Journal Research in Peace, Gender and Development (JRPGD) Vol. 3(6) pp. 90-98, August, 2013 DOI: http:/dx.doi.org/10.14303/jrpgd.2013.099 Available online http://www.interesjournals.org/ JRPGD Copyright © 2013 International Research Journals Review Beyond greed and grievance: the missing link in conflict management and peace building in Northern Ghana Seidu M. Alidu Lecturer, Department of Political Science, University of Ghana, P.O. Box LG 64, Accra, Ghana. Email:seidualidu@gmail.com, smalidu@ug.edu.gh Abstract Majority of conflicts across the world are explained using the greed and grievance theory. Specifically, the causes and repetitive escalation of conflicts in Northern Ghana is subsumed, albeit tacitly, into this broader analytical frame. Using mainly secondary data, this paper seeks to interrogate the greedgrievance theory and its implication for managing conflicts in Northern Ghana. It argues that the greedgrievance theory assumes an instrumentalist view of conflict that does not only miss its expressive dimension but tailors its resolution towards a win-lose outcome thereby making it difficult to manage when it fails. However, focusing only on the expressive dimension of conflict limits its resolution since it does not address the core issues at the heart of the problem but only provide practitioners the opportunity to examine psycho-social elements of the conflict. The paper concludes that managing conflicts in Northern Ghana requires an approach that examines both the subjective and objective dimensions of each conflict in order to achieve peace that is sustainable. Keywords: Conflicts in Northern Ghana, Greed and Grievance, Conflict Management, Peace building, Ethnic Conflicts INTRODUCTION Except for the pocket of ethnic and chieftaincy disputes that often manifest into destructive armed conflict, Ghana is deemed a peaceful country partly because it has managed (through the establishment of relatively free and fair democratic elections; by establishing national structures for dispute resolution including the National Peace Council and various Houses of Chief and the Commission on Human Rights and Administrative Justice) “...to avoid a total war in the Clausewitzian sense (Carl von Clausewitz explains “total war” as the complete mobilization of an entire society against another with the intention to annihilate the opponent). Yet, Ghana’s success in avoiding a Clausewitzian total war has not hide the numerous structural, direct and indirect violence that occur daily in specific societies within the larger state (Galtung (2000) developed the distinction between direct violence, structural violence and cultural violence. Whereas in direct violence people are shot to death, in structural violence people die as a result of hunger and preventable diseases. Cultural violence constitutes the justification for both direct and structural violence). There are proofs of violence built into social, cultural and economic structures across the country, including but not limited to cases of brutality from state security institutions at the least opportunity; outmoded cultural practices and the neglect of some of the fundamental rights of the people, including the right to accessible education and economic well-being. However, it is the elements of negative peace, rather than the examples of a positive peace enumerated above, that threaten the general security and wellbeing of the citizenry. (Johan Galtung (1996) distinguished between “negative” and “positive” peace. Whiles the former implies the absence of direct violence, the latter suggests re-building relationships destroyed by conflict, building and reforming institutions to respond to the needs of the people and resolving Alidu 91 conflictual differences in a constructive manner). Comprising intermittent chieftaincy and ethnic conflicts, the Ghanaian society is manifestly negatively peaceful. There is an estimated over one hundred chieftaincy and ethnic disputes across the country (Seini and Tsikata, 2004) with majority of those violently expressed present in the three Northern Regions. Fought mainly over land, identity and traditional power (Mahama, 2003; Brukum, 2001; Kendie, 2010) ethnic and chieftaincy conflicts in Northern Ghana are not only interrelated but also overlap one another (Jonsson, 2007) creating multi-dimensional consequences. Given that traditional rulers are custodians of development in their respective constituencies, problems inherent and/or associated to such institutions affect both the developmental ability and security of the people concerned. Majority of conflicts (civil wars in particular) across the world are explained using the “greed” and “grievance” theory (Collier and Hoeffler, 2000, 2004; Berdal and Malone, 2000; Keen, 2000, Keen and Berdal, 1997). Specifically, the causes and repetitive escalation of conflicts in Northern Ghana is subsumed, albeit tacitly, into this broader analytical frame (see Brukum, 2001, 2007; Mahama 2003; Kendie and Akudugu, 2010). “Using mainly secondary data source, this paper argues that the “greed-grievance” theory assumes an instrumentalist view (Analysis of conflicts in Northern Ghana that tend to focus exclusively on the objective dimension or actual causes) of conflict that does not only miss its expressive dimension (The expressive view is the opposite of the instrumental view and focuses on only the psycho-emotional aspects of conflicts much to the neglect of the actual grievance) but also tailors its resolution toward a win-lose outcome thereby making it difficult to manage when it fails”. On the other hand, focusing on only the expressive dimension of conflict limits its resolution since it does not address the core issues at the heart of the problem but only provide practitioners the opportunity to examine psycho-social elements of the conflict. This paper seeks to interrogate the “greed” and “grievance” theory and its implication for managing conflicts in Northern Ghana. It will argue that conflict resolution in Northern Ghana requires an approach that examines both the root causes of the conflict and the psycho-emotional issues associated to the conflict in a reinforcing and interdependent manner. Before doing this, the paper seeks to challenge two assumptions about conflicts in Northern Ghana that invariably affect the efforts to intervene or at least attempt to resolve them. The first assumption is that conflicts in Northern Ghana are characteristically tribal, ethnic or chieftaincy-related (Mahama, 2003; Kendie, 2010). Such labels assigned to conflicts in the North are unhelpful for resolving them. The second assumption, generally made by development practitioners, is that conflicts in Northern Ghana represent a breakdown of peace and development that necessarily mandate the restoration of normalcy (rather than the examination of the dynamics and the causes of the breakdown, if any). Such an assumption conceals the economic incentives of war and people who benefit from this anarchic situation. Having challenged these two assumptions, the rest of the paper will try to suggest alternative ways of examining conflicts in Northern Ghana and the role of the attitude of the conflicting parties in resolving them. I will argue that the attitude of parties to a conflict, besides the perceived economic benefits derived therein, have ramifications for its resolution. Conceptualizing Conflicts in Northern Ghana Known for its ethnic, cultural and sectarian diversity, conflicts in the three Northern regions are mostly labelled as ethnic fought purely on “ancient hatreds.” Indeed, ethnicity or identity politics has become a culprit of many wars fought across the length and breadth of Africa (Kaldor, 1999; Turton, 1997; Huntington, 1996) and increasingly been perceived as a source of stigma and discrimination (Castells, 1997). Ethnicity has been widely used to refer to the human need to belong, particularly but not exclusively, to a specific group of people, institutions or ideology (Turton, 1997). Such desire creates the tendency to identify and exclude others who do not belong to one’s group. Superficially, a person’s identity does not constitute conflictual behaviour unless it is been exploited based on genuine grievance. The primordialists hold the view that ethnic affiliations reflect a non-rational sentiment, which fosters powerful emotional attachments to collective identities. At the extreme, these attachments are expressed as the most fundamental, irrepressible tendency of human nature and could form the basis for conflict (Woodward, 1995). On the other hand, the relationalists perceive ethnicity as a reflection of voluntary allegiances and at times manipulated by logical, calculating individuals (including politicians that need political power or powerful countries that need to sell their weapons badly or exploit resources in the troubled country) to advance their interest relative to opportunities present in the environment. The power to start war easily on ethnic lines is not only due to the view that it is a natural property of a group (Eriksen, 1993) but also to the fact that it can be sustained, relative to other groupings, for a long period of time (Barth, 1969). Like the proverbial egg and chicken conundrum, conflicts are increasingly been perceived as highlighting ethnic sentiments more than ethnicity is seen as a cause of conflict. Ethnicity itself is not a sufficient explanation for 92 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. conflict but rather political power and economic resources that accrue from fighting one another. Though ethnic sentiments have the potency to motivate people to fight those perceived as not belonging to them, it is rather difficult to prove that such sentiments actually motivate people to engage in acts of war. In as much as the relationalists argument is criticized for its neglect of the history and emotional struggles of conflicts hurriedly labelled as ethnic, the premordialists conclusion that conflicts are often caused by the re-emergence of “ancient hatreds” diverts attention from the possibility that there is something modern about ethnicity and ethnic conflict (Keen, 2000). For example, the war in the former Yugoslavia that catapulted the “ancient hatred” phraseology was believed by many analysts to have originated from the disintegration of governmental authority and the breakdown of political and civil order in Yugoslavia following the politics of transforming a socialist society to a democratic market-led economy (Woodward, 1995). According to Woodward (1995), the failure of economic austerity measures and reforms required by a foreign debt crisis triggered a tilt towards political disintegration. This analysis fits into Elbadawi and Sambani’sl (2000) diagnosis of conflicts in Africa as owing much to poverty and heavy dependence on resource-based primary exports than ethno-linguistic fragmentation. Assigning ethnicity as a cause to contemporary conflicts support the idea that the parties involved in that conflict are moral equals, both fighting for irrational hatred and hence devaluing all those involved as irrational (Keen, 2000). This in itself is not a problem, but the problem however is that it legitimizes non-action from people outside the conflict zone. The view that the Yugoslav conflict was a revival of ancient ethnic hatred created an intervention fatigue for the world’s powers that responded to the call for help (Woodward, 1995; Keen, 2000). As Woodward noted, major powers that initiated and backed negotiations to end the conflict threw the ball into the court of feuding parties to find a solution, stressing that it was their war and of little interest to others. Increasingly, conflicts in Northern Ghana are seen as “northern wars” of little interest to Southerners or any part of the country for that matter. Even when government or nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) intervene, it is only restricted to humanitarian aid which does not solve the conflict problem. Labelling a conflict as ethnic, does not only deflates the value of the political and economic evaluation and processes involved (including state break down, institutional failure, beneficiaries in conflict, conflict as an extension of a policy) but also makes intervention unlikely exacerbating the conflict further. Another conception about conflicts in Northern Ghana is that it represents a breakdown of peace and generally retards development. Conflicts in general are perceived as anti-developmental and the three Northern Regions are often described as the poorest partly because of their penchant for fighting. Much of the thinking about conflicts during the period of the Cold War focuses on the dichotomy between “peace” and “war” with specific emphasis on war as a breakdown of “normal” or “peacetime” pattern of social, economic, political, and societal intercourse (Berdal and Malone, 2000). This dichotomy generally leads to the understanding of conflict as the collapse of an existing order of peace, development and prosperity (Keen, 2000) and giving way to chaos, backwardness and hardship (Duffield, 2000). However, to view conflicts as no more than costly disruption of development does not only conceal the degree to which other factors shape violence but also dismiss the benefits accrued from war. Certainly, both Collier (2000) and Reno (2000) argue that economic agenda are not only central to understanding contemporary conflicts but also become a tool for economic enterprise to many. Understood this way, we will be able to rationalize why people keep fighting or wanting to fight no matter how irrationally destructive it is. Undoubtedly, the history of economic motives in war is as old as warfare itself. Berdal and Malone (2000) wrote about the vast profit made by the Imperial Army of Wallenstein in the Thirty Years war in Germany, as well as the celebrated personal wealth of Napoleon’s war Generals. Recent cases in most countries across Africa including Sierra Leone, Liberia, and the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC) prove that such economic benefits, no matter how meagre, are not circumscribed to ancient times (Keen, 2000). Similarly, Mahama (2003) discusses how warriors in the Northern Region often revel spoils stolen from their enemies (including, but not limited to livestock), which are later sold and used to buy more weapons. Besides these general economic incentives, most individuals benefit at the personal level by assuming conflict-related positions such as spokespersons for warring factions, leaders of war committee and even custodians of war donations and funds. Such positions come with lucrative packages but on condition that the conflict is sustained. To such a category of people, transition to peace means unemployment and loss of attention (especially from the media) hitherto accorded to them. Keen (2000) therefore notes that seeing conflicts as a dramatic setback to development sends a perilous and, of course, an erroneous impression that conflict is a disaster for almost everyone concerned. Conflicts in Northern Ghana need to be explained as a situation that has functions as well as causes and effects. Just as Clausewitz (translated in Alidu 93 1989) defines war as the continuation of politics by other means, so should the causes of the problem of war not be detached from its functions. The analysis of conflicts in Northern Ghana as simply the breakdown of the regime of peace rather than the emergence of a new system of exploitation by a few, affects the attempt to resolve them. Contemporary conflicts, no matter the catastrophic dimensions they assume, serve different purpose to different category of people. The Greed and Grievance Debate The greed and grievance theory is one of the most commonly used theories to explain the causes of civil wars. It is a combination of economic and political science paradigms that utilise both economic opportunism and in-group hostility that generates from marginalization to explain the cause and perpetuation of civil wars (Collier and Hoeffler, 2000). The “greed” theory, derived mainly from economic view point, sums a rational choice paradigm that explains the causes of conflict as an absence of cooperation between feuding parties motivated to fight by financial opportunities derived from natural resources. Such resources form the basis for both operation-support and for personal enrichment. Technically speaking, the “greed” theory can be subsumed into the economic functions of war explained in the immediate paragraph before this one. However, unlike the case studies used in the pioneering study by Collier and Hoeffler, conflicts in Northern Ghana cannot be fully diagnosed as civil wars because the Government of Ghana is neither a party to it nor regular armies of the state been used. Further, except the limited gains made by few within the conflict zones and remittances sent from Northern diaspora living in Southern Ghana and beyond, there are generally no natural resources present in the North that could be used to fund the war and also motivate people to fight. Yet, the power of the few who benefit from conflicts in Northern Ghana including politicians, businessmen and members of royal gates, cannot be glossed over. This is therefore worth attention in the analysis of conflicts in the Northern Ghana. The “grievance” theory on the other hand, is rooted in behavioural paradigm, and reflects deeper social divisions and inequalities along ethnic, religious and political exclusion. The magnitude of these divisions and the consequences resulting from it, may fuel rebellion and violent resistance. Many of the conflicts fought in Northern Ghana are related to access and control of land more than ethnic and chieftaincy labels, though these two issues overlap. The traditional social structure in Northern Ghana is divided into chiefly tribes (such as the Dagombas, Gonjas, Nanumbas and Mamprusis) and the acephalous(such as the Konkombas, Nawuris, Basares and the Nchumurus, among others) (Hizkias, 2000). 2000). Unlike the acephalous societies, often seen as “migratory yam farmers,” the chiefly tribes have succeeded in organizing themselves around hereditary chieftaincy structures (Hizkias, 2000). Traditional land tenure practices in Northern Ghana do not recognize individual ownership of land. To a large extent, land is vested in paramount chiefs who in turn hold it in trust for their ethnic groups. This arrangement restricts land ownership to only chiefly tribes, a situation resented by most acephalous societies. Majority of the conflicts in Northern Ghana, far from being fought on the lines of ethnic identities, are demands by acephalous societies for the creation of their own paramountcies that can hold land in trust for them. This paper does not entirely dismiss ethnicity as a possible cause of conflicts in Northern Ghana but assumes that such labels do not only miss the fundamental grievances on which these conflicts are fought, but also discourage interventions aimed at a resolution. Notwithstanding its prominence and application, the greed and grievance theory has been widely criticized for reductively subsuming the cause of every civil war into the theory. It will be impossible to have all conflicts fought on the basis of the greed of conflicting parties given that the causes of conflicts differ across the world. It is therefore not only deleterious for successful conflict management but also oversimplifies the complexities inherent in the decision of people to go to war, if the source of all conflicts is limited to greed. Even though the grievance aspect of the theory is more compelling, it nonetheless defies the universal consensus that no single source could lead to all conflicts across the world. Every conflict is fought based on grievance – real or perceived – but the dynamics of the local environment, the culture and severity of the problem make all the difference. In a classical critique of the “greed and grievance” theory, Keen (2000) notes that Collier and Hoeffler in their pioneering study chose “dubious proxies” that do not only emphasise greed as the dominant source of conflict but indirectly gives prominence to economic variables to economic variables as major root causes thereby neglecting other more important disciplines including politics, anthropology and sociology. These critiques present a compelling case for the reexamination of the variety of dynamics across disciplines that explain sources of conflict. In the next section, this paper will examine the role of attitude and behaviour as a cause and solution to conflicts in Northern Ghana. Beyond Greed and Grievance: Peace Building in Northern Ghana As noted in the discussion at the beginning of this paper, 94 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. the manner a conflict is labelled has a wider implication for efforts towards its management and resolution. Focusing solely on the greed component of conflicts reductively limits its resolution to the decisions of the very few greedy ones who benefit from the war economy, thereby resulting in a win-lose situation. This is because when a single group controls the decision to make war and peace, as well as the resource needed to fund the war, other groups will be denied of everything. In the late 1960s, Galtung (1969) proposed an influential model for analysing the causes as well as the resolution of conflicts. Later revised in 1996, Galtung suggests that every conflict can be construed as a triangle involving contradictions, attitude and behaviour as its vertices. While contradiction refers to the underlying conflict situation between feuding parties, attitudes include emotive, cognitive and conative elements that sustain the conflict (Miall, et. al., 1999). Attitude includes the feuding parties’ perceptions and misperceptions of each other and of themselves (Woodhouse and Duffey, 2000). These perceptions may be positive or negative; however, in violent conflict feuding parties tend to develop increasingly negative stereotypes of the other and an increasingly positive self- group identity (Miall, et. al., 1999; Woodhouse and Duffy, 2000). Attitudes are often influenced by emotions such as fear, anger, bitterness and hatred. The third component of the triangle is behaviour, which comprises of signs suggesting conciliation or hostility of feuding parties. These actions are undertaken by any of the conflicting parties in a conflict aimed at the opposing party with the intention of making that party abandon or change its goals (Miall, et. al., 1999). In violent conflicts, behaviour is minimally exemplified by threats and coercion and at worst by destructive attacks. Even though all three components need to be present together in every full conflict, they may change over time or influence one another given the dynamics of the conflict concerned. These changes manifest into conflict as feuding parties’ interests clash. Hostile attitudes may lead to an intensified conflicts drawing in other parties and generating secondary conflicts (Woodhouse and Duffey, 2000). Such an expansive conflict may complicate efforts aimed at resolution and peace building. However, when it does happen, resolution will involve a set of dynamic, multidimensional and interdependent changes that could de-escalate the conflict behaviour, change the people’s attitude and transform the structures that give way to the conflict (Woodhouse and Duffey, 2000). Except the structure/contradiction (that involves the differences in goals or opinion) the other two vectors concern the character of the conflicting individuals. A conflict structure alone, (i.e., minus human traits of attitude and behaviour), is described by Galtung (1996) as latent or structural violence. Structural violence is rarely destructive as direct violence or more so cultural violence.( See footnote 3 at 1) Nonetheless, it constitutes the objective dimension of conflict and focus largely on the interests that are assumed to be in short supply. These may include land, food, water, societal position, power and recognition. Yet, neither the existence of this difference nor nursing an interest in them may lead to direct violence until the human components of attitude and behaviour set in. Both attitude and behaviour constitute the subjective dimension of conflict, which are psychologically and emotionally-based. They include fear, anger, anxiety, jealousy, mistrust, and other negative feelings. The subjective dimension of conflict usually clouds the objective one and inhibits rational communication about the objective issues. A comprehensive conflict resolution effort needs to pay equal attention to both the subjective and objective dimensions of conflicts. In the opposing greed and grievance theory, grievance refers to the objective dimensions of the conflict, thus, the actual issues at the heart of the problem. This may include claims to land, power and recognition; political and social alienation of minority ethnic groups and to a larger extent the fight for “freedom” and “self-rule.” In Northern Ghana, the acephalous tribes of Konkombas, Bimobas, Nawuris, and Nchumurus, among others have all referred to several grievances including the need for “self-rule” through an elevation to the status of a paramountcy and also the perceived oppression and dehumanization associated with been governed by another tribe. “In general, conflicts in Northern Ghana are fought over claims to land, traditional power and recognition of acephalous or minority ethnic groups from their majority or chiefly tribes. (N.J. Brukum (2001) divides tribes in Northern Region into paramouncty-based such as the Dagomba, Gonja, Nanumba and Mamprusis and non-paramountcy-based or acephalous tribes including the Konkomba, Nchumurus, Basari, Vagala, Bimoba, Nawuri, Tampluma, Komba, Chakosi, etc. among others. Similarly, Hizkias (2000) broadly categorize tribes in Northern Ghana into Chiefly and Acephalous tribes. The Chiefly tribes are Dagomba, Gonja, Mamprusi and Nanumba, while the acephalous tribes are referred to as “migratory yam farmers)”. Yet, there are several challenges in developing such an instrumentalist view of conflict in Northern Ghana partly because it may eventually lead to a win-lose situation or a total victory for one party over another. For example, elevating a chief from an acephalous tribe to Alidu 95 Structures/Contradictions Attitudes Behaviours Figure 1. Galtung’s Conflict Triangle Psychological and Emotional Issues subjective dimension Fear Anger Actual Issues Land, Power, Recognition Anxiety objective dimension Mistrust Figure 2. Representation of the Subjective and Objective Dimensions of Conflict the status of paramountcy implies giving away a chunk of the land you hold for your ethnic group to that tribe since the two go hand in hand. That will suggest a win by the acephalous tribe and a loss by the chiefly tribe. Yet, allowing acephalous tribes without paramountcy (and for that matter land) signifies a win by chiefly tribes and a loss by the acephalous tribe. The second problem in focusing on only the objective dimension is that it neglects the subjective component, which in actual fact is the main driver of violence. “Indeed, all previous attempts at resolving conflicts in Northern Ghana (including the Inter-NGO Consortium, the Permanent Negotiation Team, the Nairobi Peace Initiative, the Eminent Chiefs’ Committee and several other Commissions of Inquiries so far established) have glossed over the subjective component.” This paper therefore emphasises that before we can address the actual grievances of conflicts in Northern Ghana, we need to first of all address the subjective elements that cloud our understanding of the actual 96 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. Figure 3. Five Approaches to Conflict Source: Miall et. al., (1999). issues. For example, reaching a compromise to carve just a portion of Dagbon or Gonja lands to Konkombas for paramountcy will not much affect the status of the former nor will it undermine their national position as “superior” Northern tribes. However, have acephalous tribes like the Konkombas pursue their grievance with the right attitude and mechanism that would warrant chiefly tribes to grant them their wish? No matter how we examine conflicts and efforts towards their resolution, attitude and behaviour of conflicting parties are very essential. In reality, both the subjective and objective dimensions of conflict are interdependent and linked, and conflicts are therefore best understood when both levels of analysis are pursued and addressed in the resolution process. Nonetheless, this paper takes the position that addressing the subjective issues first, help improve the ways in which parties understand and behave towards each other. Miall et. al., (1999) argue that it is typical of conflicting parties to give high priority to their own interest than that of their enemies in any conflict situation. Using five approaches, they distinguished between the concern conflicting parties show for their interest and that of their enemies in a low to high continuum. While conflicting parties with high concern for their interest and low concern for their enemies interest are seen to be “contending” ; those with high concern for their enemies interests and low concern for theirs are seen to be “yielding.” An alternative approach is to avoid conflict completely by “withdrawing” or to balance the concern for one’s interests and that of the enemy through “problem solving.” In conflict resolution however, assuming a high concern for your interests and that of your enemies is the best-case scenario. Taking such a “compromise” position implies your strong desire to protect your interests and at the same time that of your perceived enemy. Figure three above represents these five conflicting approaches. CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS This paper has highlighted several essential issues, some of which are often dismissed as trivial in attempts at resolving conflicts in Northern Ghana. The first is the hasty prescription of all conflicts in Northern Ghana as ethnic or chieftaincy-driven fought purely on the hatred that people have long nurtured about themselves and of the other. These characteristic labels are unhelpful for resolving conflicts since it shifts the burden of intervention and management on the feuding factions and not neutral practitioners or experts. Also, reducing all conflicts in Northern Ghana to these labels conceal the actual grievance and motivation that drive people to take arms against each other and invariably affect the opportunity to deal with the exact causes of the conflict. Second, this paper proposes that to be able to resolve conflicts successfully in Northern Ghana we need to see them as the beginning of another process of life that benefit other people rather than a complete breakdown of the process of life and development. Many stand to benefit from various types of conflict situations, directly or indirectly, Alidu 97 and may do everything to sustain such instability than “risk” peace. Therefore viewing conflicts as purely bad and anti-developmental hide the benefits it provide to “peace saboteurs” who may stand on the way of peace. Notwithstanding these two important observations, it will be deleterious to confine the causes of conflict to a simple economic “greed” of a few. This paper has posited that though economic factors could form part of the grievances for waging war, much of such decisions have to do with the attitude of the feuding parties. Both the decisions to fight and to make peace are driven by our psycho-emotional attributes that at some point urge us to co-exist or resist. To be able to resolve conflicts successful in Northern Ghana, we first of all need to unmask the actual issues at the centre of the conflict by attending to the emotional and psychological issues that shield them. In doing this, we need to aim at changing both attitudes and behaviour so that they are no longer violent and hostile. But above all, we need to create disincentives for the desire to fight, and measures aimed at doing this are suggested below. First, the government of Ghana needs to address the issues of poverty and unemployment in the country in general and specifically in Northern Ghana that create the incentives for people to fight and benefit from the crime of war. Second, conflicts in Ghana and specifically Northern Region need to be depoliticized in order to delegitimize the tendency of politicians to incite wars and use it as a tool for political benefit. Third, there is a need for a deeper analysis of the causes, nature and dynamics of conflicts in Northern Ghana with the few to comprehend and solve them rather than hastily labelling them as ethnic or “tribal,” labels that hide the root causes of violence. Fourth, there is the need for people to build and nurture a culture of peace, tolerance and co-existence that have the tendency to promote peace. Lastly, there should be a critical attempt at revisiting laws on land ownership in Ghana with the view of either amending them or giving power to traditional councils in the three Northern Regions to enact new customary laws on land that could help solve these land-dominated conflicts. REFERENCES Barth F (1969). Ethnic Groups and Boundaries. London, UK: George Allen and Unwin. Berdal M, Malone DM (2000). Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Berdal M, Keen D (1997). “Violence and Economic Agendas in Civil Wars: Some Policy Implications for Outside Intervention.” Millennium: Journal of International Studies, 26:795-818. Brukum NJK (2001). The Guinea Fowl, Mango and Pito Wars: Episodes in the History of Northern Ghana, 1980 – 1999. Accra, Ghana: Ghana Universities Press. Brukum NJK (2007). “Chieftaincy and Ethnic Conflicts in the Northern Region of Ghana, 1980-2002” in Tonah S (2007) (ed.) Ethnicity, Conflicts and Consensus in Ghana, Accra: Woeli Publishing Services. Castells M (1997). The Power of Identities, Vol.2, Oxford: Blackwell. Clausewitz VC ( ). On War, Translated and Edited by Michael Howard and Peter Paret (1989), Princeton: Princeton University Press. Collier P (2000). “Doing Well out of War: an Economic Perspective” in Berdal, M., and Malone, D.M. (2000) (eds.) Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars, Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers, Inc, pp.91 – 112. Collier P, Hoeffler A (2002). “On the Incidence of Civil Wars in Africa” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(1):13-28. Collier P, Hoeffler A (2004). “Greed and Grievance in Civil Wars” Oxford Economic Papers, 56(4):563-595. Duffield M (2000). “Globalization, Transborder Trade, and War Economies” in Berdal M, Malone DM (2000). (eds.) Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, Inc, pp. 69 – 90. Elbadawi E, Sambanis N (2000). “Why Are There So Many Civil Wars in Africa? Understanding and Preventing Conflict,”Journal of Africa Economies, 9(3):244-269. Eriksen T (1993). Ethnicity and Nationalism: Anthropological Perspectives, London: Pluto Press. Galtung J (1969). “Violence, Peace and Peace Research” J. Peace Res. 6(3):167-191. Galtung J (1996). Peace by Peaceful Means: Peace and Conflict, Development and Civilization, Oslo: IPRI. Galtung J (2000). Searching for Peace: the Road to TRANSCEND, Background paper on Conflict Transformation, TRANSCEND, Booklet 2, April. Hizkias A (2000). “Co-existence and Reconciliation in the Northern Region of Ghana” in Reconciliation, Justice and Co-existence: Theory and Practice, Lexington Books: Maryland, pp. 166 – 167. Huntington SP (1998). The Clash of Civilisations and the Remaking of World Order, London: Touchstone. Jönsson J (2007). “The Overwhelming Minority: Traditional Leadership and Ethnic Conflict in Ghana’s Northern Region”, Centre for Research on Inequality, Human Security and Ethnicity Working Paper No. 30, February. Kaldor M (1999). New Wars and Old Wars: Organised Violence in a Global Era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Keen D (2000). ‘Incentives and Disincentives for Violence’ in Berdal M, Malone DM (2000) (eds.) Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Kendie SB, Akudugu MA (2010). “Application of Game Theory in the Management of Natural Resources Conflicts: the case of the Bongo District,” in Kendie, S. B. (ed.), Conflict Management and Peace Building for Poverty Reduction, Proceedings of the 2010 Harmattan School, Tamale: CCEIR. Kendie SB (2010). “Foreword”, in Kendie, S. B. (ed.), Conflict Management and Peace Building for Poverty Reduction, Proceedings of the 2010 Harmattan School, Tamale: CCEIR. Mahama I (2003). Ethnic Conflicts in Northern Ghana, Tamale: Cyber Systems. Ramsbotham O, Miall H, Woodhouse T (1999). Contemporary Conflict Resolution, Third Edition, Cambridge: Polity Press. Reno W (2000). “Shadow States and the Political Economy of Civil Wars,” in Berdal M, Malone DM (eds.) (2000). Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, Pp. 43 – 68. Tsikata D, Seini W (2004). ‘Identities, Inequalities and Conflicts in Ghana’ Centre for Research on Inequality, Human Security and Ethnicity (CRISE), Working Paper 5, Oxford, November. Turton D (1997). War and Ethnicity: Global Connections and Local Violence, New York; University of Rochester Press. Woodhouse T, Duffey T (2000). Peacekeeping and International Conflict Resolution, New York: UNITAR-POCI. 98 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. Woodward S (1995). Balkan Tragedy; Chaos and Dissolution after the Cold War, Brookings Institutions, Washington DC. How to cite this article: Alidu SM (2013). Beyond greed and grievance: the missing link in conflict management and peace building in Northern Ghana. J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. 3(6):90-98