Promoting Prosperity: Designing a Sovereign Wealth Fund in British Columbia Mark Levesque 301142335 Pol 499 Dr. Hira Simon Fraser University July 29 2014 Contents Executive Summary ........................................................................................................................ 2 Background ..................................................................................................................................... 3 Purpose and Methodology .............................................................................................................. 4 The Five Criteria Rubric ............................................................................................................. 5 Literature Review............................................................................................................................ 5 Sovereign Wealth Funds as Macroeconomic Policy Tools ......................................................... 5 Alberta Heritage Savings Trust Fund ......................................................................................... 8 Alaska Permanent Fund ............................................................................................................ 12 Norwegian Pension Fund Global.............................................................................................. 17 Conclusion................................................................................................................................. 21 Findings......................................................................................................................................... 22 Contribution Requirements ....................................................................................................... 23 Management Agency ................................................................................................................. 24 Investment Strategy ................................................................................................................... 25 Spending Ability ........................................................................................................................ 26 Total Valuations ........................................................................................................................ 27 Conclusion................................................................................................................................. 29 Recommendations ......................................................................................................................... 29 Recommendation One ............................................................................................................... 30 Recommendation Two ............................................................................................................... 30 Recommendation Three ............................................................................................................. 31 Recommendation Four .............................................................................................................. 32 Recommendation Five ............................................................................................................... 32 Conclusion................................................................................................................................. 33 Bibliography ................................................................................................................................. 34 1 Executive Summary The Government of British Columbia is planning to create a sovereign wealth fund (SWF) called the Prosperity Fund, into which it will deposit the proceeds from the planned development of liquefied natural gas. SWFs are public investment funds, and they are often instituted as savings funds that aim to promote sustainable economic growth from the exploitation of non-renewable natural resources. Many states have created SWFs for this purpose, and B.C. policymakers can learn from their experience in creating the Prosperity Fund. The Albertan Heritage Fund, the Alaskan Permanent Fund, and the Norwegian Petroleum Fund are all examples of commodity-based SWFs that provide relevant examples for British Columbia. They are each funded through a non-renewable natural resource, and they all share a common goal of sharing resource wealth across generations. However, each fund is the result of different policy approaches, and this has resulted in varying degrees of success between them. Specifically, the Petroleum Fund exhibits the strongest principles of SWF management, while the Heritage Fund exhibits the weakest policy framework of these three funds. The Heritage Fund was the first SWF in Canada, but it is not a model that B.C. should attempt to follow. Learning from the experiences of other SWFs, five principal recommendations can be made that would contribute to a strong governance framework for the Prosperity Fund. Stipulate that all LNG resource revenues be deposited into the fund. Delegate management of the fund to an independent management agency. Focus investments on maximizing long-term financial gains. Adopt a risk-averse policy early and scale upwards as fund matures. Place restrictions on the amount of the fund that can be spent annually. Following these policy recommendations will help create a well-performing SWF in British Columbia that focuses on sustaining long-term economic growth and promoting prosperity. 2 Background British Columbia is a province with abundant natural resources, and the development of these resources—both renewable and non-renewable—plays a major role in the British Columbian economy. The Government of B.C. is developing plans to promote the development of the significant liquefied natural gas (LNG) reserves in British Columbia.1 There are many factors that the government must consider, but from a public perspective, how the resource revenues are managed is a critical component of any plan to promote large-scale natural resource exploitation. This is true not only because natural resources in B.C. are owned by the Crown and are thus public resources, but also because of the governing party’s pledge to solve British Columbia’s fiscal woes by placing the revenues received from LNG into a “Prosperity Fund” that will be used to completely pay down the debt and create a “Debt-Free B.C.”2 This fund, as envisioned by the government, will be a sovereign wealth fund (SWF) in which the revenues from the LNG industry would be invested. Sovereign wealth funds are public investment funds owned by the state, and they are often funded through non-renewable resource revenues. Non-renewable natural resources can be understood as a finite stock, and commodity-based SWFs attempt to convert this stock into an income flow by investing a portion of non-renewable natural resource revenues. Many other jurisdictions have created SWFs for this purpose, and examining how other SWFs are created and managed can provide valuable insight for B.C. policymakers. This paper will analyze three such funds, the Albertan Heritage Savings Trust Fund, the Alaskan Permanent Fund, and the 1 2 BC Liberal Party 2013, 7. Ibid., 79. 3 Norwegian Pension Fund Global, in an effort to determine a set of ‘best practices’ that could be used to inform the development of a SWF in British Columbia. Purpose and Methodology The principle aim of this paper will be to address the question “what principles of sovereign wealth fund design and management can the B.C. Government include in the development of the Prosperity Fund to ensure that the fund is able to accomplish the goals set by the government?” To answer this question, a comparative analysis will be made between three SWFs already in operation to understand how different jurisdictions created and managed nonrenewable natural resource revenues, and how different policy actions effect the operation, and ultimately the success, of the funds. Each of these SWFs are funded using revenues from nonrenewable natural resources, and each employs different policy frameworks such that each one will be able to act as a model, or paradigm, of SWF management. These models can then be analyzed and compared for the purposes of informing the development of such a fund in B.C. The comparative analysis conducted in this paper will be used to elucidate the elements of well-performing SWFs, and the success of this analysis will rely on the depth and the rigor of the criteria used to evaluate their performance. This paper will evaluate the three SWFs selected based on five criteria commonly acknowledged as important factors of SWF management3: Contribution Requirements, Management Agency, Investment Strategy, Spending Ability, and Total Valuations. SWFs represent tradeoffs between current and future spending, and these criteria are elements of SWFs that focus on promoting future spending relative current spending. As the B.C. government is promoting the Prosperity Fund as a method to eliminate the provincial 3 Abdullah Al-Hassan 2013, 3-12; Das 2009, 9-12; Hammer 2008, 4-10. 4 debt over the long-term, it is reasonable to assume that this fund will prioritize future spending over the longer term and thus that these criteria are appropriate selections for the purposes of the subsequent evaluations. This list of criteria is not exhaustive, but covers the key elements of SWFs while acknowledging the limited scope of this project. Evaluating all three models on a common set of criteria will enable a systematic comparison of different SWF policy frameworks; the criteria rubric that will be used is presented in the following chart. The Five Criteria Rubric Variable Measure Interpretation Contribution Requirements Determining if the government is committed to depositing resource revenues. Existence of entity to manage the SFW on behalf of the government. Set contribution requirements will be interpreted as a positive principle. Accountable yet distinct managing entity will be interpreted as a positive indicator. Focusing on long-term investments will be viewed as a positive principle. Management Agency Investment Strategy Spending Ability Total Valuations Level of diversity/risk targeted by the fund, targets for investment, environmental targets (if applicable). What the fund is spent on, i.e., budget stabilization, endowments, or dividends. Value of the fund in American dollars, per capita worth. How the fund is spent will be interpreted based on the principles on which it was founded. Higher valuations will be positive indicators. Literature Review Sovereign Wealth Funds as Macroeconomic Policy Tools In recent decades sovereign wealth funds (“SWFs”) have come to play a much larger role in the global macroeconomic system. While there is no definitive definition of what exactly 5 constitutes a SWF, the Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute (SWFI)—an international organization dedicated to studying SWFs—defines it as “a state-owned investment fund or entity that is commonly established from balance of payments surpluses, official foreign currency operations, the proceeds of privatizations, governmental transfer payments, fiscal surpluses, and/or receipts resulting from resource exports. 4” The SWFI also states that a SWF excludes government/employee pension funds and foreign reserves held by a central bank for monetary policy. 5 This definition provides a very technical and inclusive list of what constitutes a SWF, but from this a broader definition can be drawn; simply, that a SWF is an investment fund owned by the state which is funded through any of a variety of government actions which include commodity and non-commodity sources. The SWFI currently lists over 70 SWFs valued at over 6 trillion USD, with more than 32 of these funds being created since 2005.6 The increased prominence of SWFs in the global economy stems from the macroeconomic benefits they confer onto their sovereign manager. There has been an increasing trend towards states creating sovereign wealth funds, and how states constitute their respective funds depends on the macroeconomic circumstances that prompted its creation. The context of each SWF is unique, but the SWFI lists common objectives of these funds, which includes: stabilizing government budgets from export/resource volatility, diversifying from natural resources, and funding social programs.7 In summarizing the IMF literature on the subject, Weiss states that there are three broad categories into which most SWFs belong.8 SWFs that are set up with the primary purpose of shielding government revenues from volatility in commodity markets are known as stabilization funds.9 Stabilization funds primarily 4 SWF Institute 2014, What is an SWF? Ibid., What is an SWF? 6 Ibid., What is an SWF? 7 Ibid., What is an SWF? 8 For the complete set of IMF categories on SWFs, see Abdullah Al-Hassan 2013, 5. 9 Weiss 2009, 5. 5 6 arise in states that are setting up SWFs to manage resource revenues, and help stabilize the government’s fiscal revenues.10 The second category of SWFs is savings funds, which are set up as a way to manage an inter-generational wealth transfer by investing a portion of the proceeds of non-renewable natural resources for future returns or to spur future development.11 Reserve investment corporations are the third category of SWF categorized by Weiss, which are funds created to “reduce the opportunity cost of holding excess foreign reserves.”12 Thus while the specific context of each SWF varies, it can be generally stated that every SWF falls into these one of these three broad categories. Based on the goals of the fund there are three broad categories into which most SWFs fall, and the circumstances that led to the creation of an SWF will influence how it is funded and invested. The SWFI states that SWFs can have their financial basis in either commodities, such as renewable and non-renewable resource extraction, or non-commodities, which are usually foreign exchange reserves.13 A 2008 IMF Working Paper conducted a survey of participants to the 2008 General Accepted Principles and Practices for SWFs, and found that the majority (67%) of respondents managed funds that were drawn from mineral royalties.14 Budget transfers, primarily of foreign exchange reserves, constituted the next major single category of transfers, with the remaining transfers stemming from a variety of sources.15 Commodities thus provide the basis for the majority of funds surveyed by the IMF, and commodity based funds are primarily set up as either stabilization funds or savings funds.16 Budget transfers of foreign reserves are 10 Ibid., 5. Ibid., 5. 12 Ibid., 6. 13 SWF Institute 2014, What is an SWF? 14 Hammer 2008, 4. 15 Ibid., 4. 16 Abdullah Al-Hassan 2013, 5. 11 7 non-commodity funds, and these funds are often organized as reserve investment corporations.17 The type of fund also indicates the type of investment strategy that will be employed. Stabilization funds emphasize liquidity and primarily focus on easing the cyclical nature of commodity prices, whereas savings funds assume a more high-risk investment stance to generate income for future generations or for socio-economic development.18 Non-commodity reserve investment corporations pursue high-return strategies often involving large investment in equities and leveraging debt.19 The investment strategy is thus contingent on the type of SWF that is created by the state, which is itself contingent on the type of funding the SWF is set up to manage. Alberta Heritage Savings Trust Fund The Alberta Heritage Savings Trust Fund (“Heritage Fund”) was created in 1976 to manage revenues stemming from Alberta’s immense non-renewable natural resource wealth, primarily from unconventional oil. The fund’s original goals were to share non-renewable resource wealth with future generations of Albertans, but also to support social projects and save for a “rainy day.”20 The legislation governing the Heritage Fund states the explicit mission of the fund as “WHEREAS the mission of the Heritage Fund is to provide prudent stewardship of the savings from Alberta’s non-renewable resources by providing the greatest financial returns on those savings for current and future generations of Albertans.”21 From this definition it is clear that the Heritage Fund, as its full name implies, falls into the savings fund category of SWFs. It was created by the Albertan government to invest a portion of 17 Ibid., 5. Ibid., 5. 19 Ibid., 5. 20 Murphy 2013, 5. 21 Province of Alberta 2013, 1. 18 8 the proceeds on non-renewable natural resources—primarily oil—in order to promote long-term economic prosperity for future generations of Albertans. This action by the Albertan government was an acknowledgement of the finite nature of non-renewable natural resources, and an attempt to share the wealth of their natural endowment across generations. The Heritage Fund was created as a savings fund to provide financial stewardship for the revenues of non-renewable natural resources in Alberta, but the government’s commitment to allocating revenues to the fund has changed over its history. Originally the government committed to allocating 30% of resource royalties to the fund, 22 which resulted in the Heritage Fund being valued at $4.7 billion by March 31 1979.23 However, the Government of Alberta slowly scaled back its contributions to the Heritage Fund and by 1987 ended completely the transfer of resource royalties to the fund.24 As well as altering the government’s contribution to the principal of the fund, in 1982 the fund no longer retained the income earned from its investments.25 These changes resulted in a roughly 20 year stagnation of the value of the fund, until a series of transfers occurred in the early 2000s, as shown in this chart.26 Since 2008 the value of the fund has again stagnated, and as of December 2013 it was valued at $17.4 billion 22 Smith 1980, 141. It is important to note that this $4.7 billion valuation includes a special one-time transfer of $1.5 billion from the Province of Alberta’s General Revenue Fund in 1976 (Milke 2008, 18). 24 Ibid., 18. 25 Ibid., 20. 26 Ibid., 20. 23 9 CAD.27 However, this trend is likely to change for the positive following the Alberta government’s decision to alter the savings policy such that the fund will once again retain its investment income starting in 2016-2017.28 The Heritage Fund will continue without a set contribution requirement, but the decision to allow the fund to keep its investment earnings will likely result in the renewed growth of the fund. While the exact funding scheme of the Heritage Fund has varied over the funds history, it has primarily been managed as a savings fund for the provinces natural resource wealth. The legislation that created the Heritage Fund stipulates that the Crown is the legal owner of the fund and that the Minister of Treasury Board and Finance is responsible for the management and investment of the fund.29 Originally the fund was almost entirely managed by Cabinet, with only a fraction of the funds invested being debated within the legislature.30 A legislative Select Standing Committee was established to approve the reports of the fund, but it acted only as a “post-facto” review body with no authoritative ability.31 During the pivotal 1997 restructuring of the Heritage Fund, a new Select Standing Committee was created that operates “at arm’s length” to ensure that the fund is meeting its legislative goals.32 Alberta took another step towards greater independence for the fund in 2008 by creating the Alberta Investment Management Corporation (AIMCo) as a Crown 27 Alberta Treasury Board and Finance 2014, Frequently Asked Questions. Ibid., Frequently Asked Questions. 29 Province of Alberta 2013, 2. 30 Smith 1980, 146. 31 Ibid., 146. 32 Milke 2008, 19. 28 10 corporation that manages the Heritage Fund.33 Thus while the fund began under highly central control, it has since gained greater autonomy in its investment management due to a series of policy reforms. A stated goal of the Heritage Fund was to provide future generations of Albertans with financial returns stemming from the exploitation of natural resources, which meant that how the funds were invested would be critical to meeting this goal. The legislative basis for investing the funds stipulates that the “investments of Heritage Fund assets must be made with the objective of maximizing long-term financial returns.”34 Public policy analysts have been critical of the early investment practices of the Heritage Fund, however, and assert that during the first two decades the fund focused on non-financial investment goals that limited the income earning capability of the fund.35 The 1997 restructuring of the fund shifted the investment focus towards financial gains in the long-term.36 The Heritage Fund’s asset mix as of December 2013, managed by AIMCo, was 54% in equities—most of them global and not Canadian—27% in inflation sensitive investments, and 19% in fixed income.37 This diversified asset mix has seen an 11.6% net return on investment during the 2013/2014 fiscal year, earning $1.7 billion in gross income.38 The focus on long-term growth has strengthened the fund’s ability to invest for future generations. However, while the Heritage Fund has shifted focus to maximizing long-term gains, the value of the fund has stagnated for years because of the government’s spending practices. 33 Province of Alberta 2007, 2. Province of Alberta 2013, 2. 35 Murphy 2013, 15. 36 Milke 2008, 19. 37 Alberta Ministry of Treasury Board and Finance 2014, 2. 38 Ibid., 2. 34 11 The Heritage Fund was established both to save for future generations and to support government programs, and these contradictory goals have resulted in spending practices of the Albertan government that do not reflect both of these goals equally. There are no legislative protections on the principal of the fund, which could be spent along with any income earned at any time by the government.39 The 1997 restructuring of the fund limited the government’s ability to spend the funds on special projects,40 but this did not stop the government from simply transferring any income earned by the fund to the provinces General Revenue Fund. Since the creation of the fund it has earned a total of $31.3 billion in income, of which $29.6 billion has been transferred to the legislature.41 The difference is kept in the fund due to legislative requirements that mandate the inflation proofing of the fund,42 or are investment expenses. In the 2013/2014 fiscal year current to December 2013, the government transferred $1.4 billion of the $1.7 billion income earned from the Heritage Fund to the General Revenue Fund.43 These earnings are then used by the government to support general government program spending.44 The spending practices of the government clearly emphasize current government spending over saving for future generations, and this has limited the ability of the Heritage Fund to act as a savings fund for future generations of Albertans. Alaska Permanent Fund In 1976 the Alaskan state government created the Alaska Permanent Fund to manage a portion of the revenues stemming from the exploitation of non-renewable natural resources, 39 Milke 2008, 20. Ibid., 19. 41 Murphy 2013, 13. 42 Province of Alberta 2013, 5. 43 Alberta Ministry of Treasury Board and Finance 2014, 2. 44 Alberta Treasury Board and Finance 2014. 40 12 particularly oil. To establish a SWF in Alaska required a constitutional amendment, so the Alaska citizens were asked by their government to vote on such an amendment that read: "At least twenty-five percent of all mineral lease rentals, royalties, royalty sale proceeds, federal mineral revenue sharing payments and bonuses received by the State shall be placed in a permanent fund, the principal of which shall be used only for those income-producing investments specifically designated by law as eligible for permanent fund investments. All income from the permanent fund shall be deposited in the general fund unless otherwise provided by law.”45 Alaska voters approved this constitutional amendment by a wide-margin,46 firmly placing the Permanent Fund within the constitutional fabric of the state. The Permanent Fund as created by this amendment was designed as a savings fund, and it featured set contribution minimums as well as strict rules governing the use of the principal and the earnings of the fund. As well, because the provisions of the fund are constitutionally entrenched, the state legislature cannot make major changes to the operation of the fund without further amendment to the constitution. The Alaska Permanent Fund is constitutionally mandated to receive a minimum of 25% of a range of revenues stemming from non-renewable natural resources in the state. This minimum contribution limit, when coupled with the constitutional prohibition of the state legislature to transfer money from the principal of the fund to the general fund of the legislature, has resulted in a very stable growth trend for the value of the fund. The government’s contributions to the principal of the fund include the transfer of a portion of non-renewable resource royalties, special legislative appropriations of earned income, and transfers to maintain the real 45 46 State of Alaska 1976. Alaska Permenant Fund Corporation 2013, FAQ. 13 value of the fund (inflation proofing).47 This graph illustrates the growth of the constitutionally protected principal of the fund from its creation until 2001,48 which shows an unambiguous upward trend in the value of the fund’s principal. As a result of the steady flow of revenues into the fund, it is currently valued at $51.7 billion USD, making it the largest fund of its kind in the United States.49 The constitutional requirements for allocating revenues to the fund has resulted in fund managers receiving steady flows and, barring investment losses, an ever increasing principal with which to invest for future generations of Alaskans. A major impetus behind the creation of the Permanent Fund was the concern over how the potential revenue from the large-scale exploitation of oil in Alaska was going to be managed. The constitution of Alaska declares that all natural resources belong to the citizens of Alaska, and the discovery of oil in 1968 quickly became a key issue for the public.50 The first auction of oil leases raised $900 million, and with no guidelines in place to manage these revenues, the state government had spent the entirety of these funds by 1976.51 The Permanent Fund was thus created as an entity that would ensure a portion of the revenues from non-renewable natural resources would be shielded from being spent immediately by the legislature.52 In the years following the creation of the Permanent Fund the legislature further decided that the fund should primarily be managed as a savings fund for future generations, rather than a fund used to promote current economic development.53 Having decided that the Permanent Fund was to be an intergenerational trust fund, in 1980 the legislature created the Alaska Permanent Fund 47 Milke 2008, 15. Anderson 2002, 63. 49 Alaska Permenant Fund Corporation 2013, FAQ. 50 Anderson 2002, 58. 51 Ibid., 59. 52 Ibid., 59. 53 Ibid., 59. 48 14 Corporation (APFC), a state-owned entity that would manage the assets of the fund.54 The Alaska legislature decided that entrusting a state-owned entity to manage the fund would increase the independence of the fund by reducing political interference, while at the same time holding the management of the fund accountable to the legislature and thus the people of Alaska.55 Since 1980 the AFPC has managed the investment of the Permanent Fund’s assets in accordance with the goals established by the Alaskan legislature. The Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation manages the assets of the fund, which are constitutionally bound to being invested in income-producing investments. Originally the fund was limited to only investing in fixed income investments, but the approved list of incomeproducing investments has since been expanded to enable the AFPC to invest in real estate and stocks.56 The investment goal of the AFPC is to “produce an average annual real rate of return of 5 percent over the long term” by investing in a broad portfolio diversified across different types of assets.57 Three pillars underlie the investment philosophy of the AFPC: 1) follow prudent investor guidelines in terms of investment risk; 2) assume enough risk to maximize returns in the long-run; and 3) use portfolio diversification as a method to both lower risk and maximize returns.58 Operating under these guidelines the AFPC invests in a diversified portfolio—of which the majority is equities—which in 2013 saw an overall 10.9% return across the entire portfolio, an income of $4.6 billion.59 The investor guidelines which the fund follows have resulted in a positive real rate of return, albeit of varying magnitudes, in every year since 1985.60 Maximizing 54 Alaska Permenant Fund Corporation 2013, About the APFC. Murphy 2013, 19. 56 Anderson 2002, 60. 57 Alaska Permenant Fund Corporation 2013, Investments. 58 Ibid., Investments. 59 Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation 2013, 4. 60 Ibid., 7. 55 15 long-term growth rates is critical to the success of any savings fund, but this is especially true for the Alaskan government because the constitutional basis for the fund allocates all income back into the state’s general revenue for general spending purposes. The constitutional amendment that created the Permanent Fund prohibits the legislature from allocating funds from the principal of the fund and instead transfers all income earned from the fund’s investments into the state’s general revenues. The income may be spent in any manner by the state government, but a major spending priority has been the Permanent Fund Dividend (PFD). Created by the legislature in 1982, the PFD is a unique element of the Permanent Fund. It is exactly what its name implies—it is a dividend from the investment income of fund payable to eligible Alaskan residents.61 Each year Alaskan residents receive a dividend from the income of the fund—giving every resident both a direct benefit from and a direct stake in the management of Alaska’s resource wealth.62 PFD payments constitute the single largest spending element of the Permanent Fund, and by 2009 had paid $17.5 billion to Alaskan residents.63 In recent years the average individual dividend payment has ranged between $1,000 and $1,500, which has helped make Alaska the most economically equal state in America while coinciding with robust economic growth.64 By paying dividends the Permanent Fund produces an immediate benefit to Alaskans, and by protecting the principal for future investments the fund will continue to act as a savings fund for future generations. 61 Widerquist 2012, 4. Widerquist 2012, 4. 63 Alaska Permenant Fund Corporation 2013, Dividend. 64 Widerquist 2012, 3. 62 16 Norwegian Pension Fund Global The Norwegian Pension Fund Global (hereafter referred to as the Petroleum Fund65) was created by the Norwegian national government in 1990 to manage revenues from the country’s oil industry. Oil was discovered in Norway in 1969, and the government had to decide how to manage the potentially large revenues that would be flowing into the state coffers.66 A committee of the legislature was created, and it recommended the creation of a state-owned fund that would both act as a savings fund for non-renewable natural resource revenues on behalf of future generations as well as insulate the domestic economy from the “resource curse” known as the “Dutch Disease.”67 In 1990 the government enacted the Government Petroleum Fund Act, which the Governor of the Norwegian central bank described as having four primary goals: “First: The totality of government petroleum revenues is transferred to the Fund. Second: The Fund is integrated into central government budgets and accounts. The non-oil deficit is covered by an annual transfer from the Fund. The government cannot borrow to finance current expenditure as long as there is capital in the Fund. Third: The capital in the Fund can only be used for domestic spending via general budget transfers, and not for earmarked transfers. Fourth: The Fund’s capital must be invested abroad.”68 This act created a SWF that has qualities of both savings funds and stabilization funds. It is a savings fund because it acts as an intergenerational wealth transferring vehicle for finite natural resources, but it is also a stabilization fund because it seeks to mitigate volatility in commodity markets from unduly affecting the domestic economy. It was created significantly later than the other two funds here examined, but it often regarded as the pinnacle of contemporary SWF management. 65 The Global Pension Fund Global was originally called the Petroleum Fund. The new name is a bit misleading, because the fund actually draws its revenues from oil revenues and not pensioners (SWF Institute 2014, Norway Government Pension Fund Global). The fund will be referred to as the Petroleum Fund in this paper for clarity. 66 Gjedrem 2010, Perspectives on managing the Government Pension Fund Global. 67 Chambers 2012, 68. 68 Ibid., Perspectives on managing the Government Pension Fund Global. 17 The Petroleum Fund is a commodity based SWF, and it receives the majority of its revenues from the proceeds of a non-renewable natural resource, oil. The complete list of funding includes oil revenues, proceeds from emissions taxes, as well as dividends from Statoil and revenue agreements.69 A distinguishing element of this fund is that all net proceeds from these revenue sources are deposited into the fund, not just a portion.70 This is known as an integrated budget model, where all revenue is initially deposited into the government’s general revenue, and then the net amount—the amount not used to cover the state’s non-oil deficit—is transferred to the Petroleum Fund.71 The first net-transfers occurred in 1996, and because the government had committed to transferring the entire net amount to the fund, the value of the fund quickly rose. This chart shows the staggering rise of the value of the Petroleum Fund,72 now the world’s largest SWF valued at $828 billion USD.73 Due to the large transfers to the fund, the Petroleum Fund has become a major component of the budget, despite the fact that oil production likely peaked in 2011.74 Managing the assets of the Petroleum Fund has thus become a critical matter for the Norwegian economy. The governance structure of the Petroleum Fund is designed to clearly delegate the responsibility for its management to different entities while maintaining democratic 69 Norway Ministry of Finance 2012, 1. Murphy 2013, 28. 71 Norges Bank 2014, About the Fund. 72 Norway Ministry of Finance 2014, 5. 73 SWF Institute 2014, Norway Government Pension Fund Global. 74 Chambers 2012, 68. 70 18 accountability. The Petroleum Fund is managed by two principal actors: the Norwegian government and Norges Bank, the Norwegian central bank. The Minister of Finance is accountable for the management of the Petroleum Fund to the legislature, the responsibility for which is delegated to the central bank.75 Originally the fund was managed by the central bank similar to its foreign exchange reserves,76 but in 1998 Norges Bank Investment Management (NBIM) was created as a sub-entity within the central bank charged with managing the assets of the fund.77 The governance structure is such that the Ministry of Finance is responsible for providing the goals, acceptable risk levels, as well as the rules and investment criteria for the Petroleum Fund while the everyday management occurs within NBIM.78 This relationship between the Ministry of Finance and NBIM determines the investment activities of the fund. The Norges Bank Investment Management unit invests the considerable assets of the Petroleum Fund based on guidelines established by the government. The core beliefs of the fund’s investment scheme are summarized as: maximizing long-term gains through diversification and earning risk premiums while maintaining a “commitment to responsible investing.” 79 The first guidelines focus on maximizing long-term gains by leveraging the fund’s large worth to generate significant income for future generations.80 The majority of the funds are in equities (60%), with the remaining funds investment in fixed-income activities (35-40%) and real estate (5%), all invested outside of Norway to avoid distorting the domestic economy.81 The commitment to responsible investing states that along with maximizing long-term gains, 75 Norges Bank 2014, Governance Structure. Gjedrem 2010, Perspectives on managing the Government Pension Fund Global. 77 Murphy 2013, 28. 78 Chambers 2012, 69. 79 Chambers 2012, 70. 80 Norges Bank 2014, Investment Strategy. 81 Ibid., Investment Strategy. 76 19 investments must also follow clear ethical guidelines.82 Responsible investing means prioritizing investments in companies that promote sustainability and follow established ethical guidelines, as well as excluding companies that do not meet the ethical criteria established by the government from the fund’s investment practices.83 The fund posted a nominal return rate of 15.9% in 201384, and since 1998 has earned a real return rate of 3.7%.85 The income earned by the fund has become a significant element of the budget, and it is estimated that by 2020 income from the fund alone will equal 8.45% of domestic GDP.86 The large principal and long-term investment strategy provide income which can be used to cover the non-oil deficit. Using the integrated budget method to manage the Petroleum Fund, the Norwegian government can use a portion for general spending. Unlike other SWFs which often transfer a portion or all of the income earned by the fund into the government’s general revenue, the Norwegian government first takes a portion of the gross revenues destined for the fund and withdraws an amount to cover the non-oil deficit.87 The amount that the government can spend from the gross proceeds is governed by the fiscal guidelines known as the budgetary rule. The budgetary rule states that the government may only spend 4% of the fund’s value annually, which is the fund’s anticipated long-run real return.88 This 4% has become a central element of the government’s budgets, and the Ministry of Finance estimates—albeit with considerable uncertainty—that the Petroleum Fund will cover 15% of government expenditure by 2020.89 These fiscal guidelines allow the government to spend considerable portions of the fund to 82 Norway Ministry of Finance 2014, 44. Norges Bank 2014, Responsible Investing. 84 Norway Ministry of Finance 2014, 5. 85 Norges Bank 2014, Returns. 86 Norway Ministry of Finance 2014, 5. 87 Murphy 2013, 31. 88 Chambers 2012, 69. 89 Norway Ministry of Finance 2014, 7. 83 20 support current generations, while at the same time transferring considerable sums of money to the Petroleum Fund to save for future generations. The balance of spending priorities between current and future generations is a key element of well-performing commodity-based SWFs. Conclusion This survey of the literature has provided a wealth of information which will be used to inform the comparative analysis of these three funds. All three of these funds fall into the category of commodity-based savings funds, with the goal of promoting sustainable economic growth from the exploitation of non-renewable natural resources. However, while all of the funds have the same primary goal, they each follow a different policy approach. Alberta’s Heritage Fund, valued at $16.4 billion USD, was the first SWF created in Canada. The Alberta model has no set contribution requirements and no restrictions on the government’s ability to spend the fund’s wealth. It is currently managed by the Crown corporation AIMCo, and is legislatively committed to focusing on maximizing long-term financial gains. The Alaskan Permanent Fund, valued at $51.7 billion USD, is the largest SWF in the United States. The Alaskan model commits the government to contributing at least 25% of resource revenues to the fund, and the government may only spend the income earned from its investments for general budgetary spending. APFC manages the fund, and is constitutionally committed to investing in income-producing investments. The Petroleum Fund of Norway, valued at $878 billion USD, is currently the largest SWF in the world. The Norwegian model has all resource revenues deposited into the fund, and fiscal guidelines that restrict the government’s ability to spend the wealth of the fund. The fund is managed by NBIM, which focuses on maximizing long-term gains while remaining committed to principles of responsible investment. These funds share common goals, are funded from the same natural resource, and yet have achieved varying 21 degrees of success. A major cause of this variation stems from the different policy frameworks that each government employed to manage their fund. This review of the literature will provide the information needed to analyze these competing models and to elucidate best practices. Findings The Literature Review has examined the SWFs with a primary focus on the five criteria established in the Purpose and Methodology section of this paper. The survey of the literature revealed that while the funds often share common goals, the different policy approaches taken towards SWFs by their respective governments has resulted in varying institutional frameworks, and ultimately, degrees of success. A summary of the three SWFs in relation to the Five Criteria Rubric is presented in the following chart. The information presented in this chart will be used in analyzing each criterion independently in an effort to examine how different policy frameworks have affected the relative success of each fund. Heritage Fund 90 Contribution Requirements No set contribution requirements. Management Agency Crown corporation (AIMCo) as of 2008, previously government committee. Investment Strategy Legislation requires focus on maximizing long-term gains; equities major element. Spending Ability No protection of principal, currently all income transferred to general revenue. Total Valuations $16.4 billion, ~$4,500 per capita.90 SWF Institute 2014, Heritage Fund Profile. 22 Permanent Fund Minimum 25% of resource royalties deposited annually. State-owned Entity (APFC) as of 1980. Petroleum Fund All resource revenues are deposited annually. Branch of central bank (NBIM) as of 1998, previously general central bank management. Constitutionally bound to invest in incomeproducing investments, primarily equities. Set by government, with focus on maximizing long-term gains and responsible investments. Principal is constitutionally protected, only income may be spent, primarily done so on dividend. Set by fiscal guidelines; government may spend 4% of the funds value annually for general spending. $51.7 billion, ~$70,000 per capita.91 $878 billion, ~$173,000 per capita.92 Contribution Requirements Resource revenues transferred to an SWF act as the principal for long-term investments, which can further increase the value of the fund. Two of the funds examined have set contribution requirements, while the other fund, Alberta’s Heritage Fund, does not. The lack of set contribution requirements has resulted in a very different outcome for the Heritage Fund when compared with the other funds. A 2013 Fraser Institute study found that if Alberta had followed the Alaskan model the principal of the fund would be worth nearly 4.5 times as much as it is currently valued at, and if it had followed the Norwegian model the principal of the fund would be approximately 18.5 times larger than it was at the time of the survey.93 As the growth of the principal is not dependent on a successful investment strategy but rather government contributions, the underfunding of the Heritage Fund relative to the other funds examined is primarily a result of the lack of a formal commitment on behalf of the government to contribute 91 Ibid., AFPC Profile. Ibid., GPFG Profile. 93 Murphy 2013, 35. 92 23 resource revenues to the fund.94 The exact level will depend on the circumstances of the SWF, but setting a contribution requirement will better enable a savings fund SWF to share resource wealth by promoting stable principal growth. This paper views contribution requirements as a positive principle of SWF governance, and thus in terms of the established criteria the Permanent Fund and the Petroleum Fund satisfy the requirement for a strong SWF governance framework and the Heritage Fund does not. Management Agency Sovereign wealth funds are primarily managed either within the government or by an independent management agency, and for the purposes of this analysis such an agency will be interpreted as a positive principle of SWF management. Properly instituted independent management agencies are beneficial because they limit political interference into the fund’s management while still remaining accountable to the government.95 The more political influence is allowed to intrude into the management of the fund, the more likely it is that the investment strategy will favour short-term investment projects that satisfy government economic policy rather than long-term financial gains.96 All three of the funds examined are currently managed by an independent agency of some form, and this is a clear indication that independent management agencies are key elements of any SWF policy framework. Another key distinguishing variable between the three funds is at what point they created their management agency. Both the Alaskan and Norwegian governments created management agencies within years of the creation of the fund, while the Alberta government took decades to 94 Ibid., 5. Das 2009, 13. 96 Bernstein 2013, 220. 95 24 do so, instead opting to manage the fund through a Select Standing Committee of the legislature. This resulted in significant political inference in the management of the fund in the early years that affected its performance.97 Thus while all three funds currently satisfy the rubric’s criterion for possessing a management agency, the experience with the Heritage Fund illustrates that a government creating a SWF should also plan to create a management agency early so as to minimize the risk of political interference negatively affecting the management of the fund. Investment Strategy For SWFs created as savings funds, having an investment strategy that focuses on maximizing long-term financial gains is critical to the success of the fund. All three governments have committed to following long-term investment strategies, either by means of legislation or constitutional amendment. As a result of this long-term focus, all three funds currently have a majority of their portfolio invested in equities, which exhibit strong long-term financial gains. However, there are several other major factors that affect the ideal investment strategy, and one of them is the acceptable level of risk. The level of tolerated risk will impact the investment strategy of the SWF, and a fund focused on a long-term investment horizon should be willing to accept assuming a modest amount of risk.98 Assuming risk can be challenging for newly created SWFs though, for negative returns early on can be detrimental both financially and politically.99 Newly created funds can mitigate this risk by adopting low risk strategies early, and slowly increase the levels of risk as the funds ‘buffer’ increases.100 Adopting a risk-averse investment 97 Mumey 1990, 32. Das 2009, 14. 99 Ibid., 15. 100 Ibid., 15. 98 25 strategy early and assuming more risk as the fund matures allows states to mitigate the potential ramifications of early losses. Another key benefit of commodity SWFs is that by investing the revenues of commodity booms outside of the domestic economy the country can help alleviate the negative effects of the resource curse. Thus along with accepting moderate levels of risk, a savings fund SWF should also prioritize long-term investments in global markets to help the domestic economy from being afflicted by the ‘Dutch Disease.’101 All three funds examined in this paper currently follow investment strategies that satisfy the criteria established, and provide evidence that a good SWF investment strategy should focus on maximizing long-term gains rather than short-term policy goals. Spending Ability A major goal of many commodity SWFs is to promote sustainable economic growth from the development of natural resources, and how states decide to spend the wealth generated from a SWF is critical to ensuring sustainability. The wealth of commodity SWFs can be spent on anything from endowments to dividends, and the exact spending practices of a SWF depend heavily on the circumstances of its sovereign manager. However, while the spending ability of an SWF might be more contextual than the other factors here examined, the survey of the literature did illuminate several general guidelines of SWF management. First, the experiences of the Heritage and Permanent Funds highlight the importance of protecting the principal of the fund from being spent. The Alaskan model constitutionally protects the principal of the fund, whereas the Albertan model currently has no protection for the fund’s principal. This lack of protection, 101 Bernstein 2013, 223. 26 coupled with the absence of resource revenue contributions and the complete withdrawal of all income has contributed to the stagnation of the value of the Heritage Fund.102 Along with protecting the principal, the Norwegian experience indicates that governments should exercise restraint and commit to only spending a portion of the fund’s wealth annually. While there is some concern that the Norwegian fiscal guidelines allow slightly too much to be spent annually,103 it is still an improvement from the volatile spending practices the Norwegian government followed with respect to its petroleum revenue windfalls prior to the creation of its SWF.104 Thus while the spending ability of the SWF will depend heavily on the circumstances of the sovereign manager, creating legislative protections on the government’s ability to spend the fund’s value, either by protecting the principal or committing to spending a sustainable amount of the fund’s wealth annually, is a principle of strong SWF management which only the Permanent Fund and the Petroleum Fund follow. Total Valuations The total valuation of a SWF is in itself a function of the other principles of SWF management, and evaluating a fund’s total worth is analytically similar to evaluating the fund itself. How much the fund is worth depends on a vector of variables, such as how much the government contributes to the fund, how the fund is invested and how successful the investments are, how the government decides to spend the income earned by the fund, and a host of other factors. The danger of using the total valuation of the fund as a measure of the success of a policy model is that some of the most important variables affecting commodity SWFs depend not on the model itself but on the nature of a state’s resource endowment and the performance of the 102 Milke 2008, 20. Chambers 2012, 69. 104 Bernstein 2013, 222. 103 27 commodity market. However, given that all the funds examined here are funded through the same commodity, and given that all of them have ample resource endowments—albeit some states more so than others—this paper will interpret the total value of the SWF as a measure of its success, with the caveat that the total value is a function of many factors some of which are outside the analytical scope of this paper. The three funds evaluated examined in this paper have each followed different policy frameworks, and these frameworks have contributed to varying levels of success as measured by net worth. The Heritage Fund, valued at $16.4 billion USD, is the lowest valued of the three funds. The low total valuation relative to the other funds can be contributed to several factors, the most important of which are the lack of contribution requirement and the constant raiding of the fund’s investment income. While the fund has—eventually—adopted sound management and investment strategies, the twin afflictions of low to zero contributions and revenue raiding are serious faults of the Alberta model. The Permanent Fund, valued at $51.7 billion USD, is the middle-ranked SWF evaluated and has achieved this status as a result of a strong policy framework. It has set contribution requirements, follows sound management and investment policies that promote long-term growth, and ensures stable spending practices through the constitutional protection of the principal. Overall the Alaskan model of SWF management is robust, and even superior to the Norwegian model in key areas, such as the protection of the principal. However, the Petroleum Fund, valued at $878 billion USD, is the highest valued SWF in the world and the best preforming SWF examined in this paper. Like the Alaskan model, the Norwegian model follows prudent management and investment strategies, and is legislatively committed to only spending a portion of the funds worth annually. The key difference between the two models is the level of resource contributions made to the funds. While committing at 28 least 25% has resulted in stable growth of the Permanent Fund, the Norwegian model of committing all resource revenues has resulted in the phenomenal growth of the Petroleum Fund. The growth of the Petroleum Fund has been such that the fund will continue to be a major element of the government’s annual budget for decades to come.105 This is the type of economic sustainability that saving fund SWFs aspire to, and it is why this paper views the Norwegian model as the strongest model of SWF management examined. Conclusion Each of the three SWFs examined in the paper have followed different policy approaches, and this Findings sections has evaluated each of the funds based on five criteria with the goal of determining the strongest principles, and ultimately models, of SWF management. While each of the funds has its strengths, it is the Norwegian model that best satisfies the criteria of this paper, and thus it is the principles that define this model, as well as the best principles of the other models, that will be used to inform the development of a SWF in British Columbia. Recommendations The Government of British Columbia’s plans to develop the significant LNG reserves in the province will have large impacts on the British Columbian economy, and the plans to create a SWF funded through a portion of the revenues from LNG could help promote sustainable economic growth from the exploitation of a non-renewable natural resource. Many resource rich states have begun creating SWFs to act as savings funds, and British Columbian policymakers have the benefit of being able to learn from the successes, and failures, of other SWFs. B.C. should adopt the best practices of SWF governance when creating the Prosperity Fund, and the 105 Norway Ministry of Finance 2012, 7. 29 preceding comparative analysis of the Albertan, Alaskan, and Norwegian SWFs have illuminated some of these best practices that B.C. should consider. Recommendation One Set contribution requirements in legislation that commit the government to contributing all LNG revenues annually. The Government of B.C. has ambitious plans for the Prosperity Fund, and these plans are possible only if the government establishes firm contribution requirements. The government plans to use the fund to pay down the provincial debt, reduce the tax burden on B.C. families, and provide funding for government programs.106 As well, the government has claimed that over the next 30 years the Prosperity Fund will grow to $100 billion CDN.107 Only one fund examined in this paper, the Norwegian Petroleum Fund, is valued over $100 billion CDN, primarily because the government has committed to depositing all resource revenues into the fund. A modified Alaskan model that contributes 50% or above of resource revenues could also be a solution, but given the more volatile nature of the LNG market relative to the petroleum market, the safest method to ensure the government’s policy target is achieved is to commit all LNG revenues to the Prosperity Fund. Recommendation Two Delegate the authority to manage the Prosperity Fund to an independent and accountable management agency, such as a Crown corporation. The Government of B.C. must take actions that will serve to insulate the management of the Prosperity Fund from political interference. All three funds examined have delegated the management of their respective SFWs to management agencies. The major difference between 106 107 Province of BC 2013, New British Columbia Prosperity Fund Will Ensure Lasting Benefits. Ibid., New British Columbia Prosperity Fund Will Ensure Lasting Benefits. 30 the three funds is that the Heritage and Permanent Funds are managed by state-owned corporations, whereas the Petroleum Fund is managed by the Norwegian central bank. Having the fund managed by the central bank may actually be advantageous relative to a state-owned enterprise, as they can utilize existing resources and in doing so minimize the fixed costs associated with creating a new entity.108 However, the Government of B.C., as a subnational government, cannot externalize the costs of its management onto a national central bank and must instead follow the Albertan and Alaskan model of creating a state-owned entity. B.C. can limit its expenses, however, by delegating the management of the Prosperity Fund to an already existing Crown corporation. The British Columbian Investment Management Corporation (bcIMC) is a Crown corporation that manages a variety of public sector funds valued over $100 billion CDN.109 Independent management agencies are beneficial elements of SWF governance, and tasking bcIMC to manage the Prosperity Fund would serve to both minimize potential political interference and minimize the capital costs of creating a new Crown corporation. Recommendation Three Ensure the investment guidelines for the Prosperity Fund prioritize long-term financial gain. Saving fund SWFs can promote long-term economic growth from short-term resource exploitation by investing resource revenues for future generations. However, a key element to ensuring that the fund can fulfill its inter-generational wealth-sharing purpose requires an investment strategy that focuses on maximizing long-term gains over short-run policy goals. The Albertan, Alaskan, and Norwegian funds all have investment strategies that focus, to varying degrees, on maximizing long-term financial gain. While this does mean assuming more risk, 108 109 Das 2009, 13. British Columbia Investment Management Corporation 2013. 31 focusing on long-term gains will increase the potential for investment income to further raise the value of the fund in line with the government’s goals. Thus including requirements for the fund to pursue income-earning activities, similar to the other funds, is a policy approach that should be included in the creation of the Prosperity Fund. Recommendation Four Adopt a risk-averse investment stance during the first years of the Prosperity Fund to allow the fund to accumulate wealth, and slowly include more risk into the investment strategy so as to meet the requirements for maximizing long-term gains. Assuming risk is a necessary part of an investment strategy that focuses on long-term gains; however, a newly created fund does not need to adopt such an investment strategy from the very beginning. Adopting a risk-averse strategy in the formative years will allow the fund time to accumulate wealth and ease the public in to the newly created SWF. Hosting the fund within an existing Crown corporation, such as bcIMC, will also help limit the fixed costs of establishing the new fund. As the fund matures, the government can decide when to begin assuming more risk in order to maximize long-term financial gains. Recommendation Five Establish a set of fiscal guidelines that limit the amount of annual spending that can be made from the Prosperity Fund. The Prosperity Fund envisaged by the government serves two primary purposes: enable future saving and current spending. Saving for the future requires investing revenues, and current spending requires allocating revenue from the fund to the government’s annual budget. To ensure that both goals are met, the government must commit to only spending a sustainable portion of the fund annually while leaving the remainder to be invested. The Heritage Fund highlights the dangers of a government failing to restrict its ability to spend the fund’s wealth, as 32 constant revenue raiding has contributed to the multi-year stagnation of the value of the fund. Either the Alaskan model of protecting the principal or the Norwegian model of restricting spending to 4% of the funds worth annually could be followed in B.C. to allow for sustainable spending of the fund’s wealth. Enabling governments to spend portions of the fund annually is important, but the government must ensure that any annual spending done is sustainable and contributes to the long-term goals of the fund. Conclusion Developing British Columbia’s vast LNG reserves has tremendous potential for the B.C. economy, and the government’s decision to invest LNG revenues into the Prosperity Fund can help alleviate the negative effects of resource windfalls while at the same time save for future generations. Many states in the world have created SWFs for similar purposes, and the experience of other states can inform the development of such a fund in British Columbia. The five recommendations presented here have come from a comparative analysis of three contextually relevant SWFs, and are intended to help inform the development of the B.C. Prosperity Fund. While these recommendations are not authoritative, they provide insight into the best practices of SWF management that could be used in B.C. to promote long-term economic prosperity. 33 Bibliography Abdullah Al-Hassan, Michael Papaioannou, Martin Skancke,. IMF Working Paper: Sovereign Wealth Funds: Aspects of Governance Structures and Investment Management. Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 2013. Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation. Evolving: Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation 2013 Annual Report. Annual Financial Report, Juneau: Alaska Permanent Fund Coprporation, 2013. Alaska Permenant Fund Corporation. Alaska Permenant Fund Corporation. 2013. http://www.apfc.org/home/Content/aboutFund/fundHistory.cfm (accessed June 3, 2014). Alberta Ministry of Treasury Board and Finance. Alberta Heritage Savings Trust Fund: THIRD QUARTER 2013 –2014. Quarterly Report, Edmonton: Alberta Ministry of Treasury Board and Finance, 2014. Alberta Treasury Board and Finance. Heritage Fund - Frequently Asked Questions. March 3, 2014. http://www.finance.alberta.ca/business/ahstf/faqs.html (accessed June 1, 2014). Anderson, Jonathan. "The Alaska Permenant Fund: Politics and Trust." Public Bugdeting and Finance, 2002: 57-68. BC Liberal Party. Strong Economy, Secure Tomorrow. Platform, BC Liberal Party, 2013. Bernstein, Shai, Josh Lerner, and Antoinette Schoar. "The Investment Strategies of Sovereign Wealth Funds." American Economic Association, 2013: 219-237. British Columbia Investment Management Corporation. Company Profile. 2013. http://www.bcimc.com/about/companyprofile.asp. Chambers, David, Elroy Dimson and Antti Ilmanen. "The Norway Model." Journal Of Portfolio Management, 2012: 67-81. Das, Udaibir S., Yinqiu Lu, Christian Mulder, and Amadou Sy. IMF Working Papers : Setting up a Sovereign Wealth Fund : Some Policy and Operational Considerations. Working Paper, Washington D.C.: International Montary Fund, 2009. Gjedrem, Svein. Perspectives on managing the Government Pension Fund Global. Govenor's Speech, Oslo: Norges Bank, 2010. Hammer, Cornelia Petrova, Iva Kunzel, Peter. IMF Working Papers : Sovereign Wealth Funds : Current Institutional and Operational Practices. Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund (IMF) , 2008. Milke, Mark. Restoring Peter Lougheed's Original Vision: A 2008 Comparison of Alberta's Heritage Savings Trust Fund and the Alaska Permanent Fund. Winnipeg: Frontier Centre for Public Policy , 2008. 34 Mumey, Glen and Joseph Ostermann. "Alberta Heritage Fund: Measuring Value and Achievement." Canadian Public Policy, 1990: 29-50. Murphy, Robert P. Clemens, Jason. Reforming Alberta's Heritage Fund: Lessons from Alaska and Norway. Vancouver: Fraser Institute, 2013. Norges Bank. Norges Bank Investment Management. April 4, 2014. http://www.nbim.no/en/ (accessed June 5, 2014). Norway Ministry of Finance. Provisions on the management of the Government Pension Fund: Unofficial translation from Norwegian. For information purposes only. Legislation, Oslo: Norway Ministry of Finance, 2012. Norway Ministry of Finance. Report No. 19 to the Storting: The Management of the Government Pension Fund in 2013 . Annual Report, 2014: Norway Ministry of Finance, 2014. Province of Alberta. Alberta Heritage Savings Trust Fund Act: Revised Statutes of Alberta 2000 Chapter A-23. Legislation, Edmonton: Alerta Queen's Printer, 2013. Province of Alberta. Alberta Investment Management Corporation Act: Statues of Alberta 2007, Chapter A-26.5. Legislation, Edmonton: Alberta Queen's Printer, 2007. Province of BC. New British Columbia Prosperity Fund Will Ensure Lasting Benefits. Government News Release, Victoria: Province of BC, 2013. Smith, Roger S. "The Alberta Heritage Savings Trust Fund: Introduction." Canadian Public Policy, 1980: 141-157. State of Alaska. The Constitution of the State of Alaska: Article 9 Section 15. Constitution, Anchorage: State of Alaska, 1976. SWF Institute. What is an SWF? 2014. http://www.swfinstitute.org/sovereign-wealth-fund/ (accessed May 27, 2014). Weiss, Martin A. "Sovereign Wealth Funds: Background and Policy Issues for Congress." In Sovereign Wealth Funds , by Thomas N. Litmann, William P. Carson, 1-20. Hauppauge, NY, USA : Nova Science Publishers, Inc., 2009. Widerquist, Karl and Michael W. Howard. " Introduction: Success in Alaska ." In Alaska's permanent fund dividend: examining its suitability as a model, by Karl and Michael W. Howard Widerquist, 3-12. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2012. 35