4 (2012): 1001–1040. Einhorn, Eti, and Amir Ziv. "Intertemporal dynamics of corporate voluntary disclosures." Journal of Accounting Research 46.3 (2008): 567–589. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. "Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies." The journal of finance 51.1 (1996): 55–84. Fishman, Michael J., and Kathleen M. Hagerty. "Disclosure decisions by firms and the competition for price efficiency." The Journal of Finance 44.3 (1989): 633–646. Glosten, Lawrence R., and Paul R. Milgrom. "Bid, ask and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders." Journal of financial economics 14.1 (1985): 71– 100. Graham, John R., Campbell R. Harvey, and Shiva Rajgopal. "The economic implications of corporate financial reporting." Journal of accounting and economics 40.1 (2005): 3–73. 33 Grullon, G., R. Michaely, and R. Thaler. "S. Bernartzi, 2005. Dividend changes do not signal changes in future profitability." Journal of Business 78: 1659–1682. Healy, Paul M., and Krishna G. Palepu. "Earnings information conveyed by dividend initiations and omissions." Journal of Financial Economics 21.2 (1988): 149–175. Hirshleifer, David, Sonya Seongyeon Lim, and Siew Hong Teoh. "Driven to distraction: Extraneous events and underreaction to earnings news." The Journal of Finance 64.5 (2009): 2289– 2325. Hirshleifer, David, and Siew Hong Teoh. "Limited attention, information disclosure, and financial reporting." Journal of Accounting and Economics 36.1 (2003): 337–386. Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein. "A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading, and overreaction in asset markets." The Journal of Finance 54.6 (1999): 2143–2184. Heinrichs, Anne. “Investors’ Access to Corporate Management: A Field Experiment about 1-on-1 calls.” (2013). Hutton, Amy P., Gregory S. Miller, and Douglas J. Skinner. "The role of supplementary statements with management earnings forecasts." Journal of Accounting Research 41.5 (2003): 867–890. Kalay, Avner, and Uri Loewenstein. "Predictable events and excess returns: The case of dividend announcements." Journal of Financial Economics 14.3 (1985): 423–449. Kane, Alex, Young Ki Lee, and Alan Marcus. "Earnings and dividend announcements: is there a corroboration effect?." the Journal of Finance 39.4 (1984): 1091–1099. Kelly, Bryan, and Alexander Ljungqvist. "Testing asymmetric-information asset pricing models." Review of Financial Studies 25.5 (2012): 1366–1413. Kim, Oliver, and Robert E. Verrecchia. "Market liquidity and volume around earnings announcements." Journal of Accounting and Economics 17.1 (1994): 41–67. Kimbrough, Michael D. "The effect of conference calls on analyst and market underreaction to earnings announcements." The Accounting Review 80.1 (2005): 189-219. Koch, Adam S., and Amy X. Sun. "Dividend changes and the persistence of past earnings changes." The Journal of Finance 59.5 (2004): 2093–2116. Kothari, Sabino P., Susan Shu, and Peter D. Wysocki. "Do managers withhold bad news?." Journal of Accounting Research 47.1 (2009): 241–276. 34 Kumar, Praveen, Nisan Langberg, and K. Sivaramakrishnan. "Voluntary disclosures, corporate control, and investment." Journal of Accounting Research 50.4 (2012): 1041–1076. Kyle, Albert S. "Continuous auctions and insider trading." Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society (1985): 1315–1335. Lambert, Richard A., Christian Leuz, and Robert E. Verrecchia. "Information asymmetry, information precision, and the cost of capital." Review of Finance 16.1 (2012): 1–29. Lawrence, Alastair. "Individual investors and financial disclosure." Journal of Accounting and Economics 56.1 (2013): 130-147. Leuz, Christian, and Robert E. Verrecchia. "The economic consequences of increased disclosure." Journal of accounting research (2000): 91–124. Loughran, Tim, and Jay R. Ritter. "The new issues puzzle." The Journal of Finance 50.1 (1995): 23–51. Loughran, Tim, and Jay R. Ritter. "The operating performance of firms conducting seasoned equity offerings." The Journal of Finance 52.5 (1997): 1823–1850. Leftwich, Richard, and Mark E. Zmijewski. "Contemporaneous announcements of dividends and earnings." Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 9.4 (1994): 725–762. Li, Feng. "Annual report readability, current earnings, and earnings persistence." Journal of Accounting and economics 45.2 (2008): 221–247. Madsen, Joshua. “Information disclosures and predictable returns: the resolution of customer momentum.” (2013). Merton, Robert C. "A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information." The Journal of Finance 42.3 (1987): 483-510. Michayluk, David, Karyn Neuhauser, and Scott Walker. "Dividend Increase Repetition and Market Expectations." (2011). Michaely, Roni, Richard H. Thaler, and Kent L. Womack. "Price reactions to dividend initiations and omissions: Overreaction or drift?." The Journal of Finance 50.2 (1995): 573–608. Miller, Edward M. "Risk, uncertainty, and divergence of opinion." The Journal of Finance 32.4 (1977): 1151–1168. 35 Miller, Brian P. "The effects of reporting complexity on small and large investor trading." The Accounting Review 85.6 (2010): 2107-2143. Nagar, Venky, Dhananjay Nanda, and Peter Wysocki. "Discretionary disclosure and stock-based incentives." Journal of Accounting and Economics 34.1 (2003): 283–309. Ng, Jeffrey, İrem Tuna, and Rodrigo Verdi. "Management forecast credibility and underreaction to news." Review of Accounting Studies (2013): 1–31. Patell, James M., and Mark A. Wolfson. "Good news, bad news, and the intraday timing of corporate disclosures." Accounting Review (1982): 509-527. Rogers, Jonathan L., and Andrew Van Buskirk. "Bundled forecasts in empirical accounting research." Journal of Accounting and Economics 55.1 (2013): 43–65. Sims, Christopher A. "Implications of rational inattention." Journal of Monetary Economics 50.3 (2003): 665-690. Skinner, Douglas J., and Eugene Soltes. "What do dividends tell us about earnings quality?." Review of Accounting Studies 16.1 (2011): 1–28. Soltes, Eugene. “News dissemination and the impact of the business press.” (2009). Solomon, David, and Eugene Soltes. "Managerial Control of Business Press Coverage." (2012). Taylor, Daniel. "Individual investors and corporate earnings." Available at SSRN 1707030 (2010). Tetlock, Paul C. "Does public financial news resolve asymmetric information?." Review of Financial Studies 23.9 (2010): 3520–3557. Verrecchia, Robert E. "Discretionary disclosure." Journal of accounting and economics 5 (1983): 179–194. Watts, Ross. "The information content of dividends." The Journal of Business 46.2 (1973): 191– 211. Waymire, Gregory. "Additional evidence on the information content of management earnings forecasts." Journal of Accounting Research 22.2 (1984): 703–718. Wiederholt, Mirko. "Rational inattention." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (Online Edition ed.) (2010). Zhang, Yuan. "Analyst responsiveness and the post-earnings-announcement drift." Journal of Accounting and Economics 46.1 (2008): 201–215. 36 Appendix A: Variable Definitions This appendix describes each variable used in my study. All data are from CRSP and Thomson insider’s for the years 1994 – 2011. Variable Bundle Bundlet-1 Bundlet-4 Percentage change (%ΔDiv) Dividend change scaled by price (ΔDiv/P) Description Dummy variable set equal to one if the dividend declaration occurs within one calendar day of the earnings announcement Dummy variable set equal to one if the prior quarter’s dividend declaration occurs within one calendar day of an earnings announcement Dummy variable set equal to one if the prior year’s dividend declaration occurs within one calendar day of an earnings announcement. I require that this declaration occur no fewer than 350 days before the current quarter’s declaration and no more than 380 days before. This quarter's dividend amount minus last quarter's dividend amount divided by last quarter's dividend amount. I set this value to two if percentage change exceeds two. Change in dividend divided by the price from seven days before the dividend declaration. Prior dividend yield (Divt-1/P) The dividend amount from last quarter divided by the price seven days before the dividend declaration Dividend increase Dummy variable set equal to one when the firm declares a dividend greater than the prior declared amount. Dummy variable set equal to one when the firm declares a dividend less than the prior declared amount. Dummy variable set equal to one if the firm changed the dividend. Dummy variable set equal to one if the firm changed the dividend in the prior year Dividend decrease Dividend change Prior year dividend change (Dividend changet-4) Market-adjusted returns Seasonal-adjusted returns Returns from the trading day before the dividend declaration date until the trading date after minus valueweighted market returns over the same period. First, I calculate the earnings surprise by subtracting reported earnings from the earnings reported in the same quarter one year ago. Second, I pool all earnings announcements on I/B/E/S and regress marketadjusted returns from the earnings announcement window on the sign of the earnings surprise, the winsorized value of the earnings surprise scaled by price and the 37 Formula Divt Divt 1 Divt 1 Divt Divt 1 P Divt 1 P I ( Divt Divt 1 ) I ( Divt Divt 1 ) I ( Divt Divt 1 ) I ( Divt 4 Divt 5 ) Ri RM Forecast-adjusted returns Announcement volume winsorized value of the earnings surprise scaled by price multiplied by the absolute value of the earnings surprise scaled by price. I then take the residual for all bundled announcements. For non-bundled announcements, I use simple market-adjusted returns. First, I calculate the earnings surprise by subtracting reported earnings from the average analyst forecast issued after the prior dividend declaration. Second, I pool all earnings announcements on I/B/E/S and regress market-adjusted returns from the earnings announcement window on the sign of the earnings surprise, the winsorized value of the earnings surprise scaled by price and the winsorized value of the earnings surprise scaled by price multiplied by the absolute value of the earnings surprise scaled by price. I then take the residual for all bundled announcements. For nonbundled announcements, I use simple market-adjusted returns. I include all dividend declarations where an analyst publishes at least one forecast of earnings for the earnings announcement closest to the dividend declaration. I require the analyst issue this forecast after the previous earnings announcement. I delete all observations (bundled or not bundled) without analyst following. Announcement volume is the volume of trade occuring during the three day announcement window divided by the sum of trade during the dividend announcement window and the same period one week earlier. 38 Vol[ 1,1] sum (Vol[ 1,1] , Vol[ 8, 6] ) Table I: Descriptive Statistics Panel A: Characteristics of firms that bundle and do not bundle. I define a dividend declaration as bundled if it is released within one calendar day of an earnings announcement. To compute firm characteristics, I rank all firms on the annual COMPUSTAT file from zero to one on the basis of equity value, total assets, book-to-market and return on assets (EBIT/TA). I use the rank from the fiscal year ending closest to the dividend declaration. Bundle No Yes Percentage of Observations 77.4% 22.6% Equity Value 71.6% 71.3% Total Assets 76.0% 75.1% Book-toMarket 54.3% 54.5% Return on Assets 61.8% 62.9% Percentage Dividend Yield 0.7564% 0.7496% Panel B: Characteristics of dividend declarations presented separately for firms that bundle and do not bundle. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Change MarketSeasonalDividend Percentage Divided by Percentage Adjusted Adjusted Announcement Bundle Change Change Price Dividend Yield Returns Returns Volume No Yes No Yes No Yes Decrease Decrease No Change No Change Increase Increase -39.2% -43.1% 0.0% 0.0% 18.5% 19.7% -0.7% -0.9% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% 1.7% 1.9% 0.7% 0.7% 0.8% 0.7% 39 -1.0% -2.5% 0.1% 0.2% 0.5% 0.8% -1.0% -2.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.5% 0.5% 53.0% 58.9% 50.6% 58.2% 51.8% 58.4% Table II: Effect of bundling on announcement window returns - Results of regressing dividend declaration returns on a dummy variable indicating the firm bundled its dividend declaration with an earnings announcement ("bundle"), the percentage dividend change as well as the variable of interest, bundle interacted with the percentage dividend change. All variable defininations can be found in Appendix A. Reduced Form: Column (1) includes all dividend declarations where the firm declares the dividend at least fifty days after the prior dividend declaration but no more than 130 days after. Column (2) uses the same sample, but uses seasonally adjusted returns as the dependent variable. Column (3) includes firm-fixed effects interacted with the sign of the dividend change. Column (4) includes all observations where at least one analyst issue a forecast within ninety days of the most recent earnings announcement. First Stage: Columns (5) - (6) present first stage results of regressing the two instruments, Bundlet-1 and Bundlet-1 *%ΔDiv, as well as all other exogenous variables on each of the two endogenous variables, Bundlet and Bundlet *%ΔDiv. Second Stage: Columns (7) - (10) report IV estimates. Column (7) includes all dividend declarations where the firm declares the dividend at least fifty days after the prior dividend declaration but no more than 130 days after. Column (8) includes all observations where at least one analyst issue a forecast within ninety days of the most recent earnings announcement. Column (9) includes all dividend changes in which the firm previously paid the same dividend for a period of five quarters. Column (10) includes all dividend decreases and all increases larger than 30%. (1) (2) (3) (4) (7) (8) (5) (6) (9) (10) Sample Returns Bundlet %ΔDiv Bundlet *%ΔDiv Reduced Form market seasonal First Stage seasonal forecast Bundlet ΔD/P ΔDt-1 /P Firm-Fixed Effects Firm-Fixed Effect*Sign of Change N R-squared forecast seasonal seasonal 0.2% 0.0% 0.0% -0.1% -0.1% -0.2% -0.1% -0.1% (-0.48) (0.20) (-1.88) (-1.97) (-1.87) (-0.10) (-0.98) 0.4% 0.4% 0.8% 0.3% 0.4% 0.2% -1.7% 0.0% (2.10) (2.52) (3.52) (1.53) (2.36) (0.98) (-0.38) (0.00) 1.7% 1.5% 1.4% 1.7% 2.2% 2.1% 2.8% 2.4% (4.90) (4.27) (3.34) (3.08) (4.00) (2.32) (2.09) (3.69) 56.0% 0.0% (61.16) (-0.32) Bundlet-1*%ΔDiv Div Increase seasonal (2.38) Bundlet-1 Controls Div Decrease Second Stage Bundlet-1*%ΔDiv 0.7% 57.3% (0.30) (17.47) -1.1% -1.0% -- -0.3% 2.9% -0.1% -0.9% -0.3% -1.7% -1.3% (-6.81) (-6.00) -- (-1.74) (4.67) (-0.80) (-5.74) (-1.67) (-4.68) (-4.68) --- --52.9% 0.2% 0.2% -- 1.5% 2.6% 0.0% 0.2% 0.2% (4.36) (3.83) -- (2.70) (2.63) (0.07) (4.63) (2.71) 42.2% 45.3% 6.8% 54.4% -123.3% -8.3% 37.3% 54.5% -1.7% (2.77) (2.83) (0.41) (2.33) (-3.23) (-0.26) (2.92) (2.34) (-0.38) (3.63) 40.7% 44.2% 58.2% 6.1% -51.1% -10.4% 27.8% 6.3% -2.1% 27.0% (4.11) (4.30) (5.89) (0.94) (-1.96) (-1.89) (6.46) (0.96) (-0.13) (2.51) YES YES NO NO NO NO NO NO NO NO NO NO YES NO NO NO NO NO NO NO 95,335 0.058 95,335 0.059 95,335 0.135 48,422 0.004 95,335 0.335 95,335 0.487 95,335 0.008 48,422 0.042 2,816 0.046 4,866 0.046 Reported below the coefficients are t-statistics clustered at the firm level. 40 Table III: Incremental effect of firm characteristics on announcement window returns I include all dividend declarations where the firm declares the dividend at least fifty days after the prior dividend declaration but no more than 130 days after where the firm also has information on size available from COMPUSTAT. All variable definitions can be found in appendix A. MVE is the market value of equity as of the end of the most recent fiscal year ranked for all firms in the sample by year of the dividend declaration from zero to one. #Analysts is the number of analysts issuing a forecast within ninety days of the announcement date, ranked by year of the dividend declaration from zero to one. Regressions with control variables include dividend increase, dividend decrease, dividend change divided by price and prior dividend yield. (1) (2) Adjusted returns Seasonal %ΔDiv %ΔDiv*Bundle %ΔDiv*Size 1.4% 2.3% (4.31) (3.11) 2.7% 1.0% (3.65) (3.31) -1.3% (-2.87) %ΔDiv*Size*Bundle -2.5% (-2.08) %ΔDiv*#Analysts -0.6% (-1.34) %ΔDiv*#Analysts*Bundle -1.6% Control Variables YES (-1.36) YES 94,449 0.008 94,449 0.008 N R-squared Reported below the coefficients are t-statistics clustered at the firm level. 41 Table IV: Immediate and subsequent reactions to Seasoned Equity Offerings (SEOs) and dividend initiations: All announcement window returns are seasonally adjusted and long-horizon returns are adjusted for the value-weighted portfolio. SEO sample -- I obtain the registration dates of all follow-on equity offerings from SDC Global new issues database. I select all follow-on offerings for U.S. public firms listed on the NYSE, AMEX or Nasdaq in the period 1994 - 2011. Regressions with control variables include year fixed effects, fixed effects for the market place of the offering, firm characteristics, the size of the offering relative to shares outstanding as well as a dummy variable indicating the firm issued the securities on the day on which it registered the offering. The marketplace of the offering includes U.S. Public, U.S. Private, Euro Private, Euro Public, Shelfregistered and withdrawn. Regressions with firm characteristics include the firm's rank by year in the population of firms on COMPUSTAT by size, book-to-market, total assets and return on assets ranked by year. Dividend Initiations -- I select all firms who declare a quarterly dividend who have not declared a quarterly dividend in the previous two years. I also require data from Compustat to compute firm characteristics and earnings data from I/B/E/S to compute adjusted returns. Regressions with control variables include year fixed effects, firm characteristics and dividend yield. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) SEOs Dependent Variable Intercept Bundle Control Variables N R-squared RET[-1,1] Dividend Initiations RET[-1,1] RET[2,61] RET[2,61] -1.8% (-18.19) --- 0.7% (2.47) --- 1.0% (5.66) --- 2.3% (4.85) --- -1.5% (-3.24) -1.2% (-2.66) 2.9% (2.40) 3.0% (2.55) 1.1% (1.88) 1.4% (2.27) -1.7% (-1.93) -1.8% (-2.03) NO YES NO YES NO YES NO YES 7,891 0.002 7,891 0.040 7,891 0.001 7,891 0.030 1,097 0.005 1,097 0.061 1,097 0.003 1,097 0.051 Reported below the coefficients are t-statistics clustered at the firm level. 42 Table V: Effect of bundling on drift - Results of regressing returns after the declaration window on a dummy variable indicating the firm bundled its dividend declaration with an earnings announcement ("bundle"), the percentage dividend change as well as the variable of interest, bundle interacted with the percentage dividend change. All variable definitions can be found in Appendix A. In column (1) the dependent variable is cumulative abnormal returns beginning the second trading day after the dividend declaration and ending 61 calendar days after the dividend declaration. In column (2) the dependent variable is announcement window returns at the time of the next dividend declaration. In column (3) the dependent variable is the sum of announcement window returns for the next four dividend declarations. (1) (2) Dependent Variable (3) CAR[2,61] Ret(Divt+1) Σ1-4 Ret(Divt+i) Bundle %ΔDiv Bundle*%ΔDiv Div Decrease Div Increase Firm Fixed-Effects N R-squared Reported below the coefficients are t-statistics clustered at the firm level. 43 0.1% 0.0% 0.1% (0.59) (0.31) (0.92) 0.6% 0.0% 0.7% (1.32) (-0.17) (2.63) -0.3% -0.5% -0.9% (-0.32) (-1.57) (-1.70) -0.8% 0.1% 0.7% (-1.94) (0.46) (2.25) 0.4% 0.0% -0.1% (2.83) (0.25) (-1.86) YES YES YES 95,333 0.048 92,645 0.052 84,968 0.057 Table VI: Frequency of bundling - I present the frequency of bundling for six disclosures: (1) buyback updates, (2) M&A transaction announcements, (3) debt issuances, (4) managerial forecasts, (5) CEO/CFO changes and (6) Executive/Board Changes – Other. I obtain all data from the Capital IQ key developments database. I include observations from years 2001 2011. I define a bundled disclosure as occuring within one day of an earnings accouncement (column (1)) or within one day of a dividend declaration (column (2)). In column (1), I include all key developments which occur within 60 days of an earnings announcement. In column (2), I include all key developments which occur within 60 days of a dividend declaration and which do not occur within one day of an earnings announcement (not bundled with earnings). (1) (2) Disclosure Buyback Updates % Bundled with earnings % Bundled with dividends 22.3% 18.2% M&A Transaction Announcements 8.8% 5.2% Debt Issuances 6.4% 5.5% Managerial Forecasts 76.9% 13.0% CEO/CFO Changes 10.4% 12.7% 7.4% 12.9% Executive/Board Changes 44 Table VII: Estimates of the effect of news on bundling - Results of regressing a dummy variable indicating the firm bundled the dividend declaration with the earnings announcement on a dividend change dummy, a dividend decrease dummy and a dummy indicating the firm bundled the dividend declaration the same quarter last year. I include all dividend declarations where the payment date occurs between twenty-three and sixty-nine days after the earnings announcement. This criteria ensures the firm could have bundled the dividend declaration while maintaining the same payment date. (1) (2) (3) (4) Dependent variable Dividend Change Bundlet 4.1% (6.38) Dividend Decrease 3.7% (5.52) 3.9% (6.08) 2.2% (1.74) Bundlet-4 4.4% (6.31) 0.0% (0.07) 18.9% (18.81) 58.5% (67.10) Firm-Year Fixed Effects YES YES YES NO N R-squared 55,837 0.52 55,837 0.52 49,391 0.54 49,391 0.54 Reported below the coefficients are t-statistics clustered at the firm level. 45 Table VIII: Estimates of the effect of bundling on the investor base Results of regressing the percentage of bundled disclosures on the number of transient investors and control variables. I calculate the % of bundled disclosures by summing the # of Capital IQ key developments in the calendar year which occur within one day of an earnings announcement and dividing this sum by the total number of Capital IQ key developments. I calculate the percentage of shares held by transient investors by summing the shares held by investors classified by Bushee (2001) as transients and dividing the sum by total shares. I calculate the percentage of shares held by dedicated investors and quasi-indexers similarly. Regressions with firm characteristics include size, book-to-market, total assets and return on assets ranked by year for all firms from zero to one. (1) (2) (3) Dependent variable %Bundled disclsoures %Transient Investors %Dedicated Investors % Quasi-Indexers Size Book-to-market Return on assets Total assets -15.5% (-11.46) 2.6% (4.33) 11.6% (21.00) -17.6% -11.6% (-4.94) (-2.84) 6.2% 8.9% (2.07) (2.87) -9.8% -12.6% (-1.58) (-2.03) -15.4% -8.6% (-11.50) (-6.43) 2.5% 1.8% (4.13) (3.07) 11.6% 9.5% (20.85) (16.90) 5.8% (4.61) 5.7% 5.7% (4.51) (4.51) Industry Effects NO NO YES Year Effects NO NO YES 19,229 0.06 19,229 0.07 19,229 0.13 N R-squared Reported below the coefficients are t-statistics clustered at the firm level. 46 Table IX: Estimates of the effect of bundling on bid-ask spread - Results of regressing the average bid-ask spread on the number of bundled disclosures and control variables. I calculate the bid-ask spread as the average closing bid-ask spread scaled by price over the 365 days of the calendar year, where all average spreads are ranked from zero to one. I calculate the # of bundled disclosures by summing the # of Capital IQ key developments in the calendar year which occur within one day of an earnings announcement. I define # disclosures by summing the number of key developments on the Capital IQ key developments database in the calendar year. Regressions with firm characteristics include size, book-tomarket, total assets, return on assets and price ranked by year for all firms from zero to one. (1) Dependent variable # Disclosures (2) (3) Ranked Bid-Ask Spread -0.3% -0.2% 0.0% (11.68) (9.40) (0.88) -2.2% -0.4% (20.13) (11.64) # Bundled disclosures Industry Effects NO NO YES Firm Characteristics NO NO YES 33,291 0.16 33,291 0.21 33,291 0.87 N R-squared Reported below the coefficients are t-statistics clustered at the firm level. 47 Figure I: Histogram of the percentage of dividend declarations by the number of trading days to the nearest earnings announcement. Negative (Positive) twenty relates to a dividend declaration twenty days before (after) the nearest earnings announcement. Zero relates to a dividend declaration released the same day as an earnings announcement. I include all dividend declarations which occur within 30 trading days of an earnings announcement. I obtain the dates of dividend declarations from the CRSP events database, trading days from CRSP and the dates of earnings announcements from I/B/E/S (1994-2011). 48 Figure II: Histogram of the percentage of merger announcements by the number of trading days to the nearest earnings announcement. Negative (Positive) twenty relates to a merger announcement twenty days before (after) the nearest earnings announcement. Zero relates to a merger announcement released the same day as an earnings announcement. I include all merger announcements which occur within 30 trading days of an earnings announcement. I obtain the dates of earnings announcements and merger announcements from the Capital IQ key developments database (2001-2011). Figure III: Histogram of the percentage of CEO/CFO announcements by the number of trading days to the nearest earnings announcement. Negative (Positive) twenty relates to a CEO/CFO announcement twenty days before (after) the nearest earnings announcement. Zero relates to a CEO/CFO announcement released the same day as an earnings announcement. I include all CEO/CFO announcements which occur within 30 trading days of an earnings announcement. I obtain the dates of earnings announcements and CEO/CFO announcements from the Capital IQ key developments database (2001-2011). 49