DP RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-031 Productivity, Firm Size, Financial Factors, and Exporting Decisions: The case of Japanese SMEs OGAWA Kazuo Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University TOKUTSU Ichiro Graduate School of Business Administration, Kobe University The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/ RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-031 March 2015 Productivity, Firm Size, Financial Factors, and Exporting Decisions: The case of Japanese SMEs* OGAWA Kazuo Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University TOKUTSU Ichiro Graduate School of Business Administration, Kobe University Abstract This study is an empirical attempt to compare the exporting behavior of small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) with large firms from the viewpoints of export market participation decision (extensive margin) and export volume decision (intensive margin), using firm-level panel data. We find that firm size is an important determinant of both extensive margin and intensive margin decision for SMEs as well as large firms. In contrast, productivity affects only the intensive margin of export for both SMEs and large firms. Quantitatively, the contribution of productivity to export volume is much larger for large firms. Financial factors are also important determinants of export. Liquidity reserve has positive effects on the extensive margin of export for SMEs and large firms. Moreover, financial institutions play an important role in supporting the export activities of SMEs. Keywords: Export, Extensive margin, Intensive margin, Total factor productivity, Price-cost margin, Financial constraint, Firm size JEL classification: E44, F14, O30 RIETI Discussion Papers Series aims at widely disseminating research results in the form of professional papers, thereby stimulating lively discussion. The views expressed in the papers are solely those of the author(s), and neither represent those of the organization to which the author(s) belong(s) nor the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry. * This research is conducted as a part of the Project “Study on Corporate Finance and Firm Dynamics” undertaken at the Reserach Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). This research is financially supported by Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (#25285068) from the Japanese Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and Technology. The authors would like to thank Shin-ichiro Ono and Kazumi Suzuki for helpful comments and suggestions on data issues. The authors are also grateful to Masahisa Fujita, Shin-ichi Fukuta, Kaoru Hosono, Keiko Ito, Daisuke Miyakawa, Jun-ichi Nakamura, Hiroshi Ohashi, Etsuro Shioji, Iichiro Uesugi, Nobuyoshi Yamori and seminar participants at Development Bank of Japan and RIETI for extremely helpful comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the authors. 1. Introduction Japanese small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) export much less than large listed firms. Figure 1 compares the proportion of firms that engage in exporting activities between small and medium-sized manufactures and large counterparts in the period of 1995 to 2009. The SMEs in manufacturing sector are defined as the enterprises whose number of employees is less than 300 or equity capital is less than 300 million yen. 1 Around 60 % of large firms export during this period. On the other hand, the proportion of exporting SMEs is at most 28.2% in 2009 although it exhibits an increasing trend. Figure 2 shows the share of SMEs in terms of export values of the total manufacturing sector. The share of SMEs increases over time, but it still stands at 6.5% in 2009. Why do SMEs export less than large firms? Three factors have been pointed out. First, new exporters face significant start-up costs. For example, they set up an export department, make market research of overseas market, develop marketing channels, retool and redesign products for foreign customers. Most of these costs are sunk cost, so that only large firms cover sunk entry costs. Moreover, large firms also benefit from lower variable costs such as trading costs due to scale economy. Large firms can attain lower trading costs due to bulk shipping and extensive overseas network. Thus large firms have cost advantage in export activities. 2 Second, it is well established that productivity is one of the driving engines of export. 3 Positive relationship between productivity and export has been found in many countries since the seminal work of Bernard and Jensen (1995). 4 Heterogeneity in firm productivity can explain why not all firms engage in exporting activities. As large firms have higher productivity than SMEs, SMEs export less than large firms. Third, large firms have advantage in financing export activities. It is because asymmetry in information between lenders and borrowers is less severe for large firms. Therefore large firms face lower costs in raising trade finance than SMEs. 5 1 The definition of SMEs comes from Small and Medium Enterprises Basic Act. Wagner (1995, 2001) emphasizes the importance of firm size in exports. 3 For example, see Roberts and Tybout (1997), Bernard et al. (2003), Melitz (2003) and Greenaway and Kneller (2007). 4 For example, positive relationship between productivity and export has been found in US by Bernard and Jensen(1995,1999,2004a,2004b) and Bernard et al.(2007), in Canada by Baldwin and Gu(2003), in European countries by Bernard and Wagner(2001) and Mayer and Ottaviano(2007), in Colombia, Mexico and Morocco by Clerides, Lach and Tybout(1998), in Asian countries by Aw, Chung and Roberts(2000) and Hallward-Driemeier et al.(2002) and in Japan by Kimura and Kiyota(2006), Tomiura(2007), Wakasugi, Ito and Tomiura(2008), Todo(2011) and Yashiro and Hirano(2010). 5 See, for example, Chaney (2005), Amiti and Weinstein (2011) and Manova (2013) for the 2 2 The importance of three factors in comparing the exporting behavior of large firms with that of SMEs has been well documented, but there are few attempts to evaluate quantitatively the relative importance of three factors in exporting activities of SMEs and large firms. The purpose of this study is to compare quantitatively the relative importance of three factors: firm size, productivity and financial factors in exporting activities between SMEs and large firms, using firm-level data in Japan. We use Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities (BSJBSA) collected by the Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry. The virtue of this survey is to include SMEs as well as large firms. In fact this survey covers enterprises with 50 or more employees and whose equity capital is over 30 million yen. The proportion of SMEs in this survey is 83% in 2009. We focus on firms in the four leading exporting industries: general machinery, electrical machinery, transport equipment and precision instrument. 6 The sample period covers from 1995 to 2009. This period includes decade-long stagnation in 1990s, the recovery phase of the Japanese economy from “lost decade” in 2000s and global financial crisis triggered by the massive non-performing subprime loans. The main feature of this study is to compare the exporting behavior of SMEs with that of large firms from two aspects. First, we examine the determinants of whether a firm exports or not (extensive margin). Second, we examine the determinants of export volume (intensive margin). Two equations corresponding to extensive margin and intensive margin decisions are consistently derived from firms’ profit maximizing behavior. Let us preview our main findings. We find that both firm size and financial factors are important determinants of extensive margin for both SMEs and large firms. However, marginal effects of firm size on export market participation decision are large for SMEs. Surprisingly, the profitability of export, measured by the ratio of export price to unit production cost (price-cost margin), has no effects on extensive margin of export. Price-cost margin as well as firm size is an important determinant of intensive margin of export. In addition, lending attitude of financial institutions, a proxy of financial factors, has a positive effect on exports of SMEs and world income has a positive effect on exports of large firms. Decomposing the contribution of each factor to representative firm’s exports during 1999 to 2007, we find that the contribution of firm size to export is quite large for both SMEs and large firms. The contribution of productivity to export volume is as large as that of firm size for large exporters, but the contribution of productivity to export volume is relatively small for SMEs. On the other hand, the importance of credit constraints in international trade. 6 The average export share by these four industries in BSJBSA amounts to 83% during 1995-2009. 3 contribution of lending attitude of financial institutions to export is relatively large for small and medium-sized exporters, although it is small for large exporters. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we characterize the exporting behavior of a firm in partial equilibrium context. We describe our dataset and present some descriptive statistics in Section 3. Section 4 shows our empirical results. Section 5 compares quantitatively the relative contribution of each determinant to export volume between SMEs and large firms. The last section concludes. 2. Characterization of Firm-level Exporting Behavior 2.1 Basic Model of Exporting Behavior We construct a market equilibrium model of firms that sell their products in both domestic and overseas markets. Our model is in line with the recent trade theory developed by Melitz(2003), Melitz and Ottaviano(2008) and Bernard et al.(2003) that stresses firm heterogeneity. Consider a profit-maximizing firm that sells its product in both domestic and overseas markets. The firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve in domestic and overseas market, respectively. We assume that there are N firms in the market. Downward-sloping demand curve in overseas market is given by π −π ππΈ = πΈ οΏ½πππΈ οΏ½ π€ (1) where ππΈ : demand for exports ππΈ : export price on a yen basis ππ€ : world price on a dollar basis π : exchange rate (yen per dollar) π : price elasticity of overseas demand and πΈ : factors that shift export demand The inverse demand curve is expressed as − ππΈ = πππ π΅ππΈ 1 π (2) 1 where B = πΈ π Similarly, Downward-sloping demand curve in domestic market and the inverse domestic demand curve are given by eqs.(3) and (4), respectively. 4 ππ· = π»ππ·−π (3) where ππ· :domestic demand ππ· :domestic price π: price elasticity of domestic demand and π»:factors that shift domestic demand − ππ· = π½ππ· 1 π (4) 1 where J = π» π The i-th firm maximizes its profit, defined by (5), with respect to overseas sales (πππ ) and domestic sales (πππ ). π = ππΈ πππ + ππ· πππ − πΆπ (ππ , cπ , π€π , πππ )(πππ + πππ ) − π(π΄π )πππ − πΉπ where ππΈ = πππ π΅(∑π π=1 πππ ) − 1 π , (5) 1 − π ππ· = π½(∑π π=1 πππ ) πΆπ (ππ , ππ , π€π , πππ ):unit cost function with ππΆπ πππ ππΆ ππΆ ππΆ < 0, ππ π > 0, ππ€π > 0, ππ π > 0, π π ππ ππ : total factor productivity (TFP) ππ : rental cost of capital π€π : wage rate πππ : material price π(π΄π ): unit trading cost with π′(π΄π ) < 0 π΄π : total assets and πΉπ : start-up cost of export It is assumed that production technology is linearly homogeneous, so that the unit cost function does not depend on the level of output. The trading cost includes tariff and transportation cost. We assume that the unit trading cost is a decreasing function of firm size, measured by total assets. 7 We assume that a firm pays fixed cost πΉπ to start up export. 7 Forslid and Okubo(2011) find that the unit trading cost is a decreasing function of firm size due to scale economy. 5 Extensive Margin Export Decision A firm exports if current revenue is greater than cost or ππΈ πππ − πΆπ (ππ , ππ , π€π , πππ )πππ − π(π΄π )πππ − πΉπ > 0 (6) This inequality is written as π πΈ οΏ½πΆ (π ,π ,π€ ,π π π π π ππ πΉ − 1οΏ½ πΆπ (ππ , ππ , π€π , πππ ) − π(π΄π ) − π π > 0 ) ππ In other words, a firm is more likely to export when the price-cost margin (PCM), ππΈ , is higher and firm size is larger. Large firms attain lower unit trading cost, πΆπ (ππ ,ππ ,π€π ,πππ ) πΉ π(π΄π ) and fixed cost per export, π π as export amount and total assets are positively ππ correlated. Existence of sunk costs generates hysteresis in export markets. Once a firm enters the export market by paying fixed cost, the firm is more likely to stay in the export market. To sum up, start-up decision of export depends on firm size, measured by total assets, price-cost margin and the firm’s status in the export market in the previous period. We employ a binary response model to specify the export market participation decision described above. Let us define a latent variable ππ∗ as (7) ππ∗ = ποΏ½π΄π,−1 , ππππ,−1 , ππ,−1 , ππ οΏ½ where ππππ−1 : price-cost margin in the previous year ππ,−1=1 if a firm exported in the previous year and 0 otherwise We observe ππ : disturbance term 1 ππ ππ∗ > 0 ππ = οΏ½ 0 ππ ππ∗ ≤ 0 Intensive Margin Export Decision The first order condition of export volume and domestic sales is given by (8) for all π = 1,2, β― , π. 1 − −1 π π 1 π΅π΅ππ οΏ½− οΏ½ οΏ½οΏ½ πππ οΏ½ πππ + ππΈ − πΆπ (ππ , ππ , π€π , πππ ) − π(π΄π ) = 0 π π=1 6 (8) 1 − −1 π π 1 ππ· οΏ½− οΏ½ οΏ½οΏ½ πππ οΏ½ πππ + ππ· − πΆπ (ππ , ππ , π€π , πππ ) = 0 π π=1 (π = 1,2, β― , π) Using the total export demand and domestic demand, eq.(8) is re-written as follows. 1 πππ ππΈ οΏ½− οΏ½ + ππΈ = πΆπ (ππ , ππ , π€π , πππ ) + π(π΄π ) π ππΈ 1 π (9) ππ· οΏ½− οΏ½ ππ + ππ· = πΆπ (ππ , ππ , π€π , πππ ) π π π· Thus the i-th firm’s share in total export and domestic sales is given by eq.(10). πππ ππΈ = π οΏ½1 − πππ π· πΆπ (ππ ,ππ ,π€π ,πππ ) = π οΏ½1 − ππΈ − π(π΄π ) ππΈ οΏ½ (10) πΆπ (ππ ,ππ ,π€π ,πππ ) π· οΏ½ The i-th firm’s share in total export depends upon the price-cost margin and real unit trading cost. The firm with higher price-cost margin may attain higher share of export. The price-cost margin is an increasing function of TFP and a decreasing function of wage rate, rental price of capital and material price, so that the firm’s export share increases when the firm raises its TFP and faces lower input prices. The firm may also increase its export share by lowering real unit trading cost. Larger firm may increase its export share since it faces lower trading cost due to scale economy. From eq.(10) the export function is written as πππ = π οΏ½ππΈ , πΆπ (ππ ,ππ ,π€π ,πππ ) π(π΄π ) , οΏ½ ππΈ ππΈ 7 (11) Note that ππΈ is a function of real exchange rate ππΈ πππ and shift factors E of export demand function, as is given by (1). An important ingredient of shift parameter is world income. To sum up, the export function is expressed as πππ = π οΏ½π¦π , ππΈ πππ , πΆπ (ππ ,ππ ,π€π ,πππ ) where π¦π : world income ππΈ , π΄π οΏ½ (12) This is the basis export volume equation to be estimated. 2.2 Equilibrium Export Price Aggregating the first order condition of export given by eq.(9) across firms, we obtain the following equation. π π 1 ∑π π=1 πππ ππΈ οΏ½− οΏ½ + ππΈ π = οΏ½ πΆπ (ππ , ππ , π€π , πππ ) + οΏ½ π(π΄π ) ππΈ π π=1 π=1 (13) Using the market clearing condition ∑π π=1 πππ = ππΈ , we can solve eq.(13) in terms of as ππΈ = ∑π 1 π=1 πΆπ (ππ ,ππ ,π€π ,πππ ) οΏ½ 1 1− οΏ½ππ π + ∑π π=1 π(π΄π ) π οΏ½ (14) Yen-denominated export price is therefore described as a function of the average unit cost and unit trading cost multiplied by the mark-up ratio. A rise in TFP will lower Japanese export price relative to world price and hence increases overseas demand for Japanese exports. 2.3 Role of Financial Factors in Exporting It is implicitly assumed that exporters do not face liquidity constraints in characterizing the firms’ exporting behavior above. However exporters might face higher effective borrowing rate with external finance premium added on when capital market is imperfect. This is especially so for SMEs since the SMEs have less financial assets and have limited access to capital market. Recent empirical studies find that exporters might be liquidity-constrained. Amiti and Weinstein (2011) demonstrate that 8 trade finance provided by the financial institutions played an important role in exporting behavior of Japanese listed firms. They show that bank health was important in providing trade finance with exporters and hence contributed to export increase. 8 We extend both firms’ export market participation decision and intensive margin export function by including the firm health and bank health variables. As for the firm health variable, we use the liquidity ratio, defined as the current assets less current liabilities over total assets. We use as a proxy of bank health the lending attitude diffusion index (DI) of financial institutions that measures easiness of providing external finance with exporters. Lending attitude DI is defined as the difference between the proportion of the firms feeling the lending attitude to be accommodative and that of the firms feeling the lending attitude to be severe. The larger the lending attitude DI, the healthier the banks are since healthier banks can supply more credit to their customers. The extended export market participation decision is specified as 1 ππ ππ∗ > 0 ππ = οΏ½ 0 ππ ππ∗ ≤ 0 where ππ∗ = ποΏ½π΄π,−1 , ππππ,−1 , πΏπΏπΏπΏπ,−1 , πΏπΏπΏπΏπ , ππ,−1 , ππ οΏ½ πΏπΏπΏπΏπ,−1: liquidity ratio in the previous year (15) πΏπΏπΏπΏπ : lending attitude DI of financial institutions The extended intensive margin export function is written as ππΈ,π = π οΏ½π¦πΈ , οΏ½ ππΈ οΏ½ , πππ€ π πΆπ (ππ ,ππ ,π€π ,ππ ) ππΈ , π΄π,−1 , πΏπΏπΏπ,−1 , πΏπΏπΏπΏοΏ½ (16) 3. Data Description This section describes the data sources and the procedures to construct variables used in empirical analysis. We also overview the characteristics of Japanese exporters during the sample period. 3.1 Data Construction 8 A number of researchers have examined the role of trade finance or external finance in exporting behavior. For example, see Kletzer and Bardhan(1987), Ronci(2005), Muûls(2008), Bricogne et al.(2012), Iacovone and Zavacka(2009), Feenstra et al. (2014), Haddad et al. (2010), Levchenko et al. (2010), Chor and Manova(2012) and Manova et al.(2011). 9 Three key variables in this study are: total factor productivity, price-cost margins, and real exports. This section describes how these variables are constructed. We provide detailed explanations about the data sources and the method to construct variables in Data Appendix. Our analysis focuses on the machinery-manufacturing firms since these firms play a major role in exporting activities. The data for individual corporations are all from BSJBSA in the period of 1995 to 2009. The first variable, total factor productivity for firm i in period t, πππ , is constructed by using the multilateral productivity index number developed by Caves et al. (1982) as follows. π 1 οΏ½οΏ½π₯π₯ οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ οΏ½ln ππππ − οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ lnπππ = οΏ½ln πππ − οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ ln ππ‘ οΏ½ − οΏ½οΏ½ππππ + π ln ππ₯π₯ οΏ½, π‘ = 1 2 π=1 π 1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ οΏ½ln ππππ − οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ ln ππ‘ οΏ½ − οΏ½οΏ½ππππ + οΏ½ποΏ½π₯π₯ ln ππ₯π₯ οΏ½ lnπππ = οΏ½ln πππ − οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ 2 π=1 π‘ π‘ π =2 π =2 π 1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ + οΏ½οΏ½ln ππ − οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½ ln ππ −1 οΏ½ − οΏ½ οΏ½οΏ½π π₯π₯ + ππ₯,π −1 οΏ½ οΏ½ln ππ₯,π − ln ππ₯,π −1 οΏ½, π‘ > 1, 2 π=1 where Y it is the real output of firm i in period t, X ijt is the input j of firm i in period t, S ijt is the cost share of input j of firm i in period t, and the variables with bar (-) and without subscript i indicate that they are industrial average. The first and second terms of the right-hand side is the discrepancy of log of output and factor input of firm i in period t from those of the hypothetical and representative firm of the corresponding industry in the corresponding period. The third and fourth terms are the accumulated value of the period-to-period change of the log of T of the representative firm. That is to say, the index indicates the log of T relative to the hypothetical and representative firm of the corresponding industry in the period 1 (base year). This is why the index has no first and second term for the period 1. The hypothetical and representative firm is defined as that with the arithmetic averages of cost shares and geometric averages of output and inputs of the sample firms of the corresponding industry in the corresponding period. It is clear that log of T of the representative firm is 0 in the period t. The second variable, the price-cost margin, is calculated as the value of output divided by the total cost, where the total cost (TC) is the sum of labor, material, 10 and capital cost: 9 ππ = π€π€ + ππ + ππ π where w: wage rate L: labor input c: rental price of capital K: capital stock ππ : intermediate input price M: intermediate input The cost shares, SK, SL, and SM, used in constructing TFP is obtained by dividing each factor cost by the total cost. Finally, our third key variable, real exports, is obtained by deflating the value of exports (pEQE) by the price index of exports (pE). 3.2 Descriptive Statistics of Exporters Table 1 shows the sample median of major variables in the manufacturing sector for four types of firms: large exporters, large non-exporters, small and medium-sized exporters and small and medium-sized non-exporters. Firm size is largest for large exporters, second largest for large non-exporters, third largest for small and medium-sized exporters and smallest for small and medium-sized non-exporters, whatever measure is used for firm size: number of employees, real sales or total assets. The large exporters attain best performance in price-cost margin, sales growth rate, ratio of R&D investment to sales, growth rate of total assets, while small and medium-sized exporters ranks second in all these performance measures and small and medium-sized non-exporters ranks last. As for the financial variables, the liquidity ratio is largest for small and medium-sized exporters and second largest for large exporters. Debt-asset ratio is largest for small and medium-sized non-exporters and smallest for large exporters. Figure 3 compares dynamic firm performance among four types of firms in the manufacturing sector. Continuous exporter in year t is defined as the firm that has exported for four consecutive years in year t. New exporter in year t is defined as the 9 The value of output and total cost in calculating the price-cost margin includes both overseas and domestic values since separate figures for overseas and domestic sales and costs are unavailable. Our procedure might be justified by the linear homogenous production technology. 11 firm that has not exported for three consecutive years prior to year t and started export in year t. Exit exporter in year t is defined as the firm that exits from export markets in year t, although it exported for three consecutive years prior to year t. Continuous non-exporter in year t is defined as the firm that has not exported for four consecutive years in year t. Figure 3 depicts the average of the same variables used in Table 1 for four types of firms defined above over the past three years and future three years during 1997 To 2009. Firm size is largest for continuous exporters, second largest for exit exporters, third largest for new exporters and smallest for continuous non-exporters, whatever measure is used for firm size: number of employees, real sales or total assets. 10 We observe the same rank order for the ratio of R&D investment to sales and liquidity ratio. One exception is the price-cost margin. The price-cost margin of continuous exporters is highest, but the price-cost margin of new exporters exceeds that of exit exporters in year t when new exporters start exporting. The price-cost margin of new exporters rises faster than exit exporters prior to start-up years. We test the null hypothesis that the mean of the variables is the same across four types of firms for each year by multi-way analysis of variance. Table 2 shows the test statistics of analysis of variance and the null hypothesis is decisively rejected for all the variables and years. 11 Table 3 compares the average growth rate of employment, real sales and total assets over the past three years and the future three years across four types of firms defined above. The average growth rate of employment, real sales and total assets over the past three years is highest for new exporters and lowest for exit exporters. Moreover the null hypothesis that the mean growth rate is the same across four types of firms is decisively rejected, as is shown in Table 2. However, there is no statistical difference in the mean growth rate of real sales and total assets over the future three years. In the subsequent section we examine the firms’ exporting behavior empirically, using the panel data of firms in four leading export industries: general machinery, electrical machinery, transport equipment and precision instrument. Therefore we show some descriptive statistics characterizing the firms in these industries. Table 4 shows the proportion of exporting firms in these four industries by firm size. More than 80% of large firms export in general machinery (83.5%) and precision instrument (87.8%). The proportion of small and medium-sized exporters is also high. In particular, the proportion of SME exporting firms is 53.0% and 43.2% for precision instrument and general machinery, respectively. Figure 4 shows the median of price-cost margin during 1996 to 2009 for four types of firms: large exporters, large non-exporters, small and 10 11 In Table 4 the firm size of continuous non-exporter is normalized as unity in year t. See the row of export status in Table 2. 12 medium-sized exporters and small and medium-sized non-exporters by industry. The price-cost margin is largest for large exporters and smallest for small and medium-sized non-exporters in all the four industries but general machinery. The price-cost margin exhibits an increasing trend in the 2000s and reaches its peak in 2006. It falls sharply thereafter, reflecting the aftermath of global financial crisis. Figure 5 shows the median of log of TFP during 1996 to 2009 for four types of firms by industry. Large exporters have the highest TFP in the 2000s for all the industries, followed by large non-exporters. Small and medium-sized non-exporters have lowest TFP. The log of TFP of each industry turns to a stable increasing trend around 2001 to 2002 except for transport equipment, where the log of TFP takes a U-shaped path in the 2000s. 4. Estimation Results and Implications 4.1 Determinants of Extensive Margin of Export We first examine the determinants of export market participation by estimating a binary response model specified in Section 2 by employing random probit model. The estimation results (marginal effects) of SMEs and large firms are presented in columns (1) to (3) and columns (4) to (6) of Table 5a, respectively. The dependent variable takes unity when a firm exports in year t and zero otherwise. The columns (1) for SMEs and (4) for large firms show the results of basic static model where the explanatory variables are logarithm of lagged total assets, lagged price-cost margin and two financial variables: lagged liquidity ratio and lending attitude of financial institutions. We modify the basic specification in two directions. First, we replace lending attitude of financial institutions by year dummies. Note that lending attitude is not a firm-specific variable since it takes common value for the firms in the same size group of the same industry. The estimation results are shown in the columns (2) for SMEs and (5) for large firms of Table 5a. Second, we modify the lag structure of price-cost margin. It takes a good amount of time to prepare for entering export market since the firm sets up an export department, make overseas market research, develop marketing channels, retool and redesign products for foreign customers before the firm starts exporting. Therefore we use the average price-cost margin over the past three years instead of one-year lagged value. The estimation results are shown in the columns (3) for SMEs and (6) for large firms of Table 5a. The estimation results are now in order. Firm size has significantly positive effects on participation decision of SMEs in all four industries, irrespective of specification. Liquidity ratio has also significantly positive effects on participation decision of SMEs 13 in all four industries but electrical machinery, irrespective of specification. Lending attitude of financial institutions has significantly positive effects on participation decision of SMEs only in general machinery and transport equipment. Price-cost margin does not have significantly positive effects on participation decision of SMEs in any industries, irrespective of specification. As for the large firms, we cannot find any explanatory variables that are statistically significant across specifications. Now we turn to the dynamic specification of export market participation decision. The estimation results are shown in Table 5b. In the dynamic specification hysteresis in export market is taken into consideration. The estimation results are improved to a large extent by including the firm’s lagged status in export market. 12 The coefficient estimate of lagged status in export market is significantly positive for all industries except for large firms in precision instrument, irrespective of firm size and specification. This indicates the importance of fixed costs in entering export market. Firm size exerts a significantly positive effect on export market participation decision for all industries except for large firms in general machinery and precision instrument, irrespective of firm size and specification Comparing the magnitude of the coefficient estimates of firm size between SMEs and large firms, they are larger for SMEs. Therefore firm size is much more important for SMEs in export market entry decision. Liquidity ratio is an important determinant for export market participation for both SMEs and large firms in all industries except precision instrument. On the other hand, the coefficient estimate of lending attitude of financial institutions is significantly positive only for SMEs in general machinery. It should be noted that the price-cost margin does not have significantly positive effects on participation decision of SMEs or large firms in any industries, irrespective of specification. This implies that productivity, by way of price-cost margin, does not affect the export market participation decision. 4.2 Determinants of Intensive Margin of Export We estimate the intensive margin export function derived in Section 2 under two specifications. We have six explanatory variables in the first specification. They are price-cost margin, world income, real exchange rate, lagged total assets and two financial factors: liquidity ratio and lending attitude of financial institutions. The basic export function to be estimated is given by 12 Most of the explanatory variables are still insignificant for large firms in precision instrument. This is possibly due to the paucity of the firms that do not export. In fact we have only 105 observations that do not export for the whole sample period. 14 π log(ππΈ )ππ = πΌ0 + πΌ1 πππ(πππ)ππ + πΌ2 πππ(π¦πΈ )π‘ + πΌ3 πππ οΏ½πππΈ οΏ½ + πΌ4 πππ(π΄)π,π‘−1 + πΌ5 πππ(πΏπΏπΏπΏ)π,π‘−1 + πΌ6 πΏπΏπΏπΏπ‘ + ππ + π’ππ π€ π‘ (17) where ππ : firm-specific term and π’ππ : disturbance term World income, real exchange rate and lending attitude are industry-specific and we do not include year dummies as explanatory variables in eq.(17). In the second specification we replace lending attitude of financial institutions by year dummies to see the robustness of the effects of price-cost margin, firm size and liquidity ratio on export. We take the endogeneity of price-cost margin into consideration explicitly in estimating export function. Price-cost margin is one of the important determinants of export in our model. However, the price-cost margin variable is constructed only from the information contained in balance sheet and profit-and-loss statements of firms. Thus unobservable important information such as the values of overseas network is not reflected on our price-cost margin variable. Then the observable price-cost margin might include measurement errors. Straight application of conventional panel regression might yield downward bias of the estimates. In this case the instrumental variable (IV) estimator is a legitimate procedure to allow for endogeneity. Candidates for instrument are ingredients of cost function; which are log of input prices (real wage, real capital cost), TFP, debt-asset ratio and year dummy variables, as will be explained in the next section. The preliminary estimation, however, reveals that if we adopt all the explanatory variables in the cost function as instruments, the Sargan test decisively rejected the overidentification restrictions, so that we use only part of the instruments that do not violate the overidentification restrictions. Therefore, we use the log of TFP and lagged debt-asset ratio as valid instruments for price-cost margin that do not violate the overidentification restrictions. The Hausman specification test is applied for selection between fixed-effect model and random-effect model. The estimation results of SMEs and large firms are presented in Table 6a for simple panel estimation and Table 6b for panel IV estimation. In both tables columns (1) and (2) correspond to SMEs, while columns (3) and (4) to large firms. Firm size has a significantly positive effect on export volume of both SMEs and large firms, irrespective of industry and estimation method. Contrary to the estimation results of export market participation decision, price-cost margin exerts a significantly positive 15 effect on export volume of both SMEs and large firms, irrespective of industry and estimation method. Moreover, the IV estimates are much larger than those of simple panel regression, suggesting that the price-cost margin is indeed endogenous. Our finding of positive relationship between price-cost margin and export is consistent with De Loecker and Warzynski (2012). They find that exporters have on average higher markups for Slovenian firms. Comparing the coefficient estimates of price-cost margin between SMEs and large firms, price-cost margin has much larger effect on export volume of large firms. This implies that large firms are more sensitive to profitability in export markets. As for the effects of financial factors on export volume, lending attitude of financial institutions is a significant determinant of export volume for both SMEs and large firms. The estimated coefficient of lending attitude of financial institutions is significantly positive in all four industries for SMEs under IV regression, while it is significantly positive only in general machinery and electrical machinery for large firms. Our finding is consistent with Amiti and Weinstein (2001) finding that trade finance provided by the financial institutions affects exports of Japanese firms. World income is also an important determinant of export of large firms. It exerts a significantly positive effect on export volume of large firms in all four industries, irrespective of estimation method. 5. Role of Productivity, Firm Size and Financial Factors in Exporting: Quantitative Evaluation In this section we calculate the extent to which each determinant of intensive margin of export contributed to export surge in the 2000s. In so doing we make a quantitative comparison of the relative importance of productivity, firm size and financial factors in expanding export volume between SMES and large firms during 1999 to 2007 when export surged. 5.1 Price-Cost Margin Equation The price-cost margin equation is important since it is used for evaluating quantitatively the contribution of TFP and other determinants of the cost function to export volume. The price-cost margin equation to be estimated is written as Log(πππ)ππ = π½0 + π½1 πππ οΏ½π€οΏ½π οΏ½ + π½2 πππ οΏ½ποΏ½π οΏ½ + π½3 πππ(π)ππ + πΈ ππ πΈ ππ π½4 πππ(π·π·π·π·)π,π‘ + ∑πΎ π=1 π½5π π·π·ππ + ππ + π’ππ 16 (18) Where π·π·π·π·ππ : debt-asset ratio π·π·ππ : year dummies (π = 1996, β― ,2009) ππ : firm-specific term π’ππ : disturbance term We add the debt-asset ratio and year dummies to the list of explanatory variables. Note that the material price is common to all the firms in the sample, so that it is subsumed into the year dummies. Equation (18) is estimated using the sample of exporting firms. The estimation results of SMEs and large firms are presented in columns (1) and (2) of Table 7, respectively. The coefficient estimates of factor prices are all significantly negative, irrespective of industry and firm size. There is no discernible difference in the magnitude of coefficient estimates across firm size in the same industry. The TFP variable has a significantly positive effect on the price-cost margin, irrespective of industry and firm size. One-percent rise in TFP increases the price-cost margin by 0.778 % (SMEs in transportation equipment) to 0.967% (SMEs in precision instrument). 5.2 Quantitative Evaluation of Export Determinants: Productivity, Firm Size and Financial Factors Now we calculate the contribution of each determinant of export volume: firm size, two financial factors, world demand, real exchange rate and components of price-cost margin: wage rate, rental price of capital and TFP to export variations during 1999 to 2007. We use the estimates of the intensive margin export function as well as those of the price-cost margin equation. The contribution of firm size to export is the proportion of the rate of change in total assets that explains the rate of change in export. πΌ4 οΏ½πππ(π΄)π,π‘+π−1 −πππ(π΄)π,π‘−1 οΏ½ πππ(ππΈ )π,π‘+π −πππ(ππΈ )ππ (19) Similarly, the contribution of world income, real exchange rate and lending attitude of financial institutions to export is calculated, using the corresponding coefficient estimates of the intensive margin export equation. The contribution of each component of the price-cost margin can be also obtained by using the coefficient estimates of the intensive margin export function and the price-cost function. For example, the contribution of TFP to export is given by 17 πΌ1 π½3 οΏ½πππ(π)π,π‘+π −πππ(π)ππ οΏ½ πππ(ππΈ )π,π‘+π −πππ(ππΈ )ππ (20) The contribution of the variables to export is calculated during 1999 to 2007 for all the firms that existed during this period. The first panel of Table 8 shows the median of the frequency distribution of the contribution of each variable across firms. We use the IV coefficient estimates of the intensive margin export function where world income, real exchange rate and lending attitude of financial institutions are explicitly taken into consideration. There is a large difference in the relative contribution of export determinants to export volume between SMEs and large firms. The contribution of firm size to export is sizable for large firms in electrical machinery (56.2%), transport equipment (54.7%) and precision instrument (41.3%). The contribution of TFP to export is also large for large firms. TFP can explain 19.8%, 28.7% and 35.5% of the total variations of export volume in general machinery, electrical machinery and precision instrument, respectively. The contribution of firm size to export is also large for SMEs. The contribution of firm size to export is 30.7%, 15.4% and 34.0% in electrical machinery, transport equipment and precision instrument, respectively. In contrast, the contribution of TFP is much smaller for SMEs. The contribution of TFP to export is large for SMEs in electrical machinery (17.3%), but the contribution of TFP is much smaller in other industries. 13 Financial factors, especially lending attitude of financial institutions, play more important role in expanding export activities of SMEs. The contribution of lending attitude of financial institutions is large in general machinery (17.0%) and moderately large in other industries, ranging from 5.4% in precision instrument to 7.1 % in electrical machinery and transport equipment. This implies that financial support by financial institutions is important for SMEs to expand export activities. We also calculate the contribution of firm size and TFP to export volume under different specification of intensive margin export function to see the robustness of the results obtained above. We use the IV estimate coefficients of export function where year dummies replace world income, real exchange rate and lending attitude of financial institutions. We use the same price-cost margin equation as above. The second panel of Table 8 shows the median of the frequency distribution of the contribution of each variable across firms under this specification. The results remain essentially unaltered. 13 The contribution of TFP to export volume is 5.2% for general machinery and 2.0% for precision instrument. The contribution of TFP is nil for transport equipment. 18 The contribution of firm size is large for SMEs as well as large firms, irrespective of industry. The contribution of TFP to export is also non-negligible for large firms except for transport equipment. Thus TFP is important as a driving force of export for large firms. On the other hand, the contribution of TFP to export is much smaller for SMEs except for electrical machinery. 6. Concluding Remark This study is an empirical attempt to compare the exporting behavior of SMEs with large firms from the viewpoints of export market participation decision (extensive margin) and export volume decision (intensive margin), using the firm-level panel data. We find that firm size is an important determinant of both extensive margin and intensive margin decision for SMEs as well as large firms. Marginal effect of firm size on the export market participation decision is larger for SMEs, suggesting that SMEs are more likely to cover fixed start-up cost as firm size gets larger. Furthermore, SMEs as well as large firms benefit from scale economies. In contrast, productivity affects only intensive margin of export for both SMEs and large firms. Quantitatively the contribution of productivity to export volume is much larger for large firms. Financial factors are also important determinants of export. Liquidity reserve has positive effects on extensive margin of export for SMEs and large firms. Moreover financial institutions play an important role in expanding export activities of SMEs, suggesting that financial institutions help SMEs export by providing a variety of services including trade finance. Our empirical findings yield important policy implications to activate export of SMEs. One big obstacle to SMEs’ export market participation is start-up cost, such as obtaining basic knowledge of legal systems and business practices in export markets, overseas marketing to acquire customers and reliable partners, developing marketing channels, retooling and redesigning products for foreign customers. Large firms have already accumulated expertise to facilitate export due to scale economies, but it will take a lot of efforts and cost for the SMEs to prepare such arrangement prior to export. Even if a SME has a potential technology with high TFP, the SME cannot utilize this technology advantage in exporting without painstaking initial preparation of exporting. Instead of SMEs, policymakers should play more vital role in providing a variety of information that facilitates SMEs’ participation in export markets. 14 14 Small and Medium Enterprise Agency (2014) supports our policy recommendations. In fact it presents results of an interesting survey (Questionnaire Survey into the Actual Conditions of Overseas Expansion by SMEs) that asks what the efforts that enterprises considered to be the most important are 19 We also find that SMEs need abundant liquidity reserves for entry into export markets. Financial support at start-up of export as well as maintaining export activities is also inevitable. The estimation results reveal that TFP is lower for SMEs. Policymakers should give SMEs preferential treatment on tax deduction of R&D and ICT investment to promote innovative activities that enhance productivity. Future avenue of extending our current work is to incorporate the decision of production location by SMEs, i.e. foreign direct investment, in addition to sales decision between domestic market and overseas market. in achieving success in exports. Many enterprises responded, “securing sales destinations” followed by “securing reliable business partners/advisors,” and “assessment of local market needs and trend.” 20 Data Appendix The data for individual corporations are all from Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities (hereafter abbreviated as BSJBSA) of Ministry of Economy, Trade, and Industry of the government of Japan form 1995 to 2009. Complementary aggregate time series, such as exchange rate, prices and working hours, are from the Bank of Japan online data base and the website of the Cabinet Office of the Government of Japan. [1] Nominal output (pX) and real output (X) The output is defined as the sum of [218:Sales] 15 and net increase of inventories [170:Inventory at the end of period] - [169:Inventory at the beginning of period]. It should be noted, however, that inventories are evaluated at factor costs, while sales amount are at market prices. Accordingly, we adjust this conceptual inconsistency by multiplying the ratio of [218:Sales] to [225:Cost of sales] to the net increase of inventories above. As for the output price (p), we apply the industry output price commonly to the firms within the same industry. Industry output price is the [Input-Output Price Index of the Manufacturing Industry by Sector (2005 base)/ Output Price Index/ Manufacturing industry sector] of Bank of Japan. We will explain the data on prices later in detail. The detailed explanation of output price index will be provided in [10]. [2] Total cost (TC) and price cost margin (PCM) Total cost (TC) is the sum of [225: Cost of sales], net increase of inventories [170:Inventory at the end of period] - [169:Inventory at the beginning of period], [227:General and administrative expenses], and [242: Interest and discount expense]. Price cost margin (PCM) is defined as the ratio of output to total cost, pX / TC. [3] Total asset (ASSET), total debt (DEBT), and related variables. Total asset is [180:Total asset] and total debt is [181:Total debt]. Debt / Asset ratio (DEBT) is the ratio of total debt (DEBT) to total asset (ASSET). Liquidity ratio (LIQR) is defined as the ratio of the net of current asset [168:Current asset] - [182:Current liabilities] to total asset (ASSET). 15 In what follows the number in the parenthesis indicates the item number in BSJBSA. 21 [4] Labor cost (wL), labor input (L), and wage rate (w) Labor cost (wL) is the sum of [238: Amount of salary payment] and [240: welfare expense]. Labor input (L) is in yearly working hours and defined as the products of [89: Number of regular employees] and [Hours worked by employed persons classified by economic activity] in Annual Report on National Account, Cabinet Office of the Government of Japan. Accordingly, wage rate (w) is defined as the hourly wage and obtained by dividing the labor cost (wL) by total working hours (L). [5] Capital cost (cK), real capital stock (K), and the rental price of capital (c) It is not easy to construct the gross capital stock for individual firms based on the data in the Survey. For the sake of convenience, we construct the capital stock (K) by deflating [172:Tangible fixed asset] by the price index for investment good (q) in [14]. That is to say, we evaluate the capital stock by the re-purchasing price at the corresponding period. Rental price of capital (c) is defined as follows. π = π(π + π) − πΜ , where q is the price of investment good, r is the interest rate, and d is the depreciation rate. Interest rate (r) is the ratio of [242: Interest and discount expense] to the average of current and the preceding year’s [181:Total debt]. Interest bearing debt, such as [184: Short-term bank loan]οΌ[188: Long-term bank loan] are also available in the Survey, but there are many missing cases for these items. This is the reason for our convenient treatment of interest rate. Depreciation rate (d) is the ratio of [239: Depreciation cost] to the average of the current and the preceding year’s [172: Tangible fixed asset]. Capital cost (cK) is the product of real capital stock (K) and the rental price (c). [6] Cost of intermediate inputs (p M M) and real intermediate input (M) Cost of intermediate goods (p M M) is obtained by subtracting the labor cost (wL) and capital cost (cK) from the total cost (TC). Real intermediate input (M) is obtained by deflating p M M by intermediate input price (p M ). As for the intermediate input price (p M ), as in the case of output price, we apply the industry intermediate input price commonly to the firms within the same industry. Industry output price is the [Input-Output Price Index of the Manufacturing Industry by Sector (2005 base) / Input Price Index / Manufacturing industry sector] of Bank of Japan. The detailed explanation of input price index will be provided in [11]. [7] World income (Yw) 22 World income is defined as the weighted average of GDP in constant dollars in eight regions: Asia, Middle East, Western Europe, Russia and Eastern Europe, North America, Central and South America, Oceania and Africa. The weighs are the proportion of export to each region to each industry’s total export from Japan, and thereby the world income thus obtained varies across four industries. [8] Nominal export amount (p E X E ) and real export amount (X E ) As the nominal export amount, we have [251:Amount of direct foreign export] in the Survey and real export amount is obtained by deflating it by export price (p E ). We also apply the industry export price commonly to the firms within the same industry. Industry export price is the [Input-Output Price Index of the Manufacturing Industry by Sector (2005 base) / Output Price Index/ Manufacturing industry sector (Exports)] of Bank of Japan. The detailed explanation of export price index will be provided in [12]. [9] Research and Development intensity (RD) The ratio of [525: In-house Research and Development expense] to [218:Sales] in BSJBSA. [10] Output price index (p) [Input-Output Price Index of the Manufacturing Industry by Sector (2005 base) / Output Price Index / Manufacturing industry sector]. As for the sector of electrical machinery, the sector is subdivided into “Electrical machinery”, “Information and communication electronics equipment” and “Electronic components” after 2000. Accordingly, in order to maintain the time-series consistency, we aggregate the three sectors based on the weights of 2005 (base-year) after 2000. The weights are 55.092 for “Electrical machinery”, 38.294 for “Information and communication electronics equipment” and 56.384 for “Electronic components.” We connect the series of 2000 and 2005 base years and construct the price index of 2005 base year. Concordance of the name of the data series in Bank of Japan is as follows. Concordance of code number of data series in BOJ General machinery Electrical machinery Info. & comm. electronics equipment Electronic components Transportation equipment Precision instruments Before 1999 PR’PRIO_8A0030010 PR’PRIO_8A0030011 PR’PRIO_8A0030012 PR’PRIO_8A0030013 23 After 2000 PR’PRIO05_8A0030010 PR’PRIO05_8A0030011 PR’PRIO05_8A0030012 PR’PRIO05_8A0030013 PR’PRIO05_8A0030014 PR’PRIO05_8A0030015 [11] Intermediate input price (p M ) [Input-Output Price Index of the Manufacturing Industry by Sector (2005 base)/ Input Price Index / Manufacturing industry sector]. As for the sector of electrical machinery, the sector is subdivided into “Electrical machinery”, “Information and communication electronics equipment” and “Electronic components” after 2005. Accordingly, in order to maintain the time-series consistency, we aggregate the three sectors based on the weights of 2005 (base-year) after 2000. The weights are 30.19 for “Electrical machinery”, 4.71 for “Information and communication electronics equipment” and 73.809 for “Electronic components.” We connect the series of 1995, 2000 and 2005 base years and construct the price index of 2005 base year. Concordance of the name of the data series in Bank of Japan is as follows. Concordance of code number of data series in BOJ General machinery Electrical machinery Info. & comm. Electronics equipment Electronic components Transportation equipment Precision instruments Before 1999 PR’PRIO95_6C123001 PR’PRIO95_6C133001 2000 to 2004 PR’PRIO_6C0030012 PR’PRIO_6C0030013 After 2005 PR’PRIO05_6C0030012 PR’PRIO05_6C0030013 PR’PRIO05_6C0030014 PR’PRIO95_6C143001 PR’PRIO_6C0030014 PR’PRIO05_6C0030015 PR’PRIO05_6C0030016 PR’PRIO95_6C153001 PR’PRIO_6C0030015 PR’PRIO05_6C0030017 [12] Export price (p E ) [Corporate Goods Price Index (2005 Base)/ Export Price Index (yen basis)] in BOJ data base. The code number of data series in BOJ database General machinery and equipment Electric & electronic products Transportation equipment Precision instruments PR’PRCG_1400420001 PR’PRCG_1400520001 PR’PRCG_1400620001 PR’PRCG_1400720001 As for the export price, [Input-Output Price Index of the Manufacturing Industry by Sector (2005 base) / Output Price Index/ Manufacturing industry sector (Exports)] is also available in BOJ database. For consistency with the import price index in contract currency base, we apply the [Corporate Goods Price Index (2005 Base) / Export Price 24 Index (yen basis)] [13] Import price (p W ) [Corporate Goods Price Index (2005 Base) / Import Price Index (contract currency basis)] in BOJ data base. The code number of data series in BOJ database General machinery and equipment Electric & electronic products Transportation equipment Precision instruments PR’PRCG_1500720001 PR’PRCG_1500820001 PR’PRCG_1500920001 PR’PRCG_1501020001 [14] Investment good price (q) [Corporate Goods Price Index (2005 Base) / Index by Stage of Demand and Use (reference) Investment goods] (PR’PRCG_28K1020005) in BOJ database. [15] Exchange rate (ex) [Nominal / Effective Exchange Rates (2010=100)] (ST'FX180110001) in BOJ database. The series is converted to 2005 base year. [16] Lending attitude of financial institution (LEND) [D.I./Lending Attitude] in Bank of Japan's (BOJ) National Short-Term Economic Survey of Enterprises in Japan (known for short as Tankan). The indices are classified by firm size as in the following table. As can be seen from the table, the firms with equity capital below 20 million yen are excluded after 2004. We adopt the series for industrial machinery as the index for general machinery sector. Classification by firm-size Large enterprises Before 2003 (By number of employees) More than 1000 After 2004 (By share capital) More than billion yen Medium-sized enterprises More than 300 and below 1000 Small -sized enterprises Below300 More than 100 million yen and below billion yen More than 20 million yen and below 100 million yen 25 Code number of data series in BOJ database Industrial machinery Electrical machinery Transportation equipment Precision instruments Large enterprises CO’COAEF1140612 GCQ01000@ CO’COAEF1150612 GCQ01000@ CO’COAEF1160612 GCQ01000@ CO’COAEF1200612 GCQ01000@ Medium enterprises CO’COAEF1140612 GCQ02000@ CO’COAEF1150612 GCQ02000@ CO’COAEF1160612 GCQ02000@ CO’COAEF1200612 GCQ02000@ 26 Small enterprises CO’COAEF1140612 GCQ03000@ CO’COAEF1150612 GCQ03000@ CO’COAEF1160612 GCQ03000@ CO’COAEF1200612 GCQ03000@ References Amiti,M. and D.E. Weinstein(2011). “Exports and Financial Shocks,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126, pp.1841-1877. Aw, B. Y., Chung, S. and M.J.Roberts(2000). “Productivity and Turnover in the Export Market: Micro-level Evidence from the Republic of Korea and Taiwan (China),” World Bank Economic Review 14, pp.65-90. Baldwin, J.R. and E. Gu(2003). “Export-Market Participation and Productivity Performance in Canadian Manufacturing,” Canadian Journal of Economics 36, pp.634-657. Bernard, A.B. and J.B. Jensen(1995). “Exporters, Jobs, and Wages in U.S. Manufacturing: 1976-87,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, pp.67-112. Bernard, A.B. and J.B. Jensen(1999). “Exceptional Exporter Performance: Cause, Effect, or Both?” Journal of International Economics 47, pp.1-25. Bernard, A.B. and J.B. Jensen(2004a). “Exporting and Productivity in the USA,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 20, pp.343-357. Bernard, A.B. and J.B. Jensen(2004b).“Why Some Firms Export?” Review of Economics and Statistics 86, pp.561-569. Bernard, A.B. and J. Wagner(2001). “Export Entry and Exit by German Firms,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv/Review of World Economics 137, pp.105-123. Bernard, A.B., Eaton, J., Jensen, J.B. and S. Kortum(2003). “Plants and Productivity in International Trade,” American Economic Review 93, pp.1268-1291. Bernard, A.B., Jensen, J.B., Redding, S.J. and P.K. Schott(2007). “Firms in International Trade,” Journal of Economic Perspective 21, pp.105-130. 27 Bricogne, J.C., Fontagne, L., Ganlier, G., Taglioni, D. and V. Vicard(2012). “Firms and the Global Crisis: French Exports in the Turmoil,” Journal of International Economics 87, pp.134-146. Caves, D.W., Christensen, L.R. and W. E. Diewert(1982). “Multilateral Comparisons of Output, Input and Productivity Using Superlative Index Numbers,” The Economic Journal 92, pp.73-86. Chaney, T.(2005). “Liquidity Constrained Exporters,” mimeographed, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Chor, D. and K. Manova(2012). “Off the Cliff and Back? Credit Conditions and International Trade during the Global Financial Crisis,” Journal of International Economics 87, pp.117-133. Clerides,S., Lach, S. and J.Tybout(1998). “Is Learning by Exporting Important? Micro-dynamic Evidence from Columbia, Mexico and Morocco,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, pp.903-947. De Loecker, J. and F. Warzynski(2012). “Markups and Firm-level Export Status,” American Economic Review 102, pp.2437-2471. Feenstra, R.C., Li, Z. and M. Yu(2014). “Exports and Credit Constraints under Private Information: Theory and Evidence from China,” The Review of Economics and Statistics 96, pp.729-744. Forslid, R. and T. Okubo(2011). “ Are Capital Intensive Firms the Biggest Exporters?” RIETI Discussion Paper 11-E-014. Greenaway, D., Guariglia, A. and R. Kneller(2007). “Financial Factors and Exporting Decisions,” Journal of International Economics 73, pp.377-395. Haddad, M., A. Harrison and C. Hausman(2010) “Decomposing the Great Trade Collapse: Products, Prices and Quantities in the 2008-2009 Crisis,” NBER Working Paper w16253. 28 Hallward-Driemeier, M., Iarossi, G. and K.L. Sokoloff(2002). “Exports and Manufacturing Productivity in East Asia: A Comparative Analysis with Firm-level Data,” NBER Working Paper 8894. Iacovone, L. and V. Zavacka(2009). “Banking Crises and Exporters: Lesson from the Past,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5016. Kimura, F. and K. Kiyota(2006). “Exports, FDI and Productivity of Firm: Dynamic Evidence from Japanese Firms,” Review of World Economics 142, pp.695-719. Kletzer, K. and P. Bardhan(1987). “Credit Markets and Patterns of International Trade,” Journal of Development Economics 27, pp. 57-70. Kwon, H., Kim, Y. and K. Fukao(2008). “Why Did the Japanese TFP Growth Rate Recover? An Empirical Analysis Based on Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities,” (in Japanese) RIETI DP Series 08-J-050 Levchenko, A., Lewis, L. and L. Tesar(2010). “The Role of Financial Factors in the Great Trade Collapse: A Skeptic’s View,” University of Michigan, mimeographed. Manova, K.(2013). “Credit Constraints, Heterogeneous Firms, and International Trade,” Review of Economic Studies 80, pp.711-744. Manova, K., Wei, S-J, and Z. Zhang(2011). “Firm Exports and Multinational Activity under Credit Constraints,” NBER Working Paper 16905. Mayer, T. and G.I.P. Ottaviano(2007). The Happy Few: The Internationalisation of European Firms, Bruegel Blueprint Series. Melitz, M.J.(2003). “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity,” Econometrica 71, pp.1695-1725. Melitz, M.J. and G.I.P. Ottaviano(2008). “Market Size, Trade and Productivity,” Review of Economic Studies 75, pp.295-316. 29 Muûls, M.(2008). “Exporters and Credit Constraints: A Firm Level Approach,” mimeographed. Roberts, M. and J. Tybout (1997). “The Decision To Export in Colombia: An Empirical Model of Entry with Sunk Costs,” American Economic Review 87, pp.545–564. Ronci, M.(2005) “Trade Finance and Trade Flows: Panel Data Evidence from 10 Crises,” in Access to Trade Finance in Times of Crisis, ed. Wang, J-Y. and M. Ronci (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund) Small and Medium Enterprise Agency (2014). 2014 White Paper on Small and Medium Enterprises in Japan Todo,Y.(2011).“Quantitative Evaluation of Determinants of Export and FDI: Firm-Level Evidence from Japan,” The World Economy 34, pp.355-381. Tomiura,E.(2007). “Foreign Outsourcing, Exporting and FDI: A Productivity Comparison at the Firm Level,” Journal of International Economics 72, pp.113-127. Wagner, J.(1995). “Exports, Firm Size, and Firm Dynamics,” Small Business Economics 7, pp.29-39. Wagner, J.(2001). “A Note on the Firm Size – Export Relationship,” Small Business Economics 17, pp.229-237. Wakasugi, R., Ito, B. and E. Tomiura(2008). “Offshoring and Trade in East Asia: A Statistical Analysis,” Asian Economic Papers 7, pp.101-124. Yashiro, N. and D. Hirano(2010). “Evaluating Japanese Exporters’ Performance and Investment Behavior during the 2002-2007 Export Boom,” RIETI Policy Discussion Paper Series 10-P-005. (in Japanese) 30 70 60 50 % 40 30 20 10 Data source: Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities Figure 1. Proportions of exporters by firm size 31 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 2002 SMEs Large firms 0 10 9 8 7 5 4 3 2 1 Data source: Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities Figure 2. SME’s share of export amount 32 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 0 1995 % 6 Data source: Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities Figure 3. Dynamic performance of firms by export status 33 Data source: Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities Figure 3. (cont.) Dynamic performance of firms by export status 34 Figure 4. Price-cost margin by firm size and export status 35 Figure 5. Log of TFP by firm size and export status 36 Table 1. Sample median of firm characteristics by firm size and export status (1) (2) (3) SMEs L PCM RS RD DEBT A LIQR NO (4) (5) (6) (7) Sub total Total Large firms NonExporters Sub total NonExporters exporters exporters No. of employees 113 147 120 597 807 (Growth rate) -0.93 -0.49 -0.83 -0.81 -1.02 Price cost margin 1.011 1.021 1.013 1.020 1.030 Sales amount 2,574 3,940 2,848 22,736 33,611 (Growth rate) -0.57 0.58 -0.32 0.40 1.32 R&D / Sales ratio 0.06 0.79 0.17 0.60 2.38 Debt /Asset ratio 74.68 68.01 73.09 64.98 56.04 Total asset 2,185 3,955 2,528 19,130 36,549 (Growth rate) -0.19 1.05 0.10 0.38 1.52 Liquidity ratio 11.36 18.71 13.16 5.45 14.94 No. of observations 130,120 41,044 171,164 11,448 19,046 723 -0.94 1.025 28,686 0.93 1.59 58.97 28,262 1.11 11.68 30,494 Unit: Millions of yen in 2005 constant price for RS and A. Growth rates and ratios are in percentage. Data source: Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities 37 141 -0.85 1.015 3,538 -0.10 0.34 70.97 3,138 0.28 12.93 201,658 Table 2. Multi-way analysis of variance Period Export status Industry Year Industry×export status Industry×year Export status×year (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) t-3 t-2 t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 Number of employees 9.6 326.0 334.6 329.8 280.3 240.0 208.8 2.5 6.7 7.3 10.7 7.4 7.0 6.3 2.3 1.7 ο 1.6 ο 1.5 ο 1.0 ο 1.0 ο 1.0 ο 1.8 27.9 31.6 34.2 31.3 28.3 25.6 1.1 ο 0.3 ο 0.3 ο 0.2 ο 0.2 ο 0.2 ο 0.2 ο 0.7 ο 4.9 4.6 3.9 2.9 2.1 1.5 ο 612.5 21.5 1.0 ο 43.3 0.3 ο 0.7 ο Export status Industry Year Industry×export status Industry×year Export status×year 540.3 105.1 11.6 23.0 3.0 2.9 Export status Industry Year Industry×export status Industry×year Export status×year 195.6 485.2 12.5 115.3 5.2 12.8 3.8 22.6 0.6 ο 3.0 1.1 ο 2.9 Export status Industry Year Industry×export status Industry×year Export status×year Debt / Asset ratio 520.7 198.5 103.5 114.4 91.7 16.8 12.6 6.9 8.3 7.1 1.6 ο 8.6 4.9 5.5 3.4 24.8 4.1 2.4 2.7 2.3 0.4 ο 0.6 ο 0.6 ο 0.7 ο 0.7 ο 0.9 ο 1.0 ο 0.6 ο 0.6 ο 0.6 ο Export status Industry Year Industry×export status Industry×year Export status×year Real total asset 148.4 495.1 473.3 458.0 380.1 320.1 273.9 29.1 15.6 12.7 13.1 9.1 6.9 5.8 1.7 ο 1.5 ο 1.7 ο 1.8 ο 1.5 ο 1.4 ο 1.4 ο 3.0 24.1 24.1 24.4 21.1 18.6 16.4 0.7 ο 0.5 ο 0.7 ο 0.7 ο 0.6 ο 0.5 ο 0.4 ο 1.6 1.0 ο 0.9 ο 1.1 ο 1.0 ο 0.9 ο 1.0 ο Export status Industry Year Industry×export status Industry×year Export status×year 18.9 6.8 31.0 2.9 6.2 2.8 15.1 4.1 4.7 2.1 1.7 0.9 ο Price-cost margin 20.2 29.0 21.2 4.4 8.9 5.4 5.1 8.6 7.6 2.3 3.5 2.2 1.9 3.1 3.1 1.2 ο 1.8 1.9 Export status Industry Year Industry×export status Industry×year Export status×year 27.1 6.1 9.2 2.5 3.6 2.5 136.1 26.8 4.7 2.5 0.6 ο 1.7 Liquidity ratio 61.6 63.1 12.6 14.9 2.9 4.4 1.3 ο 1.4 ο 0.6 ο 0.6 ο 1.0 ο 1.2 ο 38 50.0 11.7 2.9 1.1 ο 0.6 ο 1.1 ο (9) Past Future 3-year growth rate 3-year growth rate 18.9 6.8 31.0 2.9 6.2 2.8 16.0 6.0 38.4 2.1 4.9 4.0 15.2 31.4 25.6 2.9 15.5 3.6 0.1 ο 28.1 47.8 2.5 23.0 3.2 15.4 45.7 8.3 1.9 11.7 1.9 1.8 ο 50.9 11.5 2.4 14.1 1.6 42.5 9.6 15.6 3.5 5.7 3.9 Real sales amount 595.9 597.7 620.9 507.6 421.1 358.9 22.1 19.7 20.0 16.5 12.6 10.8 0.7 ο 0.8 ο 1.0 ο 0.7 ο 0.9 ο 1.1 ο 43.4 46.1 49.2 41.3 35.3 30.7 0.2 ο 0.3 ο 0.4 ο 0.4 ο 0.3 ο 0.4 ο 0.7 ο 0.5 ο 0.8 ο 0.7 ο 0.7 ο 0.7 ο R&D / Sales ratio 354.8 343.1 257.7 88.2 78.4 68.3 11.2 7.4 5.8 17.8 18.1 15.1 2.1 2.1 1.4 2.9 1.9 1.9 (8) 208.7 154.5 61.7 47.3 6.2 1.0 ο 14.0 10.8 1.2 ο 0.6 ο 2.7 1.5 ο 75.0 5.7 2.4 1.9 0.6 ο 0.5 ο 39.1 9.3 2.4 0.9 ο 0.6 ο 0.8 ο 60.7 4.3 1.5 ο 1.7 0.6 ο 0.6 ο 29.4 7.9 1.7 οΏ½ 0.8 ο 0.6 ο 0.7 ο Table 3. Past and future average growth rates of firm size by export status (1) (2) Number of employees Past 3 years Future 3 years (3) (4) (5) (6) Real sales amount Real total assets Past 3 years Past 3 years Future 3 years Future 3 years Mean Continuous non-exporters New exporters Exit exporters Continuous exporters -0.99 -0.41 -2.50 -1.32 -0.69 -0.50 -1.37 -0.92 0.68 3.26 0.20 2.06 0.48 1.01 -0.06 1.05 1.48 3.97 1.43 2.62 0.93 1.16 0.55 1.73 Total -1.09 -0.76 1.09 0.64 1.83 1.16 Median Continuous non-exporters New exporters Exit exporters Continuous exporters -1.19 -0.87 -1.86 -1.24 -0.87 -0.76 -1.25 -0.66 -0.34 1.33 -0.12 1.03 -0.36 0.12 -0.44 0.53 0.33 1.93 1.05 1.74 -0.06 0.54 0.14 1.21 Total -1.20 -0.81 0.03 -0.13 0.75 0.31 39 Table 4. Proportion of exporting firms by firm size (1) SMEs Large firms Total Non-exporters Exporters Total Proportion of exporters (%) Non-exporters Exporters Total Proportion of exporters (%) Non-exporters Exporters Total Proportion of exporters (%) (2) General machinery 11,971 9,099 21,070 43.2 575 2,919 3,494 83.5 12,546 12,018 24,564 48.9 40 Electrical machinery 16,424 7,727 24,151 32.0 1,920 4,097 6,017 68.1 18,344 11,824 30,168 39.2 (3) Transportation equipment 10,735 3,060 13,795 22.2 1,285 2,563 3,848 66.6 12,020 5,623 17,643 31.9 (4) Precision instruments 2,145 2,421 4,566 53.0 105 757 862 87.8 2,250 3,178 5,428 58.5 Table 5a. Estimated result of extensive margin decision: Basic specification οΌ1οΌ dy/dx PCM -1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½−3 πππ log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND no. PCM -1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½−3 πππ log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND no. PCM -1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½−3 πππ log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND no. PCM -1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½−3 πππ log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND no. -0.2187 ** (2.12) 0.3900 *** (7.73) 0.1738 *** (2.74) 0.0016 *** (3.36) 14,227 -0.0092 (1.20) 0.0224 *** (4.27) 0.0047 (1.38) 0.0000 (0.86) 16,020 -0.0015 (1.43) 0.0018 ** (2.40) 0.0015 ** (2.25) 0.0000 (1.55) 9,466 -0.0557 (0.21) 0.5640 *** (2.84) 0.6510 *** (2.58) -0.0013 (0.86) 3,017 οΌ2οΌ SMEs dy/dx -0.2129 ** (2.03) 0.3659 *** (6.33) 0.1019 (1.63) 14,227 οΌ3οΌ οΌ4οΌ dy/dx dy/dx General machinery -0.0005 (0.61) -0.0470 (0.20) 0.4872 *** 0.0005 * (5.86) (1.86) 0.2266 ** 0.0002 (2.26) (0.41) 0.0019 *** 0.0000 (2.84) (0.18) 9,596 2,669 Electrical machinery -0.0073 (1.12) 0.0033 (0.26) 0.0253 *** 0.0225 *** 0.0059 (4.23) (4.08) (1.54) 0.0054 0.0008 0.0060 (1.46) (0.21) (1.23) 0.0000 0.0000 (0.30) (0.82) 16,020 10,534 4,521 -0.0055 (0.74) Transportation equipment -0.0226 (0.40) -0.0091 (1.34) 0.0061 *** 0.0068 ** 0.0324 * (3.00) (2.54) (1.74) 0.0049 *** 0.0072 ** 0.0587 (2.61) (2.37) (1.46) 0.0000 * -0.0001 (1.86) (0.45) 9,466 6,441 3,106 -0.0053 (1.50) Precision instruments -0.0001 (0.24) 0.1582 (0.36) 0.4095 *** 0.4216 ** 0.0004 (3.43) (2.37) (0.54) 0.4843 *** 0.6684 ** 0.0003 (2.72) (1.99) (0.47) -0.0011 0.0000 (0.70) (0.47) 3,017 1,958 631 0.0012 (0.01) 41 οΌ5οΌ Large firms dy/dx οΌ6οΌ dy/dx 0.0000 (0.15) 0.0002 (1.51) 0.0001 (0.58) 2,669 -0.0027 (1.03) 0.0007 * (1.73) 0.0021 (1.35) 0.0000 (1.02) 1,917 -0.0058 (0.90) 0.0069 (1.56) 0.0067 (1.26) 4,521 0.0017 (0.23) 0.0039 * (1.90) 0.0048 (1.47) 0.0000 (0.82) 3,269 0.0008 (0.02) 0.0331 (1.57) 0.0514 (1.33) 3,106 0.0410 (0.82) 0.0143 (1.38) 0.0411 (1.32) -0.0001 (0.88) 2,347 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 631 0.0005 (0.36) 0.0007 (1.08) 0.0001 (0.10) 0.0000 (0.74) 463 Table 5b. Estimated result of extensive margin decision: Dynamic specification οΌ1οΌ dy/dx EXD -1 PCM -1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½−3 πππ log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND no. EXD -1 PCM -1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½−3 πππ log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND no. EXD -1 PCM -1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½−3 πππ log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND no. EXD -1 PCM -1 οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½οΏ½−3 πππ log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND no. 1.1581 *** (85.7) -0.1283 (1.61) 0.0800 *** (9.94) 0.1114 *** (3.64) 0.0011 ** (2.42) 14,227 0.9955 *** (66.9) -0.0487 (0.77) 0.0550 *** (9.91) 0.0639 *** (3.12) -0.0005 (0.99) 16,020 0.6725 *** (35.1) -0.0191 (0.24) 0.0585 *** (9.84) 0.0907 *** (3.84) 0.0001 (0.18) 9,466 1.1654 *** (40.2) 0.1729 (1.13) 0.0806 *** (4.49) 0.0775 (1.26) -0.0003 (0.29) 3,017 οΌ2οΌ SMEs dy/dx 1.1603 *** (85.5) -0.1189 (1.46) 0.0797 *** (9.89) 0.1057 *** (3.44) 14,227 0.9969 *** (66.7) -0.0255 (0.44) 0.0574 *** (10.2) 0.0661 *** (3.21) 16,020 οΌ3οΌ οΌ4οΌ dy/dx dy/dx General machinery 1.2021 *** 0.3201 *** (71.6) (8.25) -0.0731 (1.20) 0.0013 (0.01) 0.0763 *** 0.0040 (7.39) (0.87) 0.1169 *** 0.0928 *** (3.02) (3.01) 0.0006 -0.0001 (1.14) (0.34) 9,596 2,669 Electrical machinery 1.0263 *** 0.8559 *** (55.6) (30.7) -0.1307 (1.21) 0.0265 (0.26) 0.0670 *** 0.0218 *** (9.08) (3.13) 0.0689 *** 0.0720 ** (2.62) (2.06) -0.0013 ** -0.0013 (1.97) (1.54) 10,534 4,521 Transportation equipment 0.6716 *** 0.7291 *** 0.9239 *** (35.0) (30.0) (27.2) -0.0117 -0.1232 (0.24) (0.40) -0.0298 (0.35) 0.0587 *** 0.0607 *** 0.0348 *** (9.88) (7.72) (3.59) 0.0904 *** 0.0669 ** 0.2711 *** (3.86) (2.17) (3.78) 0.0008 -0.0002 (1.47) (0.23) 9,466 6,441 3,106 1.1833 *** (39.5) 0.2174 (1.39) 0.0795 *** (4.52) 0.0760 (1.22) 3,017 Precision instruments 1.1759 *** 0.0655 (32.0) (1.18) -0.0060 (0.19) 0.1464 (0.58) 0.0695 *** 0.0173 (2.98) (1.55) 0.0595 0.0067 (0.77) (0.36) 0.0004 -0.0004 (0.27) (1.07) 1,958 631 42 οΌ5οΌ Large firms dy/dx 0.3120 *** (7.92) -0.0754 (1.25) 0.0045 (1.04) 0.0942 *** (3.15) 2,669 0.8565 *** (30.4) -0.0873 (0.80) 0.0213 *** (3.04) 0.0691 ** (1.98) 4,521 0.9299 *** (26.7) -0.1105 * (0.35) 0.0345 *** (3.58) 0.2820 *** (3.92) 3,106 0.0032 (0.34) 0.0004 (0.19) 0.0012 (0.36) 0.0010 (0.36) 631 οΌ6οΌ dy/dx 0.3243 *** (6.88) -0.0976 (1.17) 0.0018 (0.34) 0.1164 *** (3.06) -0.0003 (0.70) 1,917 0.8355 *** (24.9) -0.1001 (0.65) 0.0189 ** (2.39) 0.0966 ** (2.34) -0.0020 * (1.92) 3,269 0.9088 *** (22.9) 0.0148 (0.03) 0.0313 *** (2.95) 0.2909 *** (3.43) -0.0009 (0.92) 2,347 0.1213 * (1.95) 0.0353 (0.53) 0.0225 ** (2.56) -0.0050 (0.15) -0.0008 (1.50) 463 Table 6a. Estimated results of intensive margin decision: Simple panel regression (1) (2) SMEs General machinery log (PCM) log (Yw) log (P E /eP W ) log (A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND overall R2 / no. Electrical machinery log (PCM) log (Yw) log (P E /eP W ) log (A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND overall R2 / no. Transportation equipment log (PCM) log (Yw) log (P E /eP W ) log (A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND overall R2 / no. Precision instruments log (PCM) log (Yw) log (P E /eP W ) log (A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND overall R2 / no. FE 0.9469 *** (6.78) 0.1714 (1.16) -0.4704 *** (2.80) 0.7257 *** (12.3) 0.1254 (0.99) 0.0073 *** (7.45) 0.2408 / 7,153 FE 1.0114 *** (7.07) 0.7218 *** (12.3) 0.0316 (0.25) 0.2354 / 7,153 FE 1.0301 *** (7.29) 1.7169 *** (8.83) -0.3841 ** (2.05) 0.8095 *** (14.7) -0.2678 ** (2.48) 0.0075 *** (5.91) 0.2469 / 6,030 FE 1.0396 *** (7.28) 0.7526 *** (13.2) -0.2796 *** (2.60) 0.2436 / 6,030 RE 0.7355 (1.52) 0.0057 (0.02) -0.1766 (0.25) 1.0683 *** (16.5) 0.4603 ** (2.18) 0.0055 *** (2.67) 0.2347 / 2,477 RE 0.9891 ** (2.00) 0.9995 *** (14.4) 0.3697 (1.74) 0.2349 / 2,477 RE 0.2914 ** (2.39) 0.2328 (0.72) -0.1429 (0.34) 0.9376 *** (13.8) 0.3862 ** (2.30) 0.0037 ** (2.10) 0.1420 / 1,871 RE 0.3081 ** (2.54) 0.9075 *** (13.1) 0.3151 * (1.87) 0.1459 / 1,871 43 (3) (4) Large firms FE FE 1.4527 *** 1.4245 *** (6.64) (6.27) 0.6236 *** (3.35) -0.5732 *** (2.84) 0.8655 *** 0.8819 *** (10.7) (10.8) -0.1556 -0.2575 (0.91) (1.54) 0.0030 *** (2.86) 0.5255 / 2,431 0.5269 / 2,431 FE 1.3461 *** (6.30) 1.9791 *** (8.56) -0.4733 ** (2.20) 0.8342 *** (12.0) -0.2018 (1.40) 0.0056 *** (3.80) 0.5668 / 3,359 FE 0.5989 (1.17) 1.4816 *** (6.33) -0.0702 (0.13) 1.3370 *** (17.0) 0.5740 *** (2.90) 0.0031 ** (2.38) 0.6664 / 2,198 RE 1.7677 *** (4.02) 0.9866 ** (2.19) -1.0895 ** (2.05) 1.1022 *** (11.6) 0.4613 (1.61) 0.0002 (0.09) 0.3738 / 608 RE 1.3146 *** (6.18) 1.1510 *** (26.2) -0.4381 *** (3.18) 0.5740 / 3,359 RE 1.2819 ** (2.55) 1.2506 *** (22.4) 0.3755 ** (2.07) 0.6681 / 2,198 RE 1.9491 *** (4.33) 0.9419 *** (9.41) 0.4129 (1.47) 0.3757 / 608 Table 6b. Estimated results of intensive margin decision: IV panel regression (1) (2) SMEs General machinery log (PCM) log (Yw) log (P E /eP W ) log (A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND overall R2 / no. Sargan χ2 (p-value) Electrical machinery log (PCM) log (Yw) log (P E /eP W ) log (A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND overall R2 / no. Sargan χ2 (p-value) Transportation log (PCM) equipment log (Yw) log (P E /eP W ) log (A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND overall R2 / no. Sargan χ2 (p-value) Precision instruments log (PCM) log (Yw) log (P E /eP W ) log (A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND overall R2 / no. Sargan χ2 (p-value) FE 1.2501 *** (7.30) 0.2120 (1.42) -0.4875 *** (2.82) 0.7362 *** (12.1) 0.0953 (0.72) 0.0069 *** (6.71) 0.2311 / 6,876 3.838 (0.050) FE 1.4872 *** (9.07) 1.6667 *** (8.33) -0.3571 * (1.86) 0.8203 *** (14.7) -0.3379 *** (2.86) 0.0072 *** (5.59) 0.2479 / 5,811 0.056 (0.814) RE 2.4577 *** (3.35) -0.0424 (0.14) -0.3663 (0.49) 1.0783 *** (16.3) 0.5611 ** (2.53) 0.0048 ** (2.24) 0.2341 / 2,354 7.712 (0.006) FE 0.3337 ** (2.46) 0.0849 (0.25) -0.1908 (0.44) 0.9630 *** (10.7) 0.4430 ** (2.30) 0.0034 * (1.86) 0.1420 / 1,871 3.081 (0.079) 44 FE 1.2603 *** (7.20) 0.7320 *** (12.1) -0.0135 (0.10) 0.2317 / 6,876 8.686 (0.003) RE 1.3658 *** (8.40) 0.9364 *** (24.2) -0.3364 *** (3.42) 0.2532 / 5,811 2.084 (0.149) RE 2.0138 *** (2.86) 1.0071 *** (14.2) 0.4592 ** (2.06) 0.2341 / 2,354 10.254 (0.001) RE 0.3377 ** (2.52) 0.9051 *** (12.9) 0.3005 * (1.74) 0.1524 / 1,871 0.243 (0.622) (3) (4) Large firms FE RE 1.6667 *** 1.6349 *** (6.63) (6.14) 0.6443 *** (3.49) -0.5296 *** (2.67) 0.8573 *** 1.1718 *** (10.7) (22.5) -0.2178 -0.0724 (1.32) (0.45) 0.0026 ** (2.44) 0.5182 / 2,390 0.5264 / 2,390 0.634 (0.426) 4.073 (0.044) RE RE 1.9333 *** 1.6941 *** (7.37) (6.54) 1.1155 *** (5.49) -0.3649 οΌ (1.65) 1.2220 *** 1.2154 *** (28.8) (28.1) -0.3823 *** -0.3472 ** (2.68) (2.43) 0.0046 *** (3.05) 0.5739 / 3,253 0.5755 / 3,253 4.038 (0.045) 3.945 (0.047) RE RE 3.1911 *** 2.6105 *** (3.99) (3.58) 1.1065 *** (4.79) 0.3352 (0.60) 1.4533 *** 1.3191 *** (28.6) (24.7) 0.4340 ** 0.3995 ** (2.29) (2.13) 0.0018 (1.26) 0.6657 / 2,156 0.6690 / 2,156 0.655 (0.418) 2.389 (0.122) RE RE 2.6935 *** 2.1996 *** (4.78) (3.98) 0.7893 οΌ (1.76) -0.7093 (1.33) 1.1886 *** 1.0268 *** (12.5) (10.1) 0.4388 0.4056 (1.54) (1.45) 0.0001 (0.04) 0.3660 / 600 0.3771 / 600 0.639 (0.424) 2.281 (0.131) Table 7 Estimated result of price cost margin equation (1) General machinery log(w) log(c) log(T) log(DEBT) overall R2 / No. Electrical machinery log(w) log(c) log(T) log(DEBT) overall R2 / No. Transportation equipment log(w) log(c) log(T) log(DEBT) overall R2 / No. Precision instruments log(w) log(c) log(T) log(DEBT) overall R2 / No. 45 (2) Large firms FE SMEs FE Fixed -0.1553 *** (113.6) -0.0171 *** (24.6) 0.9138 *** (291.5) -0.0016 (1.09) 0.9278 / 6,876 -0.1488*** (67.7) -0.0240*** (20.3) 0.9213*** (166.4) 0.0000 (0.02) 0.9459/ 2,390 FE -0.1578 *** (94.2) -0.0170 *** (20.9) 0.9323 *** (263.2) -0.0091 *** (4.67) 0.8844 / 5,811 FE -0.1250*** (53.5) -0.0305*** (25.9) 0.8617*** (147.8) -0.0016 (0.70) 0.8872/ 3,253 FE -0.0957 *** (45.9) -0.0186 *** (17.3) 0.7780 *** (90.5) -0.0068 ** (2.03) 0.7711 / 2,354 FE -0.1135*** (47.2) -0.0196*** (19.0) 0.7793*** (84.1) -0.0089*** (3.66) 0.8124/ 2,156 FE -0.2089 *** (67.0) -0.0207 *** (12.1) 0.9671 *** (246.7) -0.0018 (0.50) 0.9621 / 1,807 RE -0.1991*** (48.8) -0.0169*** (8.86) 0.9504*** (96.0) -0.0054** (2.07) 0.9586/ 600 Table 8. Decomposition of export growth during 1999-2007 (1) (2) General machinery SMEs Large firms (3) (4) Electrical machinery SMEs Large firms (5) (6) Transport equipment SMEs (7) (8) Precision instrument Large firms SMEs Large firms 0.0270 0.0512 -0.0306 0.5469 0.0041 0.0340 -0.0347 0.0107 0.0146 0.0014 0.0078 0.0043 0.0247 0.3397 0.0197 0.0543 -0.0111 0.0011 0.0204 0.0001 0.1469 0.0382 0.1013 0.4129 -0.0053 0.0016 -0.0978 -0.0007 0.3554 0.0021 Without year dummy variables log(PCM) log(Yw) log(P E /eP W ) log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND log(w) log(c) log(T) log(DEBT) 0.0358 0.0221 0.0701 0.0692 0.0012 0.1699 -0.0113 0.0039 0.0520 0.0001 0.1234 0.1174 0.1343 0.1743 0.0104 0.0856 -0.0437 0.0058 0.1976 0.0000 0.0097 0.1935 0.0100 0.3065 -0.0041 0.0713 -0.0991 -0.0023 0.1733 0.0010 0.0022 0.1372 0.0118 0.5617 0.0074 0.0350 -0.1241 -0.0087 0.2870 0.0001 0.0065 -0.0011 0.0194 0.1539 0.0025 0.0710 -0.0002 0.0034 -0.0047 -0.0001 With year dummy variables log(PCM) log(Yw) log(P E /eP W ) log(A) -1 LIQR -1 LEND log(w) log(c) log(T) log(DEBT) 0.0361 0.1210 0.0089 0.0019 0.0053 0.0220 0.0079 0.1199 0.0688 -0.0002 0.2383 0.0034 0.3499 -0.0041 0.5587 0.0067 0.1437 0.0020 0.4964 0.0037 0.3193 0.0134 0.3567 -0.0049 -0.0114 0.0039 0.0524 0.0001 -0.0429 0.0056 0.1938 0.0000 -0.0911 -0.0021 0.1592 0.0009 -0.1088 -0.0076 0.2515 0.0001 -0.0002 0.0028 -0.0039 -0.0001 -0.0284 0.0088 0.0120 0.0011 -0.0112 0.0011 0.0206 0.0001 -0.0798 -0.0006 0.2903 0.0018 46