VOLUME 2, N O . 1 M AY 2006 FRONT MATTER 3 Editor’s Note NOTES 4 The French Social Model in Times of Globalisation Riccardo Brizzi 12 A Hollow Hopelessness: Shortfalls in Unidimensional Demand for Law Models Jonathan C. Bond ARTICLES 26 New Labour’s Ethical Foreign policy With Regards to China Kayte Rath 64 The Domestic Politics of Thailand’s Bilateral Free Trade Agreement Policy Pajnapa Peamsilpakulchorn INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC POLICY REVIEW Editorial Staff, Volume 2 (2005/06): General Editors Erika Carlsson, MSc International Public Policy, External communication Alesa Esmond, MSc International Public Policy, Submissions editor Mette Ostergaard, MSc International Public Policy, Futures projects Adam Landsman, MSc International Public Policy, Webmaster Stephen Lee, MSc International Public Policy, Editorial review Joshua Mendelsohn, PhD School of Public Policy, Internal communication Jo Setters, MSc International Public Policy, Coordinator Academic Review Panel Dr. Fiona Adamson, chair Dr. David Coen Dr. Fabio Franchino Dr. David Hudson Dr. Jennifer van Heerde Editorial Board Jorge Alday, MSc International Public Policy Erika Carlsson, MSc International Public Policy Ruihua Chang, MSc International Public Policy Laurence Hopkins, MSc Public Policy Sven Kerpen, PhD School of Public Policy Adam Landsman, MSc International Public Policy Ernest Lau, MSc Public Policy Stephen Lee, MSc International Public Policy Jonathan McClory, MSc International Public Policy Joshua Mendelsohn, PhD School of Public Policy Mette Ostergaard, MSc International Public Policy Jinnifer Park, MSc International Public Policy Nikki Salisbury, MSc Public Policy Jo Setters, MSc International Public Policy Amina Shafi, MSc International Public Policy Manpreet Sidhu, MSc International Public Policy Cristina Tiron, MSc International Public Policy Tim Weeple, MSc International Public Policy The INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC POLICY REVIEW (ISSN: 1748-5207) is a peerreviewed, student-edited, and faculty-supervised academic journal published semiannually by the University College London School of Public Policy, London, UK. IPPR welcomes submissions from faculty and postgraduate students of any educational institution, of both Articles (original empirical investigations, between 8000 and 15000 words) and Essays/Notes (empirical or scholarly commentary pieces, between 3000 and 5500 words). All submissions are reviewed anonymously. The Academic Review Panel and the plenary session of the Editorial Board must also approve pieces selected for publication by anonymous referees. Manuscripts may be submitted electronically to ippr@ucl.ac.uk or sent in hard copy to the address below. (For non-electronic submissions, two copies must be provided, and manuscripts will not be returned.) All submissions must include the Submission Form and conform to the style and formatting guidelines provided at: http://www.ucl.ac.uk/spp/ippr/submissions/ To request article reprints, to submit non-electronic manuscripts, as well as for comments or other queries, please contact: General Editors, INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC POLICY REVIEW , School of Public Policy, University College London, 29/30 Tavistock Square, London, WC1H 9QU, United Kingdom. For the most recent issue and article archives, please visit IPPR online at: http://www.ucl.ac.uk/spp/ippr/. INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC POLICY REVIEW , vol. 2, no. 1 (May 2006). [ ISSN 1748-5207] © 2006 by The School of Public Policy, University College London, London, United Kingdom. All rights reserved. EDITORS’ NOTE Vol. 2, No. 1 Last year this journal published its inaugural edition and took a step out into the field of international public policy, with the acknowledgement that the field was subject to a certain amount of definitional ambiguity. Undoubtedly it will take a while longer to generate a broad agreement in the academic world on the meaning of public policy as an international phenomenon or, to put it another way, on the relevance of international issues to public policy. Competing definitions are nothing unusual in academia, least of all in the social sciences. It reflects, in part, the fact that there are different viewpoints on complex phenomena. In the present case it is also a result of an emerging discipline, or inter-disciplinary field, that has not yet established its place in the academic firmament. It does not, however, mean that there are no boundaries to the scope of study. Nor does it imply that there are no immediately recognisable international public policy issues, based on the definition that was adopted in the first issue of this journal: that it pertains to areas of governance and public policy that are either international or strongly affected by international factors. At the time of writing, to name but a few of the contemporary issues that our definition covers, there are important debates about the future structure and role of the International Monetary Fund; the proper international response to the insistence by Iran of proceeding with its nuclear programme; the increasing doubt over whether the Doha Round in the W TO will deliver what has been hoped for it; the prospects for deeper integration within the European Union and possibilities for future enlargement. The articles in this edition nicely illustrate elements of the evolving definition of this field of study by relating to areas that are recognisably concerned with international dimensions of public policy. Some of them examine the impact of international issues on national policymaking whilst others consider national policy making with an international aspect. In The Domestic Politics of Thailand’s Bilateral Free Trade Agreement Policy, Pajnapa Peamsilpakulchorn gives a detailed account of the domestic politics that have accompanied that country’s policy of developing international trade agreements, including significant agreements with both Japan and the United States. Kayte Rath takes a very different look at domestic policy making. In this case, New Labour’s Ethical Foreign policy With Regards to China considers the extent to which the ethical considerations, which the British government professed to hold dear, have been maintained in the light of contemporary events. 3 4 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W In A Hollow Hopelessness: Shortfalls in Unidimensional Demand for Law Models, Jonathan Bond centres his analysis on the demand for legal institutions in transition countries by placing the question firmly in the current literature on the subject. Finally, in The French Social Model in Times of Globalisation, Riccardo Brizzi presents a point of view on the way the French are adjusting, or perhaps not adjusting, to the changing international environment. This piece might represent a rather unconventional approach for a typical academic journal yet helps us to meet our goal of locating the International Public Policy Review at the centre of both fine scholarship and timely debate. Each of these papers provides a well-considered viewpoint on some aspect of international public policy. Taken together, they begin to outline the scope and breadth of this emerging field. We hope that they will provide stimulating reading for anybody interested in the subject. Jo Setters Erika Carlsson Alesa Esmond Ada m Landsman Stephen Lee Joshua Mendelsohn Mette Østergaard London May 2006 THE FRENCH SOCIAL MODEL IN TIMES OF GLOBALISATION Riccardo Brizzi The 29th May 2005 took the lid off Pandora’s Box and out of it has come the deep-seated fears of a France with an identity crisis, barely able to recognise itself. 1 Used to the grandiose venture, the country is all at once devoid of ideas, incapable of acting at a critical moment of history when relations with the United States are at low ebb and Europe lies in deadlock. Concomitantly, terrorism has raised its head once more and new powers have pushed themselves onto the international scene demanding the political and economic status that their demographic weight would seem to warrant. France, then, is ill at ease, questioning itself and increasingly doubtful. A nation that has always proudly stood as an example to others, traditionally an exporter of ideas and values, now realises it is condemned to look outside its own borders to learn a few recipes from others outside the Francophone world - a realisation at odds with Chirac’s proud remarks on the superiority of ‘French cuisine.’ 2 1. ANXIOUS GLANCES ACROSS THE CHANNEL: ANY ALTERNATIVES TO THE ANGLO -S AXON MODEL ? Eyes are being turned primarily across the English Channel. Suddenly, Blair has become omnipresent in the French political chatter, and especially inside the ragbag gauche. Coming to power neck and neck with ‡ Contact with questions/comments: ricbrizzi@yahoo.it. Jacques Julliard, Le Malheur français (Paris: Flammarion, 2005). 2 An expression ineptly used by Chirac just before allocation of the Olympics 2012 as he was boasting of the alleged superiority of France over England. 1 INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC POLICY REVIEW , vol. 2, no. 1 (May 2006): 5-12. [ ISSN 1748-5207] © 2006 by The School of Public Policy, University College London, London, United Kingdom. All rights reserved. 4 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 5 Jospin in 1997, the Labour leader has been eyed suspiciously in France, though European socialism might have welcomed the man who ended the seemingly absolute reign of accursed Torydom. With nearly ten years of his leadership, the exponent of the ‘Third Way’, who has faced much criticism from within his own party, has nonetheless come to stand as an inevitable reference point wherever Frenchmen are concerned. Whether these debates happen to be over globalisation, Europe or the social model, the spectre of Blair has always been tangible. While he is still seen as peddling too liberal a model – suspect, therefore 3 - and none of his countless faults are overlooked (including failure to waive the ‘British cheque’), it is coming to be admitted that the man’s dynamism and the results he has achieved can no longer be ignored. British hostility to the text was cited by many ‘yes’ supporters to bolster their own position; though few later blamed the British leader when it was found that business could not ‘continue as usual’ after France and the Netherlands had passed their sentence without appeal. A sudden and surprising convergence of views seems to have made Blair the new European leader – though the distinct absence of alternatives counts for more than any whole-hearted acceptance of his reform plans. There are cases, found beyond the French frontier too, of Blair’s proposed model being rejected as some kind of ‘hallowing’ of economics; that this upstages the institutional and constitutional axis of the European Union and would lead to the “definitive scrapping of the European political project” as envisaged and worked for in previous decades.4 For instance, the ex-secretary of Force Ouvrière, Marc Blondel, recently wrote that France should not be busying itself with accounts and deficits; that what is needed is “less pragmatism and more ideology.”5 However, one might respectfully point out that, though heavily skewed by the allowance for the CAP, the European budget (which the ‘Sapir report’ 6 dubbed ‘a historical relic’ in 2003,) has been by no means a futile dissection of technicalities, but the working out of a proper political programme as a guideline for Union policy over the next seven years. Likewise, opening up a serious discussion of the European social model hardly deprives Europe from its influential position as a political institution, but is the only way to letting it find an answer to the challenges being forced on it by today’s world. It was thus Blair’s 1st July statement, one week before his opening address as British president of the Union, spelling out the need to revise a ‘social model’ that tolerates 3 Christian Julienne, Le diable est-il liberal? (Paris: Belles Lettres, 2001). Gian Enrico Rusconi, "Se cessiamo di essere Europa," Il Mulino 4 (2005): 617-618. 5 Marc Blondel, "Le système français est le plus juste que je connaisse," Le Point 1718 (2005): 50. 6 André Sapir, ed., Europa, un’agenda per la crescita. Rapporto Sapir (Bologna: il Mulino, 2004). 4 6 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W twenty million unemployed, which turned the Labour leader into a protagonist of the debate preoccupying the French over the last year. And to be honest, if compared to the hapless French model, the Anglo-Saxon way cannot be denied a measure of success. The economic pointers are set fair: good growth, low unemployment index, and high per capita mean income. For all its undoubted distortions, Thatcherism left a heritage of flexible income and employment conditions well suited to a monetarist policy (the rigidity of monetarism needs flexible accompanying social conditions). In the ‘Euro zone’, currency at once became a ‘sacred cow’ raised to some meta-political plane, and the clearest proof of this is that national governments can no longer play with deficits in the balance. Such monetary rigidity, almost of necessity, calls for a flexible variable on the side of employment and incomes.7 If one opts for a right-wing economic policy, it ought to be flanked by a right-wing ‘social’ structure (it is worth noting that, in the last five years Great Britain has doubled its public outlay on education and transport, and increased its health budget by two thirds). In the Euro area, by contrast, we have a contradiction which is laying bare all its limitations: on the one hand, we have opted for the tightest of economic policies, left in the hands of a central European bank that enjoys total independence; on the other hand, we have kept up a level of social protection which refuses to come into line with the standards required by flexibility. The Union thus contains inside it a strange sort of ‘hybrid’: a ‘right-wing’ economic policy and a ‘left-wing’ social structure. If that is possible when there are enough resources to go round, it is not so in times of international recession; the inevitable result is increasing stagnation and unemployment. 2. THE END OF THE ‘DELORS MORTGAGE ’ AND THE FRENCH IDEOLOGICAL DESERT If France wishes to return to a leading role in Europe, as was argued in a long editorial in Le Monde by Jean-Marie Colombani,8 it must start by regaining legitimacy in the eyes of its own citizens. It is no accident that the heated referendum debate is still being waged in a ‘domestic’ version, mirroring the positions that crystallised on 29th May, but shifting the object of debate from the European to the French social model, which is the main ‘arraignee’ in today’s crisis. Designed to accompany the rebuilding and expansion of the Trente Glorieuses and never seriously reformed, the French model proved unable to accommodate the crisis of the Seventies and Eighties, let alone the new challenges of globalisation. If 7 Jean-Marc Ferry, "Face à la crise, quelles perspectives pour l’Union européenne?" Politique etrangère, 3 (2005): 511-522. 8 Le Monde, "La France à son rang", September 13, 2005. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 7 it worked in the form of an adjunct to the original ‘mixed’ French system of several decades back, it has failed to respond amid the global and financial capitalism typical of this first sliver of the twenty-first century. It has been some time since this subject occupied the centre of political attention: we would have to go back to the end of the Seventies, at least, just before the rise of Mitterand in 1981, when it was last a real pivot of the debate. First the social-democrat watershed of 1983, and then a series of swings and alliances gradually sucked it dry of interest, until it returned to the scene in a leading part with the European referendum. The one clear starting point, and the only clear issue in a welter of confused arguments, seems to be the end of the ‘Delors mortgage’ on French political life: the demise of what the philosopher A.M. Rieu has dubbed “the delusion that has prevailed, to left and right, over French political and social life ever since the late Seventies.”9 The same argument has been voiced on the other side of the Atlantic by the political analyst B.E. Barber in The American Prospect.10 Arising in the wake of the great energy crisis, the Delors ‘delusion’ rested on the conviction that the domestic markets should progressively unify to the point of achieving a sole currency, with all other arguments shelved for future consideration. His basic assumption was that the European peoples, French more than any, would not accept growing integration of their economic systems unless existing social policies were defended. However, contrary to those predictions, this has actually proved to be a trap, slowing down social and political harmonisation across the continent and giving rise to a sole market far in advance of the political and social systems that have in this way been shielded from all reform. Dissociating economics from politics and social planning has produced a backlog that can only be made good by thorough reform within each country’s national social system. The withering away of the ‘Delors mortgage’ model has not been accompanied by any alternative proposal. Even to set up a debate becomes difficult now that the traditional political and ideological categories for understanding the French political scene have suddenly collapsed. Political practice at an institutional level both contradicts orthodox Gaullism, which intended a popularly elected President of the Republic to keep the French united, and goes counter to political science, which forecast that presidential elections plus a two-tier uninominal general election would provide France with a two-party system on British lines. Meanwhile, ideologically the recent chapter of ‘political traumas’ has made Rosanvallon, 11 Julliard and Furet’s theory of the gradually arising French 9 Le Monde, "Reconstruire l’Europe au-delà du oui et du non", September 7, 2005. Benjamin R. Barber, "Dreamers Without Borders," The American Prospect, 8 (2005). 11 Pierre Rosanvallon, Le modèle politique français. La société civile contre le jacobinisme de 1789 à nos jours (Paris: Le Seuil, 2004). 10 8 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W ‘democracy of equilibrium’12 less and less serviceable. In this light, the ‘No’ at the referendum had a destructive effect and tended to suggest a relapse of ‘French fever.’ 13 For although the 21st April 2002 sounded as an alarm bell, it was at least the outcome of a series of individual decisions, few of which intended to bring about the collective result of dismissing Jospin and favouring Le Pen, the 29th May 2005 came at the end of long and heated nationwide debate, by contrast, and was the fruit of a long collective rumination, not the fleeting whim of the individual. 3. THE CULTURAL MORTGAGE OF ‘SOCIAL STATE- ISM’ OF A GLOBALISED FRANCE Another age-old tandem that seems to have bitten the dust is Siegfried and Goguel’s movement-résistance, proposed as an explanation of political developments since the Revolution. 14 The erruption of globalisation onto the French debating ground has confounded the traditional parameters of political life, making it hard to detect where party identities start and stop and leading to a rift that runs right through the traditional political families, dividing those in favour from those against globalisation. The last election campaign showed how, at least in social terms, the banner of conservatism has passed into the hands of the left wing, and the radicals in particular, who staked everything on defending and preserving social acquisitions. Take their ideas, their parties or their leaders, the image of the moderate right and left wing as they seek allies within the uninominal system, leaves an impression of chaos and in-fighting: ideological (rather than electoral) pressure from the extremities, rivalry between formations at the centre, difficulties within the dominant parties (the UMP on the right and the PS on the left) riddled with splinter groups, forced to seek allies and unsure about its leadership. The cultural mortgage of ‘social state-ism’ has had a deep effect on the two main moderate parties, the UMP and the UDF, whose liberalist exponents seem only now to be emerging from a long silence and gaining a hearing via that ‘great anomaly’ of French politics, Nicolas Sarkozy, who has recently denounced that the French right has long been ‘under a complex,’ culpably ‘going along with left-wing standard thinking.’ 15 Simplifying somewhat, there are two movements in the French right wing: the liberals who favour decentralisation under Sarkozy’s lead, and the 12 François Furet et al., La République du centre: la fin de l'exception française (Paris: Calmann-Lévy, 1988). 13 Michel Winock, La Fièvre hexagonale: les grandes crises politiques de 1871 à 1968 (Paris: Calmann-Lévy, 1986). 14 André Siegfried, Tableau des partis en France (Paris: Bernard Grasset, 1930) and François Goguel, Le régime politique français (Paris: Editions du Seuil, 1955). 15 La Croix, "Villepin et Sarkozy, deux visions de la France", September 21, 2005. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 9 ‘humanistes’ or ‘social’ current under Villepin, who has received President Chirac’s official blessing, a gesture designed to discredit the renegade dauphin and block the idea of ‘French-style Blairism.’ 16 In the opposite political camp the socialists weakened by the difficulty of taking a stand on foreign policy in the face of Chirac’s impeccable Iraqi dossier, imploded during the referendum campaign and divided over the social issue, above all. Unlike the days of Mitterand, when communists and socialists converged on a position of reformist equilibrium à la Mendès France and Keynes, the left now shows signs of out-and-out continental drift. Inside the socialist galaxy, split in two by the referendum, the frictions of the past are coming to a head; the age-old conflict is surfacing between the two ‘souls,’ reformist and hard-line. Right from the times of Jaurès and Guesde, this cropped up at regular intervals throughout the twentieth century: witness Blum against Déat and Faure between the wars, Mayer versus Mollet in 1945, Rocard against Mitterand at the end of the Seventies.17 It is still there to this day, as if reformism hankers after social-democrat ideals and internationalism, while the hardline is grounded on a singular mixture of class struggle and nationalism. The weak pact signed by the different socialist wings in Le Mans couldn’t hide that the conference (18-20 November 2005) turned into yet another round of score settling within the party, with an eye on the presidential. History seems to be repeating itself with the showdown between Hollande and Fabius, yet there is a historical difference. It concerns the fact that socialist in-fighting in the past have always hinged on diverging views of politics, whereas now they are divided in their lack of ideas. In an attempt to escape from the European trend, through which social democracy 18 is sliding to a position indistinguishable from the right, the archipelago of the French gauche is asphyxiating in self-imposed inaction. The unions doggedly criticise the French weaknesses and block all reform; the ultraleft dreams of halting globalisation, controlling the market and living better while working less; and the reformists will not resign themselves to Blairism, but cannot come up with alternatives. Voting ‘No’ was beckoned as an option for those unconcerned with future implications; it was likened to a basket gathering all the protest generated by politics and how society is being run. France is not a tiny village of Gauls besieged by Muslim or liberalist legions. The ‘No’ was a gesture of refusal that packed little punch, not just because the Euro16 438. 17 Duo Caroli, "Deux clés pour la politique française", Commentaire, 110 (2005): For deeper treatment see Claude Estier, Un combat centenaire: 1905-2005 : histoire des socialistes français (Paris: Le Cherche Midi, 2005). 18 Pascal Delwit, Où va la socialdémocratie européenne? (Bruxelles: Editions de l’Université de Bruxelles, 2004). 10 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W sceptics lacked the means to assuage the heartache they caused, but also because it turned France into an onlooker. That was the worst service the country could be rendered at a time when globalisation is calling for new strategies of collective security in the economic, social and strategic fields. The run-up to the presidential election, apart from the inevitable clash of propaganda, will offer little chance of opening up a real liberal alternative in a country, which has transformed a tradition more inclined to governmentalism than nationalism into the ‘great anti-liberal power in the European Union.’ 19 If France refuses to follow the British way, sacrificing all thoughts of justice and social equality in favour of the market, it must replace the present ‘ideological desert’ by an alternative model20 able to win support and, more importantly, get results. France needs political proposals – something quite different from today’s line-up, which looks at the future in fear and pessimism, and thus opens doors to the politics of resentment and anxiety. For a nation that claims to have roots in the French Revolution – a truly universal event – the planetary provincialism into which it is slowly sinking seems unpardonable nonsense. REFERENCES Bitterlich, Joachim. France – Allemagne: mission impossible? Comment relancer la construction européenne. Paris: Albin Michel, 2005. Blondel, Marc. "Le système français est le plus juste que je connaisse," Le Point 1718 (2005): 50. Caroli, Duo. " Deux clés pour la politique française," Commentaire 110 (2005): 438. Delwit, Pascal. Où va la socialdémocratie européenne? Bruxelles: Editions de l’Université de Bruxelles, 2004. Estier, Claude. Un co mbat centenaire: 1905-2005: histoire des socialistes français. Paris: Le Cherche Midi, 2005. Ferry, Jean-Marc. "Face à la crise, quelles perspectives pour l’Union européenne?" Politique etrangère, 3 (2005): 511-522. Furet, François, Jacques Julliard, Pierre Rosanvallon. La République du centre: la fin de l'exception française. Paris: Calmann-Lévy, 1988. Goguel, François. Le régime politique français. Paris: Editions du Seuil, 1955. Julienne, Christian. Le diable est-il liberal? Paris: Belles Lettres, 2001. Julliard, Jacques. Le Malheur français. Paris: Flammarion, 2005. 19 20 Libération, "La France, terre d’antilibéralisme", May 13, (2005). Joachim Bitterlich, France – Allemagne: mission impossible? Comment relancer la construction européenne (Paris: Albin Michel, 2005). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 11 La Croix, "Villepin et Sarkozy, deux visions de la France," September 21, 2005. Le Monde, "Reconstruire l’Europe au-delà du oui et du non," September 7, 2005. Le Monde, "La France à son rang," September 13, 2005. Libération, "La France, terre d’antilibéralisme," May 13, 2005. Rosanvallon, Pierre. Le modèle politique français. La société civile contre le jacobinisme de 1789 à nos jours. Paris: Le Seuil, 2004. Rusconi, Gian Enrico. "Se cessiamo di essere Europa," Il Mulino 4 (2005): 617-618. Sapir, André. ed. Europa, un’agenda per la crescita. Rapporto Sapir. Bologna: il Mulino, 2004. Siegfried, André. Tableau des partis en France. Paris: Bernard Grasset, 1930. Winock, Michel. La Fièvre hexagonale: les grandes crises politiques de 1871 à 1968. Paris: Calmann-Lévy, 1986. A HOLLOW HOPELESSNESS: SHORTFALLS IN UNI-DIMENSIONAL DEMAND FOR LAW MODELS Jonathan Bond ‡ A BSTRACT This essay explores and evaluates several recent efforts to conceptualise and empirically assess the demand for law in post-Soviet transitioning polities. After highlighting several questions which any robust model of the demand for law must answer and identifying several alternative conceptions of the demand for law developed in the economics literature, the essay offers a theoretical critique of unidimensional rational-choice demand for law models, such as that recently developed by Hoff and Stiglitz. The essay concludes that despite the many insights they can provide regarding the collective action problems which inhere in the establishment of stable legal orders in transitioning economies, unidimensional rational-choice models are incapable, for a variety of reasons, of accurately portraying the dynamic process by which demand for law develops in a society; consequently, it is argued that the rather bleak predictions such models yield of the prospects for legal develop ment in transitioning societies should not be accepted at face value. Keywords: demand for law; economic transition; post-Soviet transition; legal transition; rule of law Since the earliest days of the post-Soviet economic and political transition in the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), much of ‡ M.Sc. (International Public Policy), School of Public Policy, University College London; Contact with questions/comments: jonathan@jonathancbond.com. INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC POLICY REVIEW , vol. 2, no. 1 (May 2006): 12-24. [ ISSN 1748-5207] © 2006 by The School of Public Policy, University College London, London, United Kingdom. All rights reserved. 12 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 13 Central and Eastern Europe (CEE), and elsewhere, considerable attention has been paid to the importance of legal institutions and frameworks as determinants of economic growth and socio-political stability. 1 At least two factors account for this interest among both economists and legal scholars. First, both students of law and political science, already convinced of the importance of the rule of law as a determinant of economic progress, may find in the transition experiences of CIS and CEE countries evidence to support their basic supposition. Second, the “windows of opportunity,” in Kingdon’s language, created by the tumultuous ground-clearing movements which marked the beginning of transition provided, for both scholars and policymakers alike, a unique laboratory in which to experiment with institutional design.2 Such experiments, comprised of both successes and failures, have provided for tremendously fertile ground with regards to retrospective commentary and analysis. Whatever their reasons for devoting attention to this issue, scholars from both the legal and economics disciplines have arrived at several important points of consensus, yet there remain a number of apparent disagreements. That the ‘rule of law’ is in some way very important for economic expansion and development to occur, both in the post-Soviet transition context and in general terms, is not disputed.3 Moreover, scholars appear to agree that while the stock, quality, and enforcement of laws in transitioning countries have all increased (on average), the rule of law in these states remains by some measure insufficient. 4 The literature reaches a crossroads of sorts, however, when scholars take on the question of what is responsible for this deficiency in the rule of law. In the last five 1 Hoff, K., and J.E. Stiglitz, “After the Big Bang? Obstacles to the emergence of the rule of law in post-communist societies.” American Economic Review 94(3), June 2004: 753-763. 2 Hoff and Stiglitz, “After the Big Bang?” 3 D. North, Structure and Change in Economic History, (New York: Norton, 1981); R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, “Legal Determinants of External Finance,” Journal of Finance 52 (1997): 1131–1150; R. La Porta, F. Lopez-deSilanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, “Law and Finance,” Journal of Political Economy 106, no. 6 (1998): 1113– 1155; R. Barro, Determinants of Economic Growth: A CrossCountry Empirical Study (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1997); Boettke, P.J. and J.R. Subrick, “Rule of Law, Development, and Human Capabilities,” Supreme Court Economic Review 10 (2002): 109-126; European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Law in Transition 2004: Competition Law and Policy (London: EBRD General Counsel, 2004). 4 K. Hendley, “Rewriting the Rules of the Game in Russia: the Neglected Issue of the Demand for Law,” East European Constitutional Review 8, no. 4 (1999) http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/; A. Sajo, “The Law of Liposuction,” East European Constitutional Review 8, no. 4(Fall 1999) http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/; K. Pistor, “Supply and Demand for Law in Russia,” East European Constitutional Review 8 no. 4 (Fall 1999) http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/; K. Pistor, The Demand for Constitutional Law, Constitutional Political Economy 13 (2002): 73-87. 14 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W years in particular, the debate has turned to the question of why a constituency demanding the rule of law did not develop as expected after the initial tumultuous years of cataclysmic transition—what scholars have since identified as the ‘Big Bang’. 5 The aim of this essay is to explore and evaluate this debate regarding the determinants of the demand for law in countries undergoing economic transition. After highlighting several definitional and conceptual issues that underlie the issue, the paper offers a structure for understanding the disagreement within the literature concerning the causes of insufficient demand for the rule of law in transitioning economies. While rational choice and game-theoretic demand-for-law models—like that espoused by Hoff and Stiglitz—can yield important insights concerning collective action problems and other barriers to legal transition, such analyses are often incomplete and even misleading. Specifically, it is argued here that such models both overlook the roots of public perceptions of the law and overemphasise the role of a certain set of actors, behaviours, motivations, and institutions at the expense of others. Before addressing the specific factors underlying the deficiency in the demand for law, several conceptual matters must first be addressed. In essence, any study attempting to discover the root causes concerning an insufficient demand for the rule of law must first begin by answering several questions. If overlooked, it will lead to confusion in understanding the terms of the current debate. An investigation must first define what it understands ‘law’ to mean. Law as a concept can undoubtedly be considered at many levels of analysis, and yet there are bounds on what ‘law’ includes. For instance, ‘law’ is arguably narrower than the sum of all the actors and institutions that comprise “governance,” yet it is clearly broader than merely the written statutes passed by a country’s national legislature.6 ,7 A definition of law must also address the functional role of law.8 Moreover, such a definition must also identify how it takes account 5 Hendley, Hoff and Stiglitz, “After the Big Bang?” D. Kaufmann, A. Kraay, and P. Zoida-Lobaton, “Governance Matters, ”The World Bank Development Research Group and World Bank Institute Policy Research Working Paper 2196, October 1999; A. Aslund, ”Law in Russia,” East European Constitutional Review 8, no. 4 (Fall 1999), http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/. 7 It is similarly important to ask to what degree a study perceives a system of law as consisting of “primary” and “secondary” rules, to borrow the language of H.L.A. Hart (1997). That is to say, it must be asked whether a given study takes account of the distinction between the ‘ordinary’ concrete laws (viz. primary rules) which mandate or constrain behaviour by citizens, businesses, and other private entities, and the overarching rules of law (viz. secondary rules) which stipulate (1) the criteria by which law is recognised as legitimate, binding laws, (2) the procedures by which laws can be changed, and (3) the methods by which law is properly interpreted an applied. 8 That is to ask, for example, is law perceived primarily as a tool to protect private property from intrusions by other private citizens, to protect citizens and enterprises from arbitrary intrusions and interference by the state, or both ? 6 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 15 of the informal practices that may be both complementary or substitutionary vis-à-vis formal legal mechanisms. In essence, it must be recognised that the formal apparatuses for the determination and protection of property rights represent only some of the many alternatives available to individuals and entrepreneurs.9 A second question is what the study assumes about the ‘ideal’ provision of law. In other words, for the demand for law in a given country and time to be judged ‘deficient’, this degree of demand must yield, relative to some ideal target, some suboptimal level and/or type of legal framework. To this end, some suggest that the mere dominance of formal institutions of rights protection indicates that the rule of law is sufficiently present, while others insist that it is not merely a quantity or degree of legal protections which (insufficient) demand has failed to call into being, but particular laws which adhere to some “principles of natural justice.”10 ,11 A final question that all studies of the demand for law must answer is why the perceived shortfalls in the observed ‘rule of law’ should be perceived as a deficiency in demand at all. That is to say, while in the last five years there has been growing agreement that the problem is a function of insufficient demand, there is no clear consensus regarding why law should be considered as a problem of demand. This occurs due to different understandings of what the ‘demand’ for law actually is. For some, including Hoff and Stiglitz, the demand for law is reflected in political terms—whether through voting or indirect, informal political influence— and thus insufficient demand for law means simply that too few voting actors prefer to be bound by a legal regime in order for the rule of law to take hold. For others such as Pistor, however, demand for law is manifested in the economic activities and behaviours of economic actors who willingly allowing their transactions to be governed by the rule of law. This matters 9 In other words, given a certain set of incentives, it is presumed that firm managers, for instance, will choose what appears ex ante as the optimal combination of private and public provision of rights protection instruments. This may seem an obvious point, but the relationships (whether substitutionary or complementary) between these various alternatives available to economic actors are easily overlooked, even by otherwise robust analyses. 10 G. O’Donnell, “Polyarchies and the (un) Rule of Law in Latin America: a Partial Conclusion” in The (un) Rule of Law and the Underprivileged in Latin America ed. J.E. Mendez, G. O’Donnell, and P.S. Pinheiro, 317 (Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press). 11 Once the content of the ‘ideal’ system of law is considered, attention must also be paid to the origin from which the substance and/or structure of the law emanates (La Porta, “ Legal Determinants of External Finance,” “Law and Finance”; Berkowitz, Pistor and Richard, “Economic Development, Legality and the Transplant Effect”; Berkowitz, Pistor and Richard, “The Transplant Effect”). This issue is discussed in greater detail below. 16 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W because “no state controls sufficient resources to ensure legal compliance by means of coercion only,” and thus, “every formal legal system therefore relies heavily on voluntary compliance.” 12 Therefore, if the law is to have any wide-reaching effect, it must begin with economic actors themselves preferring to be bound by the law because it is in their interest. 13 ,14 The foregoing conceptual questions obviously deserve a much more thorough treatment, but this is outside the scope of the current paper. Instead, having merely highlighted these difficulties and their importance, the factors identified in the literature as contributing to insufficient demand for law must now be considered. To accomplish this, the paper will first offer a summary and critique of a recent representative study by Hoff and Stiglitz, and second will show how the rest of the literature would respond to both the insights and oversights of the Hoff and Stiglitz analysis. The recent work of Hoff and Stiglitz15 applies a game-theoretic framework to managers of private firms in Russia to answer the question of why the immense constituency demanding the rule of law promised by advocates of rapid privatisation did not in fact materialise in the years after Russia formally began its transition to democracy in 1991. The model is built around a single type of economic actor—firm managers— presumed to be comparatively equal in influence and resources.16 Each 12 It is here that the potential for informal practices, that are complementary to, rather than simple substitutes for, formal legal mechanisms, begins to become apparent. Once a credible, predictable legal system develops, informal practices (such as pre-trial settlement) will develop, which will efficiently resolve many, if not most, disputes which would otherwise be litigated. These systems are complementary because the result they achieve is likely to reflect closely the results the parties expect were they to pursue the matter through trial. As Pistor (1999) notes, several recent symposia in American law journals have insightfully addressed the importance and (complementary and substitutionary) roles of informal legal practices. See scholarly symposia at: Wisconsin Law Review vol. 375, no. 3 (1997), University of Pennsylvania Law Review 144, no. 5 (1996), and Cornell Law Review 82, no. 5 (1997). 13 Pistor, “The Demand for Constitutional Law”, 74. 14 As is already evident, then, the debate is not about whether actors accept the rule of law because it is in their interest in their own judgment. Rather, what divides the threads in the literature, inter alia, is the view they take of which actors and which of those actors’ behaviours are fundamentally responsible for the rule of law taking root. 15 The work which is the subject of their 2004 paper was originally presented at a World Bank conference on 11 April 2002 before being presented to (and published by) the American Economic Association in 2003. 16 As Hoff and Stiglitz make clear in “Obstacles to the Emergence of the Rule of Law in Post-communist Societies,” their model is intentionally designed to parallel a sort of political competitive market model, where none of the actors is disproportionately powerful and thus none has a reason to foresee his/her own actions as dramatically affecting the conditions faced by or actions taken by others. However, why they choose to design their model this way, focusing on what they estimate to be 250,000 firm managers, VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 17 manager must choose, in every time period, first whether he/she will either build value or strip assets from his/her firm, and second whether he/she will politically support or oppose the rule of law. Each of these decisions is a function of the manager’s ‘ability’ to strip assets from his/her firm, 17 and his/her expectation that the rule of law will or will not come into force before the next round of the game. Additionally, the manager’s payoffs are artificially weighted in the model such that building value with the firm’s assets is preferable when the rule of law is present. From this simple model, Hoff and Stiglitz claim to show that managers are likely to not support the rule of law, largely because they fail to take account of how their economic and political choices affect others. In short, there are externalities to the build/strip decision, but more importantly, “the political environment is…a public good (or public bad).”18 Thus, they conclude, the notion that privatisation can create a constituency that will demand law and order is fundamentally flawed. Its contribution and insights aside, this model is useful because simply by listing several of its potential oversights and missteps, one can identify the main positions put forward by alternative theories of deficient demand for law. The most significant flaws in Hoff’s and Stiglitz’s model fit into three broad categories: their conception of law, their identification of relevant actors and their actions which are deemed pertinent, and their implicit concept of an ‘ideal law’ towards which society should aim. Each of these major issues will be briefly addressed, followed by several minor difficulties the model faces. First, the Hoff and Stiglitz model conceptualises law as a unidimensional, even binary variable, which matters for several reasons. That law is actually neither uni-dimensional nor binary is self-evident: as was alluded to above. Wherever law is found, it varies both in degree, in complexity, and in content. Even if one sets aside the crucial Hartian distinction between primary and secondary rules of law, for instance, and assumes that law can either be present as a unit or wholly absent, one is still forced to consider the informal dimensions and extensions of the rule of law—whether as complements or substitutes for formal mechanisms. Second, the model presumes that the most important actors to consider are a particular subset of economic actors—the managers—but at the same time that the primary determinant of the rule of law’s as opposed to perhaps a dozen oligarchs whom they acknowledge to have actually exercised considerable influence from the ‘Big Bang’ forward, is unclear. 17 Hoff and Stiglitz, “After the Big Bang? Obstacles to the emergence of the rule of law in post-communist societies,” are also unclear about whether this ability is a natural trait of the manager or also includes some measure of the manager’s enterprise context. That is, they do not seem to account for the degree to which the manager is in an industry and/or firm where assets are easier and/or more profitable to strip. 18 Hendley, Hoff and Stiglitz, “After the Big Bang?”. 757. 18 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W establishment is the political behaviour of these actors (i.e. their ‘voting’ preferences). While observers can debate which particular actor or behaviour is most important, it seems clearly wrong to study a mismatched pair of actor and action. 19 Undoubtedly, a collective action problem can be perceived in the decisions such managers faced in the immediate aftermath of the tumultuous initial stage of transition. This problem does not centre, however, on their political (i.e. voting) decisions, but rather on economic behaviour. 20 To be fair, the Hoff and Stiglitz model does deliberately attempt to take account of the effects of economic decisions on the future establishment of a legal framework, but the way in which it does so reflects a peculiar, ultimately unsound understanding of how law comes to be established. Finally, the model seems to take for granted that a known ideal target for the development of the rule of law exists, although the content and attributes of this target are never clearly identified. The oversimplified conception of law on which the model is based may well account for this flaw in part. To some, it might have seemed obvious which fundamental direction political reforms should follow—away from the hallmarks of the Soviet regime—in the wake of such major shocks as those experienced in 1991. Even if this were the case, there remained considerable uncertainty and discord over how far these reforms should go, as well as how strong a new formal legal framework should be established once the turbulence settled. Aside from these major flaws, several additional shortcomings warrant brief mention. First, the actors are presumed to be incapable of communicating with one another, likely for the sake of fitting the scenario into a simple game-theoretic framework, and yet there is no reason this must necessarily be so. Second, Hoff and Stiglitz claim their model provides a refutation of the thesis that rapid privatisation cultivates the demand for law, but their model actually takes no account of the rate 19 That is to say, one might rightly disagree with Hoff’s and Stiglitz’s choice to exclude altogether the various political officials and administrators who are involved in the establishment of law, but this is a more subtle issue. What is more obviously wrong with the Hoff and Stiglitz analysis is that it focuses on actors whose political influence is, by Hoff’s and Stiglitz’s own stipulation, minimal at the individual level, and yet tries to explain the phenomenon of insufficient demand for law in terms of these actors’ political behaviour. In short, it would make sense to study the political behaviour of a group of actors who are politically significant (e.g. to study the voting behaviour of the public at large, instead of a contingent of a few hundred thousand at most; alternatively, one could study the indirect political influence of the handful of very powerful oligarchs who exerted great power in Russian politics for much of the 1990s). What matters about the managers is their decision to subject their own transactions to the principles and standards that the law represents especially when the law cannot effectively detect or punish noncompliance. Thus, studying their voting decisions is comparatively irrelevant. 20 Why the voting behaviour of such a comparatively small group of actors should be considered pivotal is never explained, incidentally. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 19 of privatisation. Instead, it seems to address more the method and distributional result, whereby managers were able to gain such considerable control despite the stated intentions of the privatisation plans. Third, their analysis of the decision by managers to build value or strip assets seems flawed in a number of ways.21 In all events, both these minor flaws and the major shortcomings described above are not necessary consequences of game-theoretic analysis, as similar studies of the same topic by Sonin and Polishchuk and Savvateev reveal.22 As suggested above, a review of these arguable shortcomings is helpful because it helps the student to see how an alternative view of why demand for law is insufficient takes shape. For instance, a view challenging that of Hoff and Stiglitz might conceive of law as multidimensional, complex reality—not as a highly discrete (or even binary) variable—thus resulting in a different notion of what the ‘ideal’ rule of law for a transitioning state would be. Additionally, a competing model might focus on the economic behaviours of actors—as opposed to merely their political activities and preferences—as determining whether law comes to rule the market or not. Indeed, this is just what one finds in examining such alternative views. However, above and beyond these alternative assumptions, the most important aspect of these alternative analyses of demand for law is the role played by public perceptions of both the law itself and the state’s administration of it. Propounded most adamantly in regard to the Russian case by Kathryn Hendley, the argument for public perceptions of law as a factor constraining the demand for the rule of law asserts the following: to the ordinary citizen, or even to the entrepreneur, in a transition country at the beginning of the ‘Big Bang’, the idea that law could be used as anything but an instrument by which apparatchiks and other elites exercise, preserve, and expand their power was simply untenable. Consequently, reforms that failed to address this fundamental public distrust of the law were doomed to failure from the start. 21 Specifically, they presume stripping assets to be detrimental, though they ignore cases where subunits of firms are sold off or superfluous resource or capital stocks (inherited by the firm from its predecessor under the command economy regime) are actually beneficial. Specifically, they seem to conflate assets sales with tunneling, which is incorrect, and they ignore firm-propping entirely (see E. Friedman, S. Johnson, and T. Mitton, “Propping and Tunneling,” Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (2003): 732-750). Additionally, their assumption of a normal distribution curve reflecting stripping ability, which is in large part responsible for the unstable and ‘bad’ equilibria their model generates, should be questioned. 22 Sonin specifically examines the incentives accruing to property owners considering their option to rely on informal, and not just formal, methods of rights enforcement. Polishchuk and Savvateev attempt to study the consequences of the privatization strategies, concluding that ineffective privatisation (meaning that managers were able to block, tamper with, or intercept the distribution of ownership rights to the public) plays a significant role. 20 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W This element of perception is crucial because it helps to illuminate the context that, in part, amplifies the collective action problem that undoubtedly did face economic actors. However, it differs from that portrayed by Hoff and Stiglitz. First, what determines the actual ‘establishment’ of the rule of law is the voluntary actions of economic actors to subject their dealings to the law (as opposed to their voting behaviour). 23 Thus, in order for such actors to choose the law to govern their own dealings, doing so must be more efficient in their view than prior-established habits and routines or extralegal means of rights enforcement. At the beginning of transition, and for a considerable time thereafter, however, the transaction costs of utilising the law are made higher in the estimation of economic actors, whether citizens or firm managers, both by fear of their trading partners cheating and by their lack of confidence in the impartiality, predictability, enforceability (i.e. effectiveness), and justness of the law offered by the state. It is these perceptual factors, as Hendley’s argument suggests and as several respondents affirm, 24 which transform the problem of establishing the rule of law from an ordinary collective action dilemma to a much more complicated social and economic problem. 25 Undoubtedly a host of attributes of the transition countries’ legal systems may contribute to this crisis of perception, including: the legacy of the extant legal culture, reform fatigue among voters, low quality of provision as inexperienced institution-builders experiment with legal frameworks, and exogenous (with respect to the legal order itself) problems with enforcement. 26 It is these and similar factors, therefore, which are largely responsible for the low level of demand for the rule of law. 23 In other words, law develops as those who already possess de facto ownership of certain property seek to make the delineation and defence of their rights in that property more efficient. As more and more actors demonstrate that law provided by the state is efficient, more and more property owners are persuaded to entrust the protection of the de facto ownership they already have to the guardianship of the state. By contrast, such a system cannot turn nominal rights into de facto rights. To put it another way, it is true that political power over the content and extent of the law is extremely important, but this is not the case until the law has acquired de facto control over the property concerning which it defines and protects rights. Until then, control over the law itself is meaningless (i.e. only control over the state’s coercive apparatus would matter). 24 Pistor, “Supply and Demand for Law in Russia”; Sajo; Aslund. 25 It is worth noting that ordinary collective action constraints—a field explored famously by Mancur Olson—would certainly apply to many or all informal (i.e. private) mechanisms for rights protection, and yet somehow these apparatuses materialised, the inference being that other factors, such as those Hendley and others describe, may account for the difference. 26 E.g. the fragility of many business enterprises—many of which ought to have, and did, go bankrupt—and perhaps also inadequate liquidity, result inter alia in the inability of a plaintiff to obtain restitution ordered by a court, simply because the defendant firm has insufficient assets to take (perhaps, for example, it has been funded to-date by a lingering soft-budget constraint, but such resources are not available for legal restitution). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 21 One final factor deserves mention, addressed by Hendley but more thoroughly in the works of Pistor, 27 as it connects the results of legal reform with the methods employed. This issue is the degree to which legal reformers attempt to import or transplant various aspects or whole systems of law from well-established, stable market democracies to transition countries, then imposing these systems in a top-down fashion. The basic question is whether or not and under what conditions imported or transplanted legal systems will contribute to a lower level of demand for law to rise in importance. Among the difficulties of the issue is that those most familiar with it are those whose opinions of the issue are the most complicated. On the one hand, scholars such as Hendley argue, there are many reasons to disfavour the drafting of laws by policymakers pursuing technocratic precision, usually closely patterned on the legal codes of prosperous and stable democracies abroad, but without regard for how business is actually being conducted in transition countries at the time of reform.28 Also, such strategies of imposing effectively imported law may only contribute further to the long-extant public perception that the law is merely a tool of those already in power. 29 Yet on the other hand, the rule of law reformers wish to impose, even if conceptually imported, may well be superior to the ‘rules of the game’ with which entrepreneurs in a given transition country are familiar. 30 It is true, to a degree, that law transplanted into a new context must be compatible at some level with the legal, political, and economic culture into which it is being integrated, but how then can meaningful change ever take place?31 27 Pistor, “Supply and Demand for Law in Russia” and “The Demand for Constitutional Law”; D. Berkowitz, K. Pistor, and J.F. Richard, “The Transplant Effect,” American Journal of Comparative Law 51, no. 1 (2003): 163-204; K. Pistor, “Economic Development, Legality and the Transplant Effect,” European Economic Review 47, no. 1 (2003): 165-195; C. Xu and K. Pistor, “Law Enforcement under Incomplete Law: Theory and Evidence from Financial Market Regulation,” Columbia Law School Center for Law and Economic Studies Working Paper 222, April 2003. http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=396141; K. Pistor, Y. Keinan, J. Kleinheisterkamp, and M.D. West, “Innovation in Corporate Law,” Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (2003): 676-694. 28 And thus the resulting legal codes risk being perceived as unfamiliar, and thus inefficient and irrelevant. 29 That is to say, as Hendley argues in “Rewriting the Rules of the Game in Russia: the Neglected Issue of the Demand for Law,” those who manipulate the legal framework to achieve a stable market democracy through the transition process are perhaps perceived as very similar to the prior command-economy regimes, in that they are merely using the law to impose their policy preferences (which happen to be major political and economic liberalization) on the rest of society. Thus, law may remain as it was, neither neutral nor free-standing in the eyes of the public. 30 Pistor, “Supply and Demand for Law in Russia”; Aslund. 31 Pistor, “Supply and Demand for Law in Russia”; “The Demand for Constitutional Law.” 22 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W The answer Pistor offers is insightful in tying together several of the important issues described above. It is true that in order for law to develop, a constituency voluntarily subjecting itself to the law is necessary. It is not true, however, that reformers can “let loose, wait for the dust to settle, and then respond to new demand for institution building.” 32 If they attempt this, as was often the case, they will find insufficient demand for the rule of law, at least law provided by the state, in part because of the instability and very high inefficiency of the political markets at this early and uncertain stage of transition. 33 Rather, if the state wishes the legal framework it offers to be preferred, and thus to achieve prevalence, the state must provide clear signals at the beginning of transition to address the initial perceptual problems of the public. These signals, or “signposts,” of the courts neutrality, predictability, independence, credibility, and effective enforcement of the law are numerous, but they include cases where actors on the macropolitical stage voluntarily bind themselves to decisions by the courts instead of resorting to political upheaval and violent resistance to challenges to their authority. 34 ,35 Above all, however, “some key rules simply must be imposed from the beginning,” which can establish the stability and credibility of the law sufficient to “elicit a critical mass of demand for law.”36 Moreover, while some of these key rules must be primary rules in the Hartian sense, it would seem that these should largely consist of secondary rules—that is, those which determine what law is, how it can be changed, and how rules are interpreted and applied—as these are crucial in cultivating credibility and confidence in the legal order among economic actors and the public at large. The aim of this paper has been to shed light on a complicated and often confusing, but highly significant, debate within the transition literature regarding the causes of a deficient demand for law. After portraying the most prominent threads of this literature in relation to one 32 Pistor, “Supply and Demand for Law in Russia,” n.p. No page citations are available for Pistor (1999), nor for any other work from the same symposium in the East European Constitutional Review, because the archived (electronic) versions of the publication do not provide any pagination references. 34 Pistor “Supply and Demand for Law in Russia”, n.p. 35 The recent constitutional crisis in Ukraine provides a stark example: that all sides eventually adopted even such similar rhetoric affirming the nearly unassailable prerogative of the Supreme Court is not to be viewed as a sign that the rule of law reigns supreme in Ukraine (though the progress in recent years is noteworthy), but rather the event will almost certainly serve as a signal to actors in the future, and thus is more a part of the process of establishing the rule of law, rather than an indicator of success to-date. In Pistor’s (1999, n.p.) language, “The credibility of the legal system stands or falls with the respect paid to it by those in power. This is a political rather than a technical issue.” Thus “ even a few cases of effective law enforcement would have sent an important signal.” 36 Pistor “Supply and Demand for Law in Russia”, n.p. 33 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 23 another and with respect to important conceptual questions, it has been argued that some analyses, such as the game-theoretic framework employed by Hoff and Stiglit, are both useful and misleading. In order to understand the demand for law (and what leads to an insufficiency), it is necessary to turn to a broader array of issues, especially perceptions of the law held by the citizenry, the importance of which is reinforced by the same conceptual issues described above. REFERENCES Aslund, A. ”Law in Russia.” East European Constitutional Review 8, no. 4 (Fall 1999). http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/ Barro, R. Determinants of Econo mic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1997. Berkowitz, D., K. Pistor, and J.F. Richard. “ The Transplant Effect.” American Journal of Comparative Law 51, no. 1 (2003): 163-204. ———. “Economic Development, Legality and the Transplant Effect.” European Econo mic Review 47, no. 1 (2003): 165-195. Boettke, P.J. and J.R. Subrick. “Rule of Law, Development, and Human Capabilities.” Supreme Court Economic Review 10 (2002): 109-126. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Law in Transition 2004: Competition Law and Policy. London: EBRD General Counsel, 2004. Friedman, E., S. Johnson, and T. Mitton. “Propping and Tunneling.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (2003): 732-750. Hart, H.L.A. The Concept of Law, 2 nd ed. Oxford: Oxford Univ. Press., 1997. Hellman, J.S., G. Jones, and D. Kaufmann. Seize the State, Seize the Day: State Capture and Influence in Transition Economies. Journal of Comparative Eocnomics 31 (2003): 751-753. Hendley, K. “Rewriting the Rules of the Game in Russia: the Neglected Issue of the Demand for Law.” East European Constitutional Review 8, no. 4 (1999). http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/ Hoff, K., and J.E. Stiglitz. “Obstacles to the Emergence of the Rule of Law in Post-communist Societies.” Paper presented at the World Bank 11 April 2004, 2002. http://info.worldbank.org/etools/bspan/PresentationView.asp?PID=28 5&EID=136 ———. “After the Big Bang? Obstacles to the emergence of the rule of law in post-communist societies,” American Econo mic Review 94, no. 3 (2004): 753-763. Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and P. Zoida-Lobaton. “Governance Matters.” 24 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W The World Bank Development Research Group and World Bank Institute Policy Research Working Paper 2196, October 1999. Kingdon, J.W. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies, 2 nd ed. New York: Harper Collins, 1995. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny. “Legal Determinants of External Finance.” Journal of Finance 52 (1997): 1131–1150. ———. Law and Finance. Journal of Political Economy 106, no. 6 (1998): 1113– 1155. North, D. Structure and Change in Economic History. Norton, New York, 1981. O’Donnell G. 1999. “Polyarchies and the (un) Rule of Law in Latin America: a Partial Conclusion.” InThe (un) Rule of Law and the Underprivileged in Latin America, edited by Mendez, J.E., G. O’Donnell, and P.S. Pinheiro, 303-37. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press. Olson, M. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press., 1971. Pistor, K. “Supply and Demand for Contract Enforcement in Russia: Courts, Arbitration, and Private Enforcement.” Review of Central and East European Law 22, no. 1 (1996): 55– 87. ———. Supply and Demand for Law in Russia. East European Constitutional Review 8, no. 4 (Fall 1999). http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/ ———. The Demand for Constitutional Law. Constitutional Political Economy 13 (2002): 73-87. Pistor, K., Y. Keinan, J. Kleinheisterkamp, and M.D West. “Innovation in Corporate Law.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (2003): 676-694. Pistor, K., M. Raiser, and S. Gelfer, S. “Law and Finance in Transition Economies.” The Economics of Transition 8, no. 2 (2000): 325–368. Polinsky, A.M. and S. Shavell, S. “The Economic Theory of Public Enforcement of Law.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 6993, March 1999. Polishchuk, L. and A. Savvateev. “Spontaneous (non) Emergence of Property Rights.” Center for Institutional Reform and the Informal Sector Working Paper 241, January 2001. http://www.iris.umd.edu/publications/detail.asp?ID=wp&number=241 Sajo, A. “ The Law of Liposuction.” East European Constitutional Review 8, no. 4, Fall 1999. http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/ Sonin, K. “Why the rich may favour poor protection of property rights.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (2003): 715-731. Xu, C., and K. Pistor. Law Enforcement under Incomplete Law: VOL. 2 , NO. 1 — MAY 2 0 0 6 Theory and Evidence from Financial Market Regulation. Columbia Law School Center for Law and Economic Studies Working Paper 222, April 2003. http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=396141. 25 26 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W THE CHALLENGE OF CHINA: TESTING TIMES FOR NEW LABOUR’S ‘ETHICAL’ DIMENSION A CASE STUDY OF THE EU ARMS EMBARGO ON CHINA Kayte Rath ‡ A BSTRACT 1 The inclusion, in 1997, of an ‘ethical’ dimension to foreign policy by New Labour has been a heavy burden for the UK Government to bear. This can be seen most clearly in the negotiations surrounding the proposal to lift the EU arms embargo on China, which has been in place since the events in Tianan men Square in 1989 on a policy stance aligned to protect international human rights. The discussion within the UK sidelined this element of the debate, using manipulation of human rights discourse to support its pro-lift position. The minimal element that the discourse of human rights played can be best understood by considering two other factors. First, the rise of China as an econo mic power has provided an incentive for the EU to deliver a symbolic gesture, in the form of the embargo lift, to attempt to socialise China into the international global economy and its implicit mannerisms. This is underpinned by a long-term, strategic econo mic engagement with the country and the pursuit of global stability. Second, the overt advocacy of France and Germany in support of the proposal meant that the UK could not take up a stance against this. However, the UK’s relationship with the US restricted its ability to take a ‡ M.Sc. (Public Policy), School of Public Policy, University College London; Contact with questions/comments: kayterath@hotmail.com. 1 The author would like to extend special thanks to Thom Rath and Jack Straw. Further thanks to all interviewees, Charles-Henry Courtois, Tamzin Robertson, Moms, Pops and Sis. Xie xie. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 27 strong stance and it sought to balance its two competing diplomatic relationships. The passing of an anti-secession law by the Chinese government led to a critical change in the embargo discussions. Human rights were then used as a way for the EU to avoid political embarrassment, but keep the embargo lift on the agenda for the future. Overall, the case study shows the ease with which human rights discourse can be manipulated to serve the interests of different groups. Thus, a nuanced realist framework is the most illuminating in this case and although international normative pressure can exert itself, such as with the embargo’s original imposition, this remains the exception rather than the rule. 1. INTRODUCTION The pursuit, by New Labour, of a foreign policy with an ‘ethical dimension’ is one that has plagued the government’s foreign relations since it came to power in 1997. Ever since the then Foreign Secretary, Robin Cook outlined his vision of British foreign policy as one that “would put human rights at the heart of our foreign policy”2 giving them “a new priority,” 3 New Labour has consistently struggled to make this policy ideal into a concrete reality. The move towards an ethical practice was meant to rejuvenate British foreign policy so that Britain, once more, could become an important player in the international community. Instead, it has proven to be a heavy burden to bear, with the traditional cartels of national interest, geopolitics and economic prowess continuing to dominate. The well-documented rise of China’s prominence onto the international scene has raised questions about the kinds of pitfalls involved in juggling ethical considerations with more traditional foreign policy concerns in a starker contrast than ever before. The burgeoning Chinese economy and the opportunities for investment and trade are juxtaposed against the authoritarian regime and the widespread human rights violations it perpetuates. China is a “particularly difficult case”4 and presents a dilemma for the EU, USA and the rest of the world, in how they can benefit from a strong economic relationship with the country, while at the same time being politically wary about China’s policies and actions. 2 Robin Cook quoted in T. Dunne and N.J. Wheeler, Moral Brittania? Evaluating the Ethical Dimension in Labour’s Foreign Policy (London: The Foreign Policy Centre, 2004). 3 R. Cook, “Human Rights: Making the Difference” Speech given by Robin Cook to Amnesty International Human Rights Festival, October 16, 1998. 4 Peter Hain MP quoted in New Statesman, “The New Statesman Interview”, April 3, 2000. 28 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W This broad ranging struggle is encapsulated in the ongoing negotiations surrounding the lifting of the European Union’s arms embargo policy towards China. Originally put in place on human rights grounds in 1989 following the incidents in Tiananmen Square, the policy has risen to the European agenda and has been the subject of fierce debate since 2003. In an analysis of the UK’s role and position on this policy, this paper seeks to illuminate current trends in UK policy towards China and demonstrate how much of the once publicised ‘ethical dimension’ really remains rooted in New Labour’s agenda. This will be achieved through an analysis of the role human rights considerations have played in the formation of the UK’s position on this issue. The move by Labour to an ‘ethical’ foreign policy can be seen as part of a wider shift in the foreign policies of Western governments in taking a more normative stance in their international relations, offering alternative motives for action other than the narrow concerns of national interest that have traditionally characterised foreign policy formation.5 Although realism6 has dominated the field of international relations theory, normative international relations theories have gained increasing attention, 7 demonstrating the mirroring of Labour’s shift towards a more normative approach in academic discourse. However, as Brown notes, realism itself does not lack an ethical dimension, it just sees moral priority as lying in serving the interests of the members of its own state above the interests of members of other states.8 Similar to Brown, Frost 9 notes that all foreign policy statements and actions have ethical meaning and implication so the idea of an ethical versus a non-ethical foreign policy is something of a false dichotomy. For him, the importance rests with the interplay between normative and selfinterested concerns, with realism positing a more modest, circumscribed ethical element than the publicly trumpeted ‘ethical’ stances of New 5 M. Light & K. Smith (eds.), Ethics and Foreign Policy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001). 6 Theory of international relations, which predicts that due to the anarchic nature of the international system states will always work in their own self-interest to secure their own interests to maintain or increase their position on the international stage. See Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Boston: McGraw Hill, 1979). 7 C. Beitz, Political Theory and International Relations. (Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press, 1979); Chris Brown, International Relations Theory: New Normative Approaches (Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1992); M. Frost, Ethics in International Relations (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); M. Hoffman, “ N ormative International Theory: Approaches and Issues in Groom”, In Contemporary International Relations: A Guide to Theory ed. A. R J. and M. Light. London: Pinter Publishers, 1994). 8 Chris Brown, “Ethics, Interests and Foreign Policy” In Ethics and Foreign Policy ed. M. Light & K. Smith, 15-32 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001). 9 M. Frost, Putting the World to Rights: Britain's Ethical Foreign Policy Cambridge Review of International Affairs 12 (1999). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 29 Labour. Committed realists, such as Carr10 would point to such moral discourse as only a guise for other narrow national interests or argue for the potential for moral discourse to play an instrumental role in comprising the power of the state to act. 11 As Chandler12 points out, an ethical dimension to foreign policy is one that suits Western governments, such as Britain, since it provides a mission statement and increased legitimacy to their domestic audience. On these accounts, any discussions around lifting the embargo would focus their concerns solely on national interest. These arguments deny the role of international socialisation and norm dynamics, however, which have played a role in allowing norms, such as human rights, a greater degree of acceptance in foreign policymaking. Finnemore 13 stresses this and the way norms can shape and regulate the behaviour of states. Realist explanations fail to take into account essential features of politics like emotional appeal to a political goal or the grounds for moral judgement. The original imposition of the arms embargo could be seen as just such an instance, motivated purely on the grounds of moral judgement and motivation derived from international norms, bolstered by a large-scale, intensely vocal mobilisation of global civil society. However, if normative explanations proved true in all cases, Labour’s reputation of sticking to its ethical commitments would be more positive than it currently is. Although some have been broadly favourable to the Government, 14 the involvement of the ‘ethical dimension’ seems to have declined over time. Dunne and Wheeler, for instance moved from concluding in 1998 that there “has been a marked shift in the content and conduct of British foreign policy” to two years later supporting the conclusion that there is an “increasing discrepancy between the moral rhetoric of the Blair Government and its subsequent practices.”15 More 10 E.H. Carr pointed to the role of the British Harmony of Interests in convincing others, including those victims of British imperialism, that their interests were the same as Britain’s in E.H. Carr, The Twenty Years Crisis 1919-1939: An Introduction to the Study of International Relations (London: Macmillan, 1964). 11 Henry Kissinger, American Foreign Policy 2 (New York: W. W. Norton, 1997). 12 D. Chandler, “Rhetoric Without Responsibility: The Attraction of ‘Ethical’ Foreign Policy” British Journal of Politics and International Relations 5, no. 3 (2003): 295-316. 13 Martha Finnemore, National Interests in International Society (New York: Cornell University Press, 1996). 14 R. Little and M. Wickham-Jones (eds.), New Labour’s Foreign Policy: A New Moral Crusade? (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2000); R. Cook, “Putting Principle into Practice: The Role of Human Rights in Foreign Policy” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 15, no. 1 (2002): 45-51. 15 T. Dunne and N. Wheeler, “Good International Citizenship: A Third Way for British Foreign Policy” International Affairs 72, no. 1 (1998): 850; T. Dunne and N.J. Wheeler, “Blair’s Britain: A Force for Good in the World?” in Ethics and Foreign Policy ed. M. Light & K. Smith, 168 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001). 30 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W recently, they have shown further disappointment arguing that Blair’s decision to go to war with Iraq has irreversibly damaged the reputation of the ethical foreign policy and it is in sore need of revival. 16 Similarly, Abrahmsen and Williams 17 show that although the introduction of an ‘ethical dimension’ into British foreign policy has raised the UK’s profile in the international arena, the policy is intrinsically problematic. The tension between New Labour’s internationalism and the more traditional realist concerns of national interest are all too apparent, as are the contradictions involved with committing to both political and economic liberalism. Furthermore, as Williams18 discusses, the jettisoning of the term ‘ethical’ in Labour’s election manifesto for 2001 demonstrates how the explicit use of the term proved too much of a burden to bear by providing benchmarks that highlighted the administration’s failings, more than achievements in a positive light. Consequently, there is a sense of failure around the policy, even amongst Labour’s own MPs, 19 yet this is too simplistic a reaction. As previously stated, realism is not without its ethical components and international norms have had their role to play. However, this case shows that with a lack of robust civil society pressure or large scale, emotive media events, there may be a tendency to regress into narrower realist (though not necessarily unethical) concerns of national interest. Realist assumptions in generally prove useful however; the fact that there has not been a complete removal of content associated with ‘ethics’ from the Foreign and Commonwealth Office (FCO) may suggest that a more nuanced account of realism is needed. This is one that acknowledges not only the ethical dimension of traditional diplomacy itself, but also of the possible influence of international civil society in creating constituencies for newer broader definitions of ethics in foreign policy, although these may remain the exception rather than the rule. As stated, despite the seeming decline of Labour’s ethical stance, an examination of FCO policy, mission statements, speeches and press releases reveals the element still alive and kicking. 20 It is hard to avoid the discourse of human rights. The FCO has published annual human rights 16 T. Dunne and N.J. Wheeler, Moral Brittania? Evaluating the Ethical Dimension in Labour’s Foreign Policy (London: The Foreign Policy Centre, 2004). 17 R. Abrahmsen and P. Williams, “Ethics and Foreign Policy: The Antinomies of New Labour’s ‘Third Way’ in Sub-Saharan Africa” Political Studies 49 (2001): 249-264. 18 P. Williams, “The Rise and Fall of the ‘Ethical Dimension’: Presentation and Practice in New Labour’s Foreign Policy” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 15, no. 1 (2002);.See also The Guardian, “Labour Drops ‘Ethical Tag’,” September 4, 2000. 19 T. Kingham, “Wanted: Ethics in Foreign Policy” Socialist Campaign Group News 164 (2001). 20 Foreign and Commonwealth Office Website, FCO, www.fco.gov.uk, (accessed 12 th September 2005). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 31 reports since 1998, has a specific department dedicated to human rights concerns, democracy and governance (HRDGG), and maintains human rights concerns among its key priorities.21 The ‘ethical’ element is still overtly present and still jostling for position within the FCO’s varied and competing foreign policy considerations. As stated before, China represents a considerable challenge on this front as to how the UK can marry its desires to see economic advancement, regional and global stability while committing itself to the improvement towards better human rights and democratic structure in China. These are more often than not conflicting interests, which form part of a wider debate on the management of China’s rising prominence. How to deal with the increasing importance of China is perhaps one of the most prominent elements of post-Cold War international relations. Throughout history, countries have risen up and fallen down the ladder of supremacy and there is no magic formula for dealing with a rising power. 22 How you deal with a rising power will also reflect one’s own position within the spectrum. However, the case of China is seen as presenting a plethora of difficulties based not only on its unprecedented economic growth, but also its political regime and its potential to develop global influence rivaling that of the USA, perhaps attaining superpower status.23 Different strategies have been developed to try and deal with China. These have ranged from strict advocates of containment 24 and the use balance of power principles and tactics to different forms of engagement intended to integrate China into international society. 25 The policy of containment however, is now largely defunct with most governments agreeing that some form of engagement is the best policy for dealing with 21 Foreign and Commonwealth Office Website, “UK Priorities,” FCO, http://www.fco.gov.uk/servlet/Front?pagename=OpenMarket/Xcelerate/ShowPage&c=Pa ge&cid=1007029393465, (accessed 12 th September 2005). 22 R. Schweller, “Managing the Rise of Great Powers: History and Theory” In Engaging China: The management of an emerging power ed. A.I. Johnston and R.S Ross (London: Routledge, 1999). 23 D. Shambaugh (ed.), Greater China: The Next Superpower? (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995); S. Kim, “China as a Great” Current History Sept. (1997): 246251; A. Goldstein, “Great Expectations: Interpreting China’s Arrival” International Security 22, no. 3 (1997): 36-73. 24 A. Waldron, “Deterring China” Commentary 100, no. 4 (1995); G. Rachman, Containing China in Washington Quarterly 19, no. 1 (1996): 129-140; G. Segal, “East Asia and the containment of China” International Security 20, no. 4 (1996): 107-135. 25 D. Shambaugh, “Containment or Engagement of China? Calculating Beijing’s Responses” International Security 21, no. 2 (1996): 180-209; J. Shimm, Weaving the Net: Conditional Engagement with China (New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1996). 32 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W China, 26 although what form this takes will vary. Shambaugh argues that although “the insular and defensive character of Chinese politics and nationalism suggests that China will be reluctant and difficult to engage and to integrate into the existing international order,”27 the international community must try in order to protect international order and economic stability. For those such as Shimm, 28 this policy of engagement means attempting to develop a constructive way to react to the rise of China. This will involve increasing economic integration and the pursuit of security engagement to reduce the risks posed by China’s military expansion. Pursuit of these aims will lead China into the international fold. Enmeshing China into global regimes will help direct its action in a more cooperative manner. 29 As demonstrated by Ross, success has already been seen in this area. He argues that the US has been fairly successful in engaging with China by managing to pursue short-term, as well as longterm aims. In the short-term it has gained access to valuable Chinese markets and in the long-term it has facilitated engagement of China in multilateral institutions.30 However, policies of engagement have focused mainly on economic and security integration, with Shimm placing ‘respect for basic human rights’ at the bottom of his ten principles of conditional engagement. 31 The assumption is that economic liberalization will lead to an improvement in human rights, democracy and the rule of law. The effect of China’s ‘opening up’ policy has so far been positive in this area. For example, it has led to the allowance of more media freedom. This was initially aimed at reducing financial losses, but the freeing of public discourse has been an indirect result. 32 However, the effect is diffuse and protracted, and as Nathan argues, “Economic engagement is a 26 Shambaugh, “Containment or Engagement of China? Calculating Beijing ’s Responses.” e.g. the EU, Australia, Japan, ASEAN, Canada and the US. 27 Shambaugh, “Containment or Engagement of China? Calculating Beijing ’s Responses,” 209. 28 Shimm. 29 S. Kim, “China and the United Nations in Economy” In China Joins the World: Progress and Prospects ed. E & M. Oksenberg, 43-89 (New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1999). 30 The US was instrumental in getting China into the CTBT (the Preparatory Commission for the Comprehensive Nuclear Test Ban Treaty), the Nuclear Non Proliferation Treaty (NPT) and the Zangger Committee (Committee looking at the interpretation of article III, paragraph 2 of the NPT) (see R.S. Ross, “Engagement in US China Policy in Johnston” In Engaging China: The management of an emerging power ed. A.I. Johnston and R.S. Ross (London: Routledge, 1999). 31 Shimm, 8. 32 1994). M. Pei, From Reform to Revolution (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 33 complement to, not a substitute for, human rights policy.” 33 There are areas where economic integration may harm rights, such as labour conditions and areas where it may make no difference at all, such as the high death rates evidenced in Chinese orphanages. Contrary to Shimm, Nathan holds that China must be held to a level of human rights conduct concurrent with its emerging importance and this justifies urgent and sustained attention to China’s human rights record by the West. The necessary attention to human rights Nathan calls for, however, will frequently come into conflict with the economic pursuits of countries in China. As noted by Breslin, 34 the UK’s pursuit of commercial contracts in China is in danger of overriding any remaining ethical element of foreign policy the UK has. Presumably, following similar logic to Shimm, the improvement in human rights is set to follow on from this. However, as Nathan points out, it is only when the West has taken a strong stance on human rights in China has it been able to successfully support China’s internal evolution. 35 Furthermore, the UK’s reputation for improving human rights in China has been poor. New Labour’s “much heralded diplomacy of human rights produced little in the way of discernible achievements in China,” 36 focusing more on not wishing to ‘rock the boat’ and endanger commercial ties. At the EU level, policies toward China are sometimes just as confused with those not always contributing towards the objectives of a more stable, democratic China, and often failing to bring about the intended result of making China a more stable global partner. 37 It is against this backdrop that the lifting of the EU arms embargo on China emerges. As Labour begins its third term in government, takes on the EU presidency and begins charm offensives towards China in the form of various diplomatic visits, an assessment of how human rights considerations are impacting British foreign policy now is an important test not only for Blair’s government, but for the promotion of universal principles in general. A study of relations with China, through the lens of the arms embargo, is a perfect opportunity to examine the extent to which human rights considerations really are given credence in UK foreign 33 A. Nathan, “China and the International Human Rights Regimes in Economy” in China Joins the World: Progress and Prospects ed. E. and M. Oksenberg, 136-160 (New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1999). 34 S. Breslin, “Beyond Diplomacy: UK Relations with China since 1997” British Journal of Politics and International Relations 6, no. 3 (2004): 409-425. 35 Nathan, 159. Dunne and Wheeler, 182. 37 K. Barysch, C. Grant and M. Leonard, “Embracing the Dragon: The EU’s partnership with China” (London: Centre for European Reform, 2005). 36 34 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W policy, and how Britain is fostering relations with this rapidly expanding nation. This paper will first give a brief background to the arms embargo and the debate surrounding it. This will be followed by a discussion of the role accorded to human rights in the formulation of the UK’s position, arguing that the role was so minimal as to virtually be non-existent. The remainder of the paper will seek to explain why this was the case and conclude that the UK hides behind its bilateral human rights dialogues with China to justify its avoidance of human rights in broader policy discussions. In addition, it has failed to acknowledge the potential leverage available from the embargo and the symbolic significance of lifting the embargo without human rights concessions by China. It will also conclude that on this issue, the UK’s commitments to and pressures from its relationships with the EU and the USA prevented it from making a strong stance on the arms embargo, demonstrating that its pledge to an ethical stance falls well below the priority accorded to sustaining its diplomatic ties. 2. B ACKGROUND TO THE EU ARMS EMBARGO ON C HINA 38 The embargo under discussion was put in place on 27 June 1989 in response to the crackdown by the Chinese authorities on students protesting for democracy in Beijing’s central square. The EU responded during the Madrid European Council by putting an embargo in place on arms sales and military cooperation. 39 China has long been calling for the embargo to be lifted, perhaps most ardently in China’s EU Policy Paper in October 2003. The first of its kind, this paper calls explicitly for an end to the embargo stating “The EU should lift its ban on arms sales to China at an early date so as to remove barriers to greater bilateral cooperation on defence industry and technologies.”40 This prompted discussion within the EU, and China found a truly prominent advocate within the union, in the form of France. France pushed the issue to the EU agenda for discussion, with German Chancellor Schroeder quickly adding his voice to that of the French president Chirac. 38 A copy of the original Declaration On China, containing the arms embargo appears in Appendix 1. 39 European Parliament, “European Parliaments Fact sheet 6.3.10: China”, European Parliament, http://www.europarl.eu.int/facts/6_3_10_en.htm, (accessed September 12, 2005). 40 Department of European Affairs, “China’s EU Policy Paper”, Dept. of European Affairs, http://www.fmprc.gov.cn/eng/wjb/zzjg/xos/dqzzywt/t27708.htm, (accessed September 5, 2003). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 35 Since then, the embargo has undergone various negotiations, being referred to the GAERC and COREPER. 41 Proponents of the embargo lift have argued that the embargo is no longer relevant in today’s international society, and therefore the EU should be working towards a more positive engagement with China by moving away from multilateral stigmatisation. Those against a decision in lifting the embargo have argued how such a decision could destabilise the tense situation between Taiwan and China42 and how China’s human rights records does not deserve the kind of reward the embargo lift would represent. The embargo was due to be lifted in June 2005, but this deadline was dropped following the passing of an anti-secession law against Taiwan by China, which was said to change the political atmosphere of the discussions surrounding a policy reversal. It remains in place at the present time. Although the EU remains committed to lifting the embargo at some point, it is uncertain as to when this will occur. What is certain however, is that during the UK’s presidency of the EU, the topic is almost sure not to arise. The UK’s position on the issue has been characterised by non-commitment and a sense of “muddling through in the middle of the pack.” 43 Although it is keen to stress that the proposal to lift the embargo is “still under review and is still an ongoing negotiation,” 44 the UK has come out publicly in favour of the lift, with Jack Straw claiming that he “supported the proposal from President Chirac and Chancellor Schroeder that we should review the EU China arms embargo because, on the face of it, it had run its course.”45 This pro-lift position will be investigated in the rest of the paper. 41 General Affairs and External Relations Council and the Permanent Representatives Committee respectively. 42 The territory of Taiwan possesses an ambiguous diplomatic status. The PRC seeks the total reunification of the territory of Taiwan as part of its ‘one China’ policy. However, the present Taiwanese administration views Taiwan as an independent sovereign state. This tension has the potential to escalate into military confrontation, which could involve the USA under the Taiwan Relations Act of 1979. 43 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005 (please note, all transcripts are available from the author. 44 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 3, July 28, 2005. 45 Defence, Foreign Affairs, International Development and Trade Industry Committees (Quadripartite Committee). “Strategic Export Controls: HMG’s Annual Report for 2003, Licensing and Parliamentary Scrutiny” (London: HMSO, 2005). 36 3. IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W “H UMAN RIGHTS HAVE BEEN A VERY SMALL PART OF THIS WHOLE 46 DISCUSSION ” : THE ROLE OF HUMAN RIGHTS CONSIDERATIONS IN SHAPING THE UK’S POSITION Given that Mr. Straw thought the embargo had ‘run its course,’ it becomes necessary to examine why the UK Government under the leadership Tony Blair took this stance. As previously mentioned, this paper focuses on the role of human rights in policymaking as a test for the Government’s explicit commitments to human rights. Consequently, we shall begin with a discussion of the role human rights plays in the considerations regarding the UK’s pro-lift position. A commitment to human rights forms one of the sets of priorities the FCO has in pursuing its foreign policy and is said to be “integral to the Government's wider foreign policy and security agenda.”47 However, the extent to which these considerations have played in the UK’s position on the EU arms embargo is not as transparent as its mission statement would indicate. Given that the embargo was originally put in place on human rights grounds, one might imagine that considerations of human rights also played a crucial role in the proposals for lifting the embargo. However, most of the evidence points to the contrary. As one source indicates “there hasn’t been a real attempt to push China to make human rights concessions as a quid pro quo for lifting the embargo.”48 The view that emerges is one of human rights as a “general foreign policy concern,” 49 which needs to be addressed not substantively in itself, but because of public perception or its instrumental uses. The Government puts little effort into ensuring human rights are taken seriously and the lack of clarification over what constitutes human rights means there is considerable room for interpretation, manipulation and manoeuvre, which the Government has used to the full in relation to this case. In the wider public sphere however, the subject of human rights has been raised on numerous occasions in respect of this policy: in Parliament, in the press and by NGO groups. NGOs have consistently raised concerns over the issue of human rights. Amnesty International urged the EU to consider carefully the message it would send out about human rights if the embargo were to be raised,50 whilst Human Rights Watch warned that to lift the embargo without sufficient pressure on the Chinese “would be a major setback for human rights in China and the EU’s reputation as a 46 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. Foreign and Commonwealth Office Website. “Speech of FCO minister, Ian Pearson” (21st July), http://www.fco.gov.uk, (accessed September 12, 2005). 48 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 49 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. 50 Amnesty International, EU Press Office Release, April 14 (Brussels: Amnesty International, 2004). 47 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 37 serious advocate for human rights.”51 In addition, some organisations took part in extensive lobbying of the UK and EU to promote further this aspect of the situation. 52 In the press, human rights considerations were also featured, albeit alongside the issues of regional stability involving Taiwan and the reaction from the US. Comment pieces in national newspapers warned of trading the embargo away lightly without due consideration of the human rights element: the “EU does not have to give away the embargo for free,” 53 suggesting concessions on human rights regarding the release of Tiananmen prisoners or ratification of the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights as an appropriate gesture by the Chinese. This is echoed by David Shambaugh in the International Herald Tribune who also cites China’s numerous human rights failings as a significant contributing factor to making the lift unacceptable.54 In Parliament, the subject has been raised both within the House of Commons and the House of Lords. As Tom Harris MP pointed out, since 1989, “China's human rights record has barely improved in any discernible way.”55 Similarly, several Early Day Motions (EDM) by MPs from across the parties make explicit reference to the human rights arguments surrounding the debate and raise concerns about the lifting of the embargo without taking these sufficiently into account. 56 As Greg Pope notes, “the lifting of the EU arms embargo is not warranted by China's appalling human rights record.”57 In addition to this, the Foreign Affairs Committee (FAC) Human Rights Report 2005 concludes that “the raising of the EU arms embargo on China would send the wrong signal at this time, in the absence of strong undertakings from the Chinese government to address human rights issues.”58 The acknowledgement of a human rights element to the debate by those involved in parliament, the media and NGOs is clear. However, the widespread vocalisation of these concerns was certainly less than that 51 Human Rights Watch, “Open Letter to Tony Blair, Prime Minister: Recommendations for the upcoming E.U.-China Summit”, http://www.hrw.org.uk (accessed August 30, 2005). 52 Alison Reynolds, interview with author, August 16, 2005. 53 The Guardian, “The Lure of Beijing,” May 25, 2005. 54 The International Herald Tribune, “EU To Put Brakes on Lifting the EU Arms Embargo to China”, April 13, 2005. 55 Hansard Reporting, “Tom Harris MP, Column 156-157” (London: TSO, January 25, 2005), www.parliament.uk. 56 H. Cohen, Early Day Motion 986: EU Arms Embargo on China (London: TSO, 2004); S. Doughty, Early Day Motion 630: Arms Embargo on China (London: TSO, 2005); all EDMs available at www.parliament.uk. 57 G. Pope, Early Day Motion 891: Arms Embargo in China No. 2 (London: TSO, 2005). 58 Foreign Affairs Committee, Human Rights Report 2005. (London: HMSO, 2005), 7, 36. 38 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W garnered in 1989, owing to the lack of a specific, high profile, emotive media event. This is not to deny that there were no other concerns to be expressed if the embargo were to be lifted.59 Crucially though, human rights concerns, while acknowledged by all as at least minimally relevant to the public debate, were given very different discursive and political priority by different groups. For the FAC, Greg Pope and the 31 MPs that signed his motion, human rights concerns were enough in themselves for the embargo to remain. For others, it was enough to raise grave concerns and call for a compulsory review of the embargo before a decision on its lifting should be made.60 Yet for the Government, these concerns featured little in the formation of their position on the issue and the possibility of a review, indicated by Straw, has never been fully substantiated: “There has never been a review in the sense of ‘let’s see what having the embargo there has achieved. Let’s see whether we should maintain it or even strengthen it.’ Instead, it has been more about ‘shall we lift it?’ and if so ‘how can we mitigate the impact?’ When you see a review being spoken of, that’s rubbish.”61 This suggests that Government considerations were purely instrumental and totally divorced from the original objectives of the embargo; it also seems to suggest that the lift was seen as inevitable and therefore the Government concentrated on the effect of the decision itself, rather than whether to lift it or not. To the extent that the Government did take account of the human rights element it can be seen more as an exercise in damage control. It did offer responses to the human rights concerns discussed by arguing firstly, that it believed China had improved its human rights record since 1989 and secondly, following on from the first point, that it did not belong in the same category as other states under embargoes. A standard response to the human rights argument within this debate, from the Government was that “the human rights situation in China has eased” and is “significantly better than it was 15 or 16 years ago.”62 Bill Rammel MP demonstrates this position in a speech given on China in Westminster Hall: “Human rights and individual freedoms, particularly on the economic and social side, have undoubtedly increased greatly in the 59 Increased arms sales to China and the potential for this to cause regional instability; potential to destabilise China’s relationship with Taiwan and the potential for damage to UK transatlantic relations were all concerns that were openly expressed by MPs, Peers, the media and NGOs alike. 60 M. Ancram, Early Day Motion 1004: Arms Embargo on China (no.2) (London: TSO, 2005). 61 Interview with source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 62 Defence, Foreign Affairs, International Development and Trade Industry Committees (Quadripartite Committee), Oral evidence given by Jack Straw, Q114 on January 12, 2005. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 39 past 10 years.”63 The Chinese would also point to the amount of people they have pulled out of poverty since 1989 and indicate these as advances in social, economic and development rights; a position the Government is willing to accept. 64 However, by emphasising economic and social rights they seem to be moving the parameters away from the original abuses that caused the embargo’s imposition. These were abuses of civil and political freedoms surrounding issues of freedom of expression. In this area, the Chinese Government can hardly point to any improvement, as is discussed below. The invocation of social and economic rights raises questions about the trade off between different kinds of rights and which ones take priority. It also indicates the ease with which the discourse of human rights can be manipulated and broken down to serve the interests of different groups. Since there are no clear criteria as to which rights rank higher or lower in priority, there is no way to significantly judge a country’s record with any consistency. If the British Government agrees with the Chinese on the significance of economic and social rights in this instance, then they would seem to be indicating the lesser importance of civil and political rights, yet arguably, since the embargo relates specifically to the Tiananmen incident and the abuse of rights there, the Government’s arguments are not addressing the key reasons for the embargo’s imposition, making their stance largely irrelevant. Moreover, without consistent criteria for assessing how much better or worse things have gotten, it is hard for this discourse to have any real practical meaning, either for governments or civil society. This leads to perhaps one of the most striking aspects of the debate in the UK, which is how the events of Tiananmen Square, having been absolutely central to justifying and motivating the original embargo, are frequently elided or pushed to the margins in government statements and policy considerations. With Tiananmen and civil rights restored to its central discursive position, the argument for retaining the embargo on human rights ground flows easily. Not only are political dissidents imprisoned after the events still in jail, but during the run up to the fifteenth anniversary of the crackdown the Chinese Government showed that little had really changed in their approach, either to the event itself or to the issues surrounding freedom of expression that it represents. The government “still forbids any public commemoration of the event. Police harass and detain those dedicated to securing rehabilitation of victims, payment of compensation, or reconsideration of the official verdict.” 65 63 Hansard Reporting, “Bill Rammell MP, Column 337W pt 24” (London: TSO, March 16, 2005), www.parliament.uk. 64 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005 65 Human Rights Watch, World Report 2005 (New York: Human Rights Watch, 2005), 1. 40 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W Even the installation of a new leadership 66 in 2003 did not bring about a significant turn around in the official Chinese view of events, with the attitude of the Chinese administration remaining unapologetic. The new government still refuses a review of the events, and the impunity surrounding 1989 is ongoing, with no signal that this will change.67 Returning to the Government’s claim about the ‘easing’ of the human rights situation in China, even if one was to concede that the events of Tiananmen Square were no longer relevant, a big concession admittedly, these claims of an ‘easing’ are not as well evidenced as the Government would like to imply. The evidence to condemn China’s human rights record is readily available and can even be found within the FCO, the very department that is attempting to argue its improvement. The FCO’s own Hu man Rights Report 2005 still lists China in the ‘Major Countries of Concern’ section, with the UK continuing to have “serious concerns about basic human rights in China.” 68 They are not alone. International NGO groups have frequently and consistently condemned China’s human rights record. Amnesty International, although seeming to agree to some extent with the UK Government’s assessment that the human rights situation has improved, stresses that whilst “there was progress towards reform in some areas, this failed to have a significant impact on serious and widespread human rights violations perpetuated across the country.” 69 It is not just these ‘usual suspects’ that hold this concern. The US Department of State’s 2004 Country Reports on Human Rights Practices details the countless failings in China’s human rights record of recent times claiming that “China’s cooperation and progress on human rights during 2004 was disappointing. China failed to fulfil many of the commitments it made at 66 The pairing of Hu Jintao, President and Wen Jiabao, Prime Minister The Guardian, “Tiananmen Review Rejected,” June 7, 2005. 68 Foreign and Commonwealth Office, Human Rights Report 2005 (London: HMSO, 2005), 40. 69 Amnesty International, Undermining Global Security: The EU’s Arms Exports 2004 (London: Amnesty International, 2004). Areas of improvement included: new regulations aimed at preventing torture in police custody; an amendment to the Constitution in March stated “the state respects and protects human rights”; progress was also made on China’s AIDS/HIV epidemic with a new law to strengthen AIDS prevention and stop discrimination against those infected; China also continued to engage in human rights dialogues with other countries and allowed the UN Working Group on Arbitrary Detention to visit. However, the government still arbitrarily detained peaceful activists and advocates of reform; freedom of expression continued to be curtailed; violence against women was widespread as a result of the family planning policy; imprisonment and detainment of political activists was still widespread; repression and detention of the Falun Gong movement and other unofficial religious groups continued; the death penalty continued to be used extensively and arbitrarily; torture continued in a wide variety of state institutions; there was forcible deportation of North-Korean Asylum seekers; harsh repression on the Uighur minority in Xinjiang continued to be justified by the ‘war on terror’; Freedom of religion, expression and association continued in Tibet with arbitrary arrests and trials. 67 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 41 the 2002 US-China Human Rights Dialogue.”70 Thus, the US seems to be in disagreement with the UK as to the level of human rights progress that has actually been obtained within China. This provokes questions as to the evidence and criteria each government uses. Either they both work from identical criteria but disagree on evidence or they have the same evidence but a totally different understanding of what is an acceptable ‘easing’ of conditions. If human rights were really a central consideration, one would expect the UK Government to make its criteria clear; it has failed to do so and has further complicated the issue by invoking social and economic rights. Again, there is a lack of clarity, which seems to indicate a probable lack of seriousness on the part of the Government. A further line of argument the Government has used with the intention of justifying the removal of the arms embargo, was that China did not deserve to be in the same category as other states such as Burma and Zimbabwe, which are subject to similar arms embargoes. Jack Straw intimated that he had “long understood China’s argument, which is that to lump them in with, say, Burma and Zimbabwe is not appropriate and I do not think it is.”71 This seems to imply that although China is a human rights abuser, it is not as big an abuser as the likes of Burma and Zimbabwe and does not deserve to be castigated in this manner. Given the previous discussion over the confusion of the ranking of rights and which ones figure highest, it is hard to then understand the Foreign Secretary’s implied view that China is less of a human rights abuser than Burma or Zimbabwe. As far as the Government has shown, it has no explicit criteria in making this judgment, nor does the Foreign Secretary give any further explanation as to why exactly China no longer deserves to be in the same group as these two. Again, there is lack of clarity and of consistency showing an overall lack of seriousness in considering the issue of human rights in China. Aside from these arguments relating to the embargo, sources close to the Government were keen to point to the bilateral human rights dialogues that exist between China and the UK and stress these as the appropriate means of tackling human rights issues with China. 72 This is further 70 US Department of State, Introduction at http://www.state.gov/g/drl/rls/hrrpt/2004/41586.htm: The report criticises China’s record on arresting and detaining political activists, as well as those freely discussing ideas on the Internet, those attending house churches, lawyers acting on behalf of dissidents and the disposed, workers protesting their rights, journalists and intellectuals. It is also critical of continued abuses in prisons, the crackdown on the Falun Gong and states that the Constitution amendment to include protection of human rights, remains unclear as to what extent the Government plans to implement this. 71 Defence, Foreign Affairs, International Development and Trade Industry Committees (Quadripartite Committee), Oral evidence given by Jack Straw. 72 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005; Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 3, July 28, 2005. 42 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W supported by various parliamentary questions raised on China’s human rights record, which sees ex-FCO minister, Bill Rammell consistently pointing to the dialogue as the correct means of raising such issues with China. 73 Together with the FCO, 74 these sources also have pointed to projects that the UK had undertaken in China. 75 It is argued that these dialogues and programs show the UK’s commitment to human rights in China and are said to be more effective than the embargo at making a difference to the situation in the country. However, Dunne and Wheeler 76 showed these dialogues have in reality born little fruit. Instead, the Chinese have used the dialogue as an end in itself, avoiding further scrutiny of the human rights situation and threatening withdrawal from the talks should the UK bring robust pressure.77 Yet, despite the failings of these dialogues, the UK has refused to acknowledge the opportunity to use the embargo as a tool of leverage over China on human rights. As Alison Reynolds of Free Tibet argues, UK policy towards China on human rights has “for too long been channelled into a very specific programme, which is the bilateral human rights dialogues.”78 Her point is that the UK should be pursuing its human rights agenda with China through a variety of means and valuing a diverse approach. The UK Government has failed to acknowledge that the “EU arms embargo is a fantastically powerful means of leverage.”79 The Chinese have applied considerable diplomatic pressure in trying to get the embargo lifted: “Their lobbying was very forceful with no real hint that they felt they needed to do anything in return.” 80 Such vigorous lobbying indicates the importance the Chinese have attached to the lifting of the embargo. With this kind of desire the EU could have used the embargo as a tool with which to secure certain concessions on the basis of human rights. This is something that the UK has seemingly ignored, rather content on shifting the focus to the dialogues and programmes it pursues, without acknowledging the human rights dimension of the debate or realising the 73 Hansard Reporting, ”Bill Rammell MP, Column 1549W pt24” (London: TSO, November 16, 2004); Hansard Reporting, “Bill Rammell MP, Column 1651W pt26” (London: TSO, 12 February, 2004); Hansard Reporting, “Bill Rammell MP, Column 337W pt 24” (London: TSO, March 16, 2005); Hansard Reporting, “Bill Rammell MP, Column 971W pt16” (London: TSO, February 28, 2005). All available at www.parliament.uk. 74 Foreign and Commonwealth Office. 75 These include: promoting judicial justice by reforming criminal trial procedure; reforming the death penalty review system; standardising the death penalty through sentencing guidelines; police and human rights and enhancing human rights in prisons. (Foreign and Commonwealth Office, 44). 76 Dunne and Wheeler, “Blair’s Britain: A Force for Good in the World?” 77 Foreign Affairs Committee, Tenth Report: People’s Republic of China. 78 Alison Reynolds, interview. 79 Alison Reynolds, interview. 80 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 43 power they might have over China in this circumstance. It demonstrates, along with the previous evidence, a lack of willingness to allow human rights to play a significant role in policy discussion, preferring instead to keep it boxed away in specific dialogues, which have a questionable reputation for success. Again, a human rights profile is maintained but the reality is that they are frequently sidelined in broader policy discussions and the ineffective bilateral dialogues may suit the interests of the UK as much as China, in that they project an image that cares about human rights, but this is backed by little substance. A closer institutional analysis of the role of the Human Rights, Democracy and Governance Group (HRDGG) in the policy formulation process confirms this general impression. It is true that the HRDGG was consulted on the issue,81 yet the extent and nature of this consultation remains unclear due to restrictions imposed because of the current undecided nature of the policy and its ongoing sensitivity. One source close to the Government asserted that there were “three pillars”82 within the FCO that were involved with the discussion of the arms embargo. These were the Counter Proliferation Department, the East Asia Group and the EU Department (External). The HRDGG was not mentioned as a major player within the policy process. Furthermore, the main forum for public discussion on this issue was the Quadripartite Committee, whose remit is to deal with strategic export controls. Those giving evidence to the Quadripartite Committee 83 on this topic along with Jack Straw were Edward Oakden, Director of Defence and Strategic Threats, and David Landsman, Head of the Counter-Proliferation Department. This indicates that these departments were considered by the Government to be the most important players involved. The extent to which the embargo was discussed in any other forum seems to have been minimal. Furthermore, former Amnesty International Campaigns Manager for Arms and Trade, Robert Parker suggests that the role of the HRDGG within the FCO is severely limited with respect to arms exports licensing. Based on his own investigations, he found that although the HRDGG was the agency responsible for raising human rights concerns in the FCO “it was unclear whether concerns raised by the HRPD (now the HRDGG) would always be circulated to the DTI 84 , or whether their concerns were sometimes taken out of the final collective FCO response if the decision to support the licence application had been made. They don’t have the power to actually veto applications on human rights grounds, and it was 81 HRDGG (pers. comm.) Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 83 Committee made up of the Defence, Foreign Affairs, International Development and Trade Industry Committees. 84 Department of Trade and Industry, the department responsible for all final decision on export applications. 82 44 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W unclear to what extent they ‘have the ear’ of the Foreign Secretary over and above other FCO departments such as the Counter Proliferation Department.” 85 Considering the previous evidence on those who were involved, the HRDGG seems to have played an equally shadowy role in this arms licensing debate than in previous ones. Overall, human rights have played into this policy formulation only in the most confusing, contradictory, endlessly mutable, and flexible manner. This is perhaps inevitable given that all the evidence points to government indifference or at the most, negligible interest towards the human rights concerns originally behind the embargo. There is also evidence of the absence of basic, clear, commensurate criteria across departments, governments and NGOs on human rights standards providing proper means of assessment, comparison and debate. There is a great deal of room for different interpretations and stances, all apparently equally loyal to ‘human rights’. Lastly, the Government’s bilateral human rights dialogues with China have provided a veil to hide behind, with the Government doing little to incorporate these concerns in wider debates. The rest of the paper will examine further the first point raised above, namely the Government’s indifference to human rights on this policy and focusing on two main factors, and seek to explain why human rights concerns, in this instance were not valued by the UK Government and what other considerations were viewed as more important. 4. THE RISE OF CHINA AND THE “ BIG SYMBOLIC PRIZE”86 : THE ROLE OF THE GROWING C HINESE ECONOMY IN SHAPING THE UK’S POSITION Although it can be argued convincingly that China’s human rights record has not changed significantly since 1989, other extremely important factors in the country’s strategic importance to other states have. It’s not new to note the amazing rise of China as an economic power. China is the world’s fastest growing economy and as the most populous country on the planet, it increasingly tantalizes the national interests of other states by offering a potentially enormous market for European trade and by having the ability to effect world markets. Secondly, and flowing on from the previous point, China’s foreign policy has consequently become more important. As it begins to have a greater influence on the international market, it becomes more important to other international actors and demands greater attention. As Sutter notes “China’s present international significance rests heavily on its rapidly 85 86 Robert Parker, written interview, received August 16, 2005. Interview conducted with a source close to the government 2, July 26, 2005. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 45 growing economy and its increasing integration with the world economy.”87 Having already seen that one of the FCO’s priorities relates to the promotion of human rights, a glance at another priority may hold the key to why human rights was accorded so little attention. The UK pledges, as a foreign policy priority, the “promotion of economic interests in an open and expanding global economy.” 88 With such a rapidly expanding economy, China can hardly be left out of the UK’s calculations when considering the potential future of the global economy in benefiting British interests. The importance to the UK of a profitable trade relationship with China is further supported by the FAC in stating that “the heart of the Government’s new China policy has been a focus on promoting the United Kingdom’s commercial interests.” 89 So, can the decision by the UK to support the lifting of the arms embargo be seen as an attempt by the UK to pursue this particular foreign policy priority with China? Although there is some room for debate in this area, the majority of the evidence seems to suggest that the role of economic motivation itself was not key. Firstly, the incentive for increased arms trade with China was not present, and secondly, the incentives towards less direct, commercial benefits were not obvious, thus, not making them a key factor on their own. However, the increasing importance of China as an international actor due to its expanding economy was a key driver, making the decision to lift the embargo one of political symbolic value rather than material and commercial one. In respect to the arms trade, the removal of the embargo is not expected to open up any major new markets for the UK. The EU’s Code of Conduct, 90 which already regulates and assesses the granting of license for arms exports against a series of criteria, is expected to maintain a similar level of control over the market as the embargo. This is debatable and is contested by NGOs.91 They argue that the existence of the Code means that there is in place a regulatory mechanism on the arms trade, which is seen to prevent, to a degree, the granting of export licenses. In turn this 87 R. Sutter, “Why Does China Matter?” Washington Quarterly 27, no. 1 (2004): 76. Foreign and Commonwealth Office Website, “UK Priorities.” 89 Foreign Affairs Committee, Tenth Report: People’s Republic of China, paragraph 88 109. 90 Introduced in 1998, the Code of Conduct defines a list of criteria and operative provision that must be met by all EU member states when exporting arms. Within this Criterion 2 takes into account human rights, referring to the non-export of arms to countries where the export may be used for internal repression. Criterion 4 takes into consideration issues of regional peace, security and stability. 91 For a full exploration of the Code’s failings see: Saferworld, Taking Control (London: Saferworld, 2004); Amnesty International, Undermining Global Security: The EU’s Arms Exports 2004; Oxfam, Lock, Stock and Barrel (Oxford: Oxfam, 2004). 46 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W means that a motivation by the UK, based solely on the chance of increased arms sales would be implausible. Brinley Salzmann, Director of exports for the Defence Manufacturers Association sees little aspiration from EU member states to capitalise on the embargo’s removal, confirms this.92 In regards to the UK, an increase in arms sales, related specifically to the embargo lift, is almost certainly sure not to arise for two reasons. Firstly, due to the nature of the UK license application procedure as it stands, and secondly, due to the relationship that the UK defence industry has with the USA. Salzmann claims that he “can be perfectly certain that a lifting of the embargo won’t result in any additional defence sales to China,” 93 due particularly to the nature of the UK licensing procedure as it already stands. He describes this as a “very strict and robust assessment criteria for China.” 94 Secondly, because of the UK’s close transatlantic ties with the USA and the USA’s relationship with Taiwan, any attempt by the UK defence industry to sell weapons to the Chinese could potentially rebound in a reactionary loss of sales from the US market or US sanctions. 95 At the present time, in relation to the arms industry “the Americans are our biggest off shore supplier. They are our second biggest export customers in the world and they are our biggest collaborative partners.”96 American business relations, for the UK arms industry, are too important to be jeopardised by US retaliation over sales to China. BAE Systems demonstrated as much when they claimed they would not sell arms to China if the embargo were to be lifted, for fear of endangering their extensive American interests.97 Although the embargo lift might seem like a potential opening for arms sales, this is not the case. In terms of a potential market for arms, China is even less attractive to the UK than it is to other EU member states given its already strong licensing procedure and the close business links with the American arms industry. If it is not going to cause a direct positive economic impact on the UK defense industry, the question then 92 Brinley Salzmann, interview with author, July 21, 2005. Brinley Salzmann. 94 Brinley Salzmann. 95 The Guardian, “Europe Risks Sanctions Over China Arms Sales”, March 3, 2005; J. Tkacik, “The East Asia Security Act: A Step Towards Consensus Against Arms Sales To China,” (The Heritage Foundation, 2005). Details the East Asia Security Act, which was recently defeated in Congress. The EASA mandates that any person, firm, or country that provides military arms, equipment, or technology to China or dual-use items to the Chinese military, security forces, police, or other repressive agencies face heightened scrutiny of its arms relationship with China and, if warranted, be denied access to U.S. weapons technology. 96 Brinley Salzmann. 97 The Times, “British Arms Firm Will Spurn China If Embargo Ends”, February 22, 2005. 93 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 47 arises concerning other less direct commercial benefits that might occur from the embargo lift and whether these had any impact upon the consideration of the UK government in choosing to support the lifting of the embargo. In favour of this proposition are assessments based on past Chinese attitudes to sanctions imposed against them and diplomatic or political moves by other states, which do not fit with the Chinese government’s aims. Past actions might imply that the Chinese, upon lifting the embargo, would reward those member states in the EU who had been proponents of the lift and punish those states that had been against it. Evidence relating to Chinese actions concerning commercial ties would seem to indicate that the government does work, to some extent, on such a ‘tit-for-tat’ basis. For example, the US imposed trade sanctions on China after it had transferred military equipment to Pakistan. In response, Chinese aviation authorities switched to buying from the US company Boeing to the European Airbus. Additionally, upon selling jets to Taiwan, France suffered short-term economic harm in relation to its interests in China. 98 Consequently, it could be inferred that being seen to support the embargo lift might cause similar results. The importance of good political and bilateral ties with China to the advancement of commercial interests in the country is key. When the president of China visited the UK in 1999 “major commercial contracts worth a total of 2 billion were signed”99 and as Lord Powell, Chair of the China Britain Business Council argues, “A good bilateral relationship at the political level is very important for doing business in China—and probably more important in the case of China than most other countries, simply because the role of the state and the government is so big.”100 However, despite this kind of evidence, in relation to the embargo, the advancement of commercial economic interests by the UK has not been the “main driver,” 101 although it has probably had some effect on the policy making process. From sources close to the Government and those outside it, the picture that emerges is one where, although long-term economic interests were considered and are generally considered with regards to China, in respect to the embargo policy, it was not the main driving force behind their decision to support a lift. This was primarily due to the intangible nature of any derived benefits. The sources indicated that there were no particular references by the Chinese of specific or even more general commercial areas that might benefit. Moreover, as one source argued, even though “the French had been pushing for it very clearly - as is seen 98 Breslin, 421. Foreign and Commonwealth Office Website. “FCO Strategy” (accessed September 12, 2005). 100 Oral evidence to Foreign Affairs Committee. 101 Bill Olner, interview with author, July 18, 2005. 99 48 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W by the Chinese to have been pushing for it very clearly - it wasn’t altogether clear that they would repay the bilateral incentives for doing so.” The economic incentive is “an argument you could advance but the evidence doesn’t seem to back it up.”102 The benefits of lifting the embargo for the UK would, in terms of trade and improved relations be long-term and fairly imperceptible103 and consideration of this factor would have to be balanced against the detrimental effect that lifting of the embargo might have in UK/US commercial ties. Overall, China’s rise in terms of economics has been considered as part of the formulation of the position of the UK on the embargo lift but did not form a major component and can probably best be thought of as an ongoing long-term strategic engagement with China in commercial terms. In that sense, it fits with the wider move towards economic engagement and the UK priority as it relates to the global economy. However, there was a further incentive at work, closely connected with the economic rise of China, but more concerned with its role on the wider international scene than with its economic potential and more concerned with social engagement of China than economic engagement. The desire to bring China into the international community and provide a symbolic gesture that would make the Chinese government feel more included and respected in the international community can perhaps be seen as the fundamental driver in the formulation of the UK’s position. 104 This is underpinned by the theory, espoused by Wang and Deng,105 that including China more in international society will help it to be more shaped by the multilateral institutions it belongs to and become a responsible and constructive player within the international community: “International enmeshment facilitates China’s social learning in terms of the values, norms and principles, and rules of the international system.” This approach was summarised by the FAC when they concluded that the UK should attempt to encourage and support China’s closer integration into the international system, in all fields, as a friendly and responsible partner. 106 In this context, the embargo can be seen as a perfect opportunity in accomplishing this objective. “Th ere are lots of global challenges where we need China on the same side. You do not help that process - in fact you actively hinder it - if you have them somewhere as a pariah, as some way stigmatising them and an arms embargo is a good way 102 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 104 Bill Olner, interview; Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005; Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005; Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 3, July 28, 2005; Brinley Salzmann, interview; Roy Isbister, interview with author, July 27, 2005. 105 F. Wang and Y. Deng, In the Eyes of the Dragon: China Views the World (Lanham, MD: Brown & Littlefield, 1999). 106 Foreign Affairs Committee. 103 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 49 of doing that.” 107 By lifting the embargo, “you’ve given the Chinese a big symbolic prize and they know it’s a prize and you know it’s a prize.”108 This would then have the hoped effect of moving forward some kind of social and political engagement with China and help in other areas such as global warming or being more responsible members of the Security Council. In one source’s estimate this was “the only driver for doing it.” 109 The Government is “not interested in making statements for the sake of it.” 110 Their agreement to support the symbolic gesture in favour of China by lifting the embargo is backed up by the perceived benefits it may accrue in terms of China’s increased socialisation into the international community, long-term stability and institutionalisation. However, the opposing effect of this positive symbolic gesture is the negative one sent out in respect of human rights. Without any significant progress on human rights in China, the symbolic reward of the embargo lift sends out a damaging message about the extent to which human rights are considered and the importance attached to them. Yet the UK has chosen to ignore this element demonstrating that making a purely symbolic stand on human rights is not a policy option. Human rights in themselves are not enough to motivate states to act and this supports a more realist approach, where national interests must be satisfied. In this case, this is through the perceived long-term, geopolitical benefits to the UK. However, this attempt at socialisation is something of a contradictory response. In attempting to socialise China into international norms by violating one of the founding ones, namely human rights, one can hardly hope to successfully achieve their respect for international standards. Rather it would send out a message that “either you think that human rights in China are ok or you don’t really care about them.” 111 The Government has already shown that it is not of the opinion that China’s human rights are ‘ok’. This leaves the latter response and such a signal can hardly hope to achieve respect for human rights from the Chinese if they see this norm disregarded by those who purport to uphold it. Consequently, whether these attempts to integrate China will be successful remains to be seen however, the embargo policy can be seen as part of this wider attempt to engage with China and bring it into the international fold. It would produce no tangible short-term economic benefits, only long-term intangible ones, but may produce concessions in other vital areas in terms of international cooperation. Unfortunately, the UK failed to see the negative side of this symbolic gesture in terms of the value of human rights and the contradictory nature of the message it was 107 Interview conducted Interview conducted 109 Interview conducted 110 Interview conducted 111 Interview conducted 108 with with with with with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. a source close to the Government 1, July 11 2005. a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. 50 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W sending out, which could undermine the socialisation they are attempting to achieve. The long-term economic incentive to advance UK commercial interests in China was present to some degree in the policy formulation, but this was a minimal factor compared to the political symbolism of the embargo lift. 5. “THE GREAT EUROPEAN POWER PISSING CONTEST” 112 VERSUS “THE 113 EIGHT HUNDRED POUND GORILLA IN THE ROOM” : THE ROLE OF THE EU AND THE USA IN SHAPING THE UK’S POSITION Britain’s diplomatic ties with the rest of the world also feature within FCO strategy and it emphasises the need for the FCO to work with others in order to meet the priorities that they’ve set out: “No country can tackle these issues alone,” 114 yet they also stress that “our most important partnerships will be within the EU and with the United States.”115 As Hill argues, “New Labour has sought to be friends with almost everyone.” 116 It has built a strong relationship with the EU, whilst maintaining a close relationship with the White House. It has also adopted the role of a bridge between the two actors 117 leading to “a vast range of commitments, even when times are serene.” 118 When times are not ‘serene’, such as with the embargo debate, the range of commitments required to both actors can restrict the UK’s to the point where it is unable to take its own stance on the issue. It found itself “caught between two stalls in quite a classic way,”119 with little room for manoeuvre. Given that the arms embargo is an EU policy, the role of the institution in shaping UK policy is crucial. The positions that other member states took on the issue greatly affected the way that the UK was able to precede with its own agenda. The issue first arose at the EU European Council Summit on 18 December 2003 where France and Germany proposed the lifting of the embargo. France began the initial talk and “was keen to show that it was China’s best friend in Europe.” 120 Germany also lent their voice in support of the lift, with Schroeder coming out strongly in support. This overt support of the lift from the 112 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. Roy Isbister, interview. 114 Foreign and Commonwealth Office Website, “FCO Strategy.” 115 Foreign and Commonwealth Website, “FCO Strategy.” 116 C. Hill, “Foreign Policy” in The Blair Effect: The Blair Government 1997-2001, ed. A. Seldon, 348 (London: Little, Brown and Company, 2001), 348. 117 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July, 11 2005; Interview conducted with source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005; Bill Olner, interview. 118 Hill, 348. 119 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 120 Interview conducted with a source close to the government 1, July 11, 2005. 113 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 51 UK’s European great power rivals left the UK in a difficult position in forming their own take on the arms embargo issue. Once these two countries had come out in favour of the lift, the UK had little option than to agree with them. The nature of the UK’s position within the EU meant that they were under a lot of pressure not to go against the two other major powers and risk isolation in Europe. 121 The prominent advocacy of the other two states also meant that any attemp t to take a different position would run the risk of the UK being seen as anti-China. If they had sought to take a strong stance against the embargo this is the perception that would have come across particularly to the Chinese who might, as discussed earlier, have punished the UK in the form of a withdrawal from economic cooperation and damaged their bilateral relationship. According to one source, the UK was motivated by a desire not to be caught out: “If France was going to lead the show and you want to stand in the way of that, then you can’t help but be seen as extremely anti-China. I think that’s just the way European politics works.”122 The UK “wanted to stay in the pack.” 123 This meant agreeing with the two other member states. On a leadership level of analysis, membership of the EU also exerted its pressure. Tony Blair would not have wanted to take a position on the embargo that was against that of his French and German equivalents: “It would not have been acceptable to the Prime Minister or the Government to take a much more backward position on lifting the embargo in leadership terms against Chirac and Schroeder.”124 Presumably, this is due to keeping up a certain political image within the EU and not letting either of the other two prominent member state leaders overtake him in importance or profile. The eyes of Number 10 were firmly on the process within the FCO and were watching it “particularly closely.” 125 This attention was further heightened by the approach of the UK’s ascendancy to the presidency of the EU. As one MP argues, “the policy has been decided not on the basis of our national interest, but on the short-term tactical interest of the Prime Minister at the beginning of the EU presidency. The obsession with regaining popularity among European leaders seems to take precedence over any other considerations.”126 121 Interview conducted a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005; Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005; Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 3, July 28, 2005. 122 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 123 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 124 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 125 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. 126 Hansard Reporting, “Dr Liam Fox MP, Column 164 pt4” (London: TSO, May 18, 2005), www.parliament.uk. 52 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W At the European level, the UK’s hands were tied by the prominent positions of its major counterparts in Europe. Both on UK level and a leadership level, it would not have been possible for the UK to make any kind of strong stance on the embargo for fear of being isolated in Europe and of being punished by the Chinese. However, the UK’s hands were also tied from another angle by its relationship with the US. Arguably the most powerful state on the planet, the USA has played a progressively increasing role of importance within the discussions surrounding the embargo. Given that the policy is an EU one and bears no direct relation to the US, the involvement of the state could have been thought to be minimal. However, it appears that the USA may have been the single strongest factor in determining how the UK reacted towards the proposals to lift the arms embargo. For some, the pressure that the USA exerted during the discussions around the policy is the main reason why the embargo is still in place. Roy Isbister of Saferworld believes that “if it weren’t for the US the embargo would have been lifted. Ultimately, that’s what has so far delayed any lifting”127 and there is convincing evidence to support this claim. When listing the factors involved with the issue of the embargo, one source close to the government cited America first 128 detailing how “you have to take American concerns quite seriously…that was a significant factor.”129 Bill Olner MP, who stresses that “you can’t forget that the USA plays a big role in this as well”, further supports this.130 Furthermore, at present concern over America’s response to the embargo lift is at the point where no further progress can be made without some kind of change in the US’s stance: “We do want to lift the embargo, but we can’t do it with the Americans in the way they are, because their retaliation would be horrible.”131 The reason that the US is such a significant factor, as already discussed, is because of its relationship with Taiwan. If the arms embargo were to be lifted, the US would fear an increased sale of arms and European military technology to China. This demonstrates a lack of trust in the EU’s system of arms export control, the Code of Conduct, a point that Salzmann confirms: “They don’t understand how robust or export control policies and procedures are over here.”132 Consequently, any proposed lifting of the embargo, if not handled properly, could sour the relations between the EU and the US: “There could be an EU/US dispute of almost 127 Roy Isbister, interview. Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. 129 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. 130 Bill Olner, interview. 131 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 132 Brinley Salzmann, interview. 128 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 53 the order of magnitude of Iraq. That is what people in Washington have indicated.”133 This would hit the UK hardest given their closer ties with the US not only on a commercial basis, as discussed earlier, but also given their closer diplomatic and political relations between the two countries. What is evident is that there is a difference between the way the US views China and the way the EU does. The Americans are much more concerned about military advances, and this can be ascribed to their relationship with Taiwan. However, it can also be ascribed to balance of power concerns over China’s strengthening economy and increasing modernisation. These concerns are all too valid according to Mearsheimer. 134 As stated earlier, China has the potential to rival the US’s powerful position internationally thus, the US’s anti-lift position may best fit with the containment theories of the mid 1990s in attempting to block the country’s rise. This contrasts greatly with the EU’s pursuit of enmeshment and integration discussed earlier, suggesting that the two actors are operating on different agendas with regards to China. However, in the real world of diplomatic pressure these two agendas have clashed and forced the presentation of the policy to undergo fundamental changes. In relation to the UK, the significance of US pressure was how it forced the UK to act within Europe. In the EU Council conclusions of December 2004, the EU concludes that as a result of lifting the embargo there must be no quantitative or qualitative increase in arms sales.135 This clause is an attempt to placate America’s fears that any embargo lift will cause arms sales to rocket. Although keen to stress that the decision on this matter, as with all matters in the EU is a decision by the twenty-five member states collectively, 136 the UK engineered the inclusion of the clause, since it served its vested interest in keeping the USA at bay. 137 The escalation of the situation in the Straits into a military conflict is not something that any country wants to see, but with the EU lacking a fundamental tie to the situation, its interests in this area are of less concern. Thus, the clause can best be seen as an effort by the UK to pacify US fears. Further evidence of the importance of the US in shaping the UK’s position was shown when the Chinese passed an anti-secession law against Taiwan, which in the event of Taiwan claiming any form of independence 133 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. John Mearsheimer, The Tragedy of Great Power Politics (New York: W. W. Norton, 2001), 337. 135 European Council, “Brussels European Council Presidency Conclusions 16/17 December,” http://ue.eu.int/ueDocs/cms_Data/docs/pressData/en/ec/83 201.pdf (accessed September 12, 2005), conclusion 57. 136 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 3, July 28, 2005. 137 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 134 54 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W from mainland China, would allow the use of “non-peaceful means and other necessary measures to protect China's sovereignty and territorial integrity.” 138 This blatant reference to the use of force against Taiwan happened at a sensitive time for the arms embargo discussions and changed the terms of the debate entirely: “by passing that legislation and that law the Chinese were actually doing something quite provocative at a quite stupid time” 139 and the Foreign Secretary Jack Straw admitted that the law had created “a difficult political environment” for the embargo to be lifted.140 Here was proof of violent intentions and gave concrete evidence for the US to back up their concerns about military action. It also gave the UK an excellent excuse for lowering the ratchet of the debate and easing the pressure that the role of a bridge between the US and the EU and been putting upon them: “The anti secession law was good for us. It allowed us to point to an objective factor out there.” 141 The UK could bow to US pressure without being overtly seen to be doing so and persuade the rest of the EU that there was no longer consensus on the issue therefore, it should be dropped from the agenda. However, the interesting point to note here is that whilst human rights had been at the background of the debate within the UK and the EU, after the passing of the anti-secession law they began to come to the forefront and an expression of conditionality on human rights grounds for the lifting of the embargo began to surface. In April 2005, a French diplomat, when asked if this was the case said, “this link is indeed beginning to emerge.”142 In May of this year “representatives of the European Union decided to delay a move to lift the arms embargo against China, citing human rights”143 and referring specifically to four areas of concern. 144 In parallel to the EU, Alison Reynolds notes that the first time the UK Government really began to take the human rights argument seriously was in April 2005, after the anti-secession law. When Jack Straw gave evidence to the Quadripartite Committee in January 2005, the 138 Government of the People’s Republic of China, “The Anti Secession Law adopted at the Third Session of the Tenth National People’s Congress,” (March 14, 2005), Article 8. 139 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 2, July 26, 2005. 140 BBC News 2005, “EU may delay China arms move, 22nd March,” BBC News, http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/asia-pacific/4371361.stm (retrieved 31st August 2005), quoting Jack Straw. 141 Interview conducted with a source close to the Government 1, July 11, 2005. 142 The International Herald Tribune, “EU To Put Brakes on Lifting the EU Arms Embargo to China,” April 13, 2005 (quoting an anonymous French diplomat) 143 Amnesty International, “People’s Republic of China Briefing on EU Concerns Regarding Human Rights in China” (London: Amnesty International, September 2, 2005). 144 1. The need for China to release prisoners still held in connection with the events in Tiananmen Square in 1989 2. The need for the ratification of the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights by China 3. The need for reform of China’s ‘re-education through labour’ system 4. The need to ease media censorship. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 55 argument for human rights was barely considered at all.145 However, after the anti-secession law and the climate had changed, human rights began to be used as a way to back out, with credibility, of the June 2005 deadline for the lift. This again suggests that human rights alone are not enough to change the consideration of the UK, but in the face of other external factors they can be used (and abused) to support a quick reversal in policy decisions. The human rights argument had always been present, but the UK had chosen not to use it to its full force or make any pronounced stance in relation to it. It was only after the change in the dynamics of the debate, from the anti-secession law that saw the human rights argument drafted in to avoid openly admitting the law had created a change of such magnitude. The Chinese would not repeal the law and so the law itself could not be cited as an explicit reason for the embargo not being lifted. This would prevent lifting it in the future. Moreover, explicitly accepting the US’s anti-lift position would indicate a weakness on the part of the EU in forming their own foreign policy; a particularly sensitive area given the ongoing development of the EU’s Common Foreign and Security Policy. This would be an undesirable outcome for member states and weaken their position as an effective multilateral body, capable of pursuing their own goals. Consequently, putting human rights conditionality on China gave China something they could legitimately work towards and continue negotiating around, leaving the door open for the embargo to be lifted in the future, whilst also serving to avoid the EU looking like the US’s puppet. Human rights were not adopted for their own sake but because, at this particular conjuncture, they served the EU’s diplomatic and PR needs in relation to China, the US, the public and its own self-image quite efficiently. Overall, the positions of France and Germany directly affected the way the UK responded to the proposal to lift the embargo and the political dynamic in the EU meant the UK had little choice but to agree. The US’s relationship with Taiwan and its concerns over China’s growing power meant that its involvement in the arms embargo negotiations was also key and for the UK it was particularly important. They had to carefully consider their economic and diplomatic ties with both entities and attempt to bridge the gap between two actors following very different agendas. Furthermore, the US’s concerns about Taiwan and balance of power politics directly shaped the way the EU proceeded with the policy to lift the embargo and this was exemplified by the anti-secession law. The inclusion of human rights conditionality on the embargo lift after the antisecession law shows once more the use of human rights in an instrumental 145 Alison Reynolds, interview with author, August 16, 2005. 56 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W manner intended to keep the embargo lift on the agenda, avoiding embarrassment for the EU. 6. C ONCLUSION In summary, human rights were of minimal importance to the UK concerning this policy. The Government showed little regard for these considerations over and above its need to produce public perception of inclusion of this element and their use as an instrumental tool. It manipulated the discourse by invoking different sets of rights, without providing clear criteria by which to assess its claims. In addition, by consistently pointing to its bilateral human rights dialogues and programmes in China it sought to box off its human rights commitments in respect to China, missing opportunities to exert pressure and failing to draw a consistent picture of its human rights commitments. Linking this to its stated ‘ethical’ foreign policy goal, it is hard to see how the UK, in this instance, managed to maintain any such commitment. The Government’s indifference to human rights in this instance can be best explained by two other major factors, which were deemed of more importance. Firstly, China’s rise necessitates increased international cooperation and this led to a desire by the EU to give a symbolic gesture, in the form of the embargo lift, to remove stigmatisation and facilitate its socialisation. However, this long-term institutional approach should not be collapsed into suggesting that norms, such as human rights are important in any simple fashion. States may seek to enmesh China into the international community and its norms, but this may centre more on promoting general geo-political and financial stability than causing any great change in China’s domestic human rights situation. Improvement in this area may come in the long-term from this kind of approach, as normative theories argue. However, in this case a sufficiently nuanced realist framework is far more illuminating for understanding the actions of the UK. Secondly, since the UK assumes a bridging role between the EU and the USA it found itself trapped by its commitments to both and by the different approaches to China the two actors have. Consequently, the UK was prevented from making any forthright or strong stance on the issue. Pressure from the US did drive the UK to act in Europe indicating that the right level of pressure will force it do so and to do so successfully. Human rights pressure however, did not serve any instrumental ends for the UK and so it sought no concessions from China on this front. The EU is now seeking conditionality, on human rights grounds, but this is only after the commotion surrounding the passing of the antisecession law and the UK was not instrumental in bringing this point to bear. This pertinently shows how human rights discourse can become a VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 57 useful resource at the disposal of the West in dealing with rising Asian powers, which can come into play at specific conjunctures where it is diplomatically and discursively useful to do so. However, it rarely seems to ascend beyond this fundamental instrumentality. This is not to say human rights are always and everywhere irrelevant. This arms embargo is hard to envisage in the first instance without the human rights norms of global civil society, but the vociferousness and volubility of civil society on these issues, in this case, is transient and the geopolitical and economic interests of the states involved, much less so. Overall, it seems that despite the Government’s explicit human rights commitments and the explicit human rights element in this policy debate, the UK failed to act or assert itself on this basis. The UK is content to keep human rights isolated into particular arenas, like its bilateral human rights dialogues with China and refuses to let them significantly shape wider policy debates, preferring to stick to narrower (though not necessarily unethical) concerns relating to its interests in geopolitical and economic stability. In specific relation to China, this seems to suggest that the UK holds its commercial and political ties with China above its wish to see the human rights situation improved. The lifting of the EU arms embargo to China was a perfect opportunity to make a stance on the internationalist principles of human rights. However, both the UK and the EU succeeded only in showing how little importance they accord human rights over and above its instrumental uses. In relation to China, this bolsters the Chinese opinion that they need do little on human rights and that their economy and rising profile will win them friends in high places, regardless of the abuses they perpetuate. REFERENCES Abrahmsen, R. and P. Williams. “Ethics and Foreign Policy: The Antinomies of New Labour’s ‘Third Way’ in Sub-Saharan Africa” Political Studies 49 (2001): 249-264. Amnesty International. Undermining Global Security:The EU’s Arms Exports 2004. London: Amnesty International, 2004. ———. EU Press Office Release, 14 th April. Brussels: Amnesty International, 2004. ———. Amnesty International Report 2005: The State of the World’s Human Rights. London: Amnesty International, 2005. ———. People’s Republic of China Briefing on EU Concerns Regarding Human Rights in China. London: Amnesty International, September 2, 2005. Ancram, M. Early Day Motion 1004: Arms Embargo on China (no.2). London: TSO, 2005. 58 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W Barysch, K., Grant, C. and M. Leonard. “Embracing the Dragon: The EU’s partnership with China” London: Centre for European Reform, 2005. BBC News 2005: “EU may delay China arms move, 22 nd March” http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/asia-pacific/4371361.stm. Beitz, C. Political Theory and International Relations. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press, 1979. Breslin, S. “Beyond Diplomacy: UK Relations with China since 1997” British Journal of Politics and International Relations 6, no. 3 (2004): 409-425 Brown, C. International Relations Theory: New Normative Approaches. Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1992. ———. “Ethics, Interests and Foreign Policy” In Ethics and Foreign Policy, Edited by M. Light & K. Smith, 15-32. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001. Bureau of Democracy, Human Rights and Labor. Report on Human Rights Practices. Washington: US Department of State, 2005. Carr, E. H. The Twenty Years Crisis 1919-1939: An Introduction to the Study of International Relations. London: Macmillan, 1964. Chandler, D. “Rhetoric Without Responsibility: The Attraction of ‘Ethical’ Foreign Policy” British Journal of Politics and International Relations 5, no. 3 (2003): 295-316. Cohen, H. Early Day Motion 986: EU Arms Embargo on China. London: TSO, 2004. Cook, R. “Human Rights: Making the Difference” Speech given by Robin Cook to Amnesty International Human Rights Festival, October 16, 1998. ———. “Putting Principle into Practice: The Role of Human Rights in Foreign Policy” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 15, no. 1 (2002): 45-51. Defence, Foreign Affairs, International Development and Trade Industry Committees - Quadripartite Committee (UK). ‘Strategic Export Controls: HMG’s Annual Report for 2003, Licensing and Parliamentary Scrutiny.” London: HMSO, 2005. ———. “Oral evidence given by Jack Straw, Q114.” London: HMSO, January 12, 2005. Department of European Affairs (UK). “China’s EU Policy Paper,” http://www.fmprc.gov.cn/eng/wjb/zzjg/xos/dqzzywt/t27708.htm. Doughty, S. Early Day Motion 630: Arms Embargo on China. London: TSO, 2005. Dunne, T and N. Wheeler. “Good International Citizenship: A Third Way for British Foreign Policy” International Affairs 72, no. 1 (1998): 847-870. ———. “Blair’s Britain: A Force for Good in the World?” VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 59 In Ethics and Foreign Policy edited by M. Light & K. Smith, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001. ———. Moral Brittania? Evaluating the Ethical Dimension in Labour’s Foreign Policy. London: The Foreign Policy Centre, 2004. European Council. “Brussels European Council Presidency Conclusions 16/17 December,” http://ue.eu.int/ueDocs/cms_Data/docs/pressData/en/ec/83 201.pdf. European Parliament. “European Parliaments Fact sheet 6.3.10: China,” http://www.europarl.eu.int/facts/6_3_10_en.htm. Finnemore, M. National Interests in International Society. New York: Cornell University Press, 1996. Foreign Affairs Committee. Tenth Report: People’s Republic of China. London: HMSO, 2000. Foreign Affairs Committee. Human Rights Report 2005. London: HMSO, 2005. Foreign and Commonwealth Office. Human Rights Report 2005. London: HMSO, 2005. Foreign and Commonwealth Office Website. www.fco.gov.uk. ———. “UK Priorities.” FCO, http://www.fco.gov.uk/servlet/Front?pagename=OpenMarket/Xcelerat e/ShowPage&c=Page&cid=1007029393465. ———. “Speech of FCO minister, Ian Pearson.” FCO. July 21, 2005, http://www.fco.gov.uk. ———. “UK Priorities.” FCO. http://www.fco.gov.uk/servlet/Front?pagename=OpenMarket/Xcelera e/ShowPage&c=Page&cid=1068716937231#economic. ———. “FCO Strategy.” FCO. http://www.fco.gov.uk/servlet/Front?pagename=OpenMarket/Xcelera e/ShowPage&c=Page&cid=1067967903739. Frost, M. Ethics in International Relations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996. ———. Putting the World to Rights: Britain's Ethical Foreign Policy. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 12 (1999). Goldstein, A. “Great Expectations: Interpreting China’s Arrival.” International Security 22, no. 3 (1997): 36-73. Government of the People’s Republic of China, “ The (2005) The Anti Secession Law adopted at the Third Session of the Tenth National People’s Congress,” March 14, 2005. Hansard Reporting. ”Bill Rammell MP, Column 1549W pt24,” London: TSO, November 16, 2004, www.parliament.uk. ———. ”Bill Rammell MP, Column 324 WH,” London: TSO, 25 th March, 2004, www.parliament.uk. ———. “Bill Rammell MP, Column 1651W pt26,” London: TSO, 12 February, 2004, www.parliament.uk. 60 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W ———. “Dr Liam Fox MP, Column 164 pt4,” London: TSO, May 18, 2005, www.parliament.uk. ———. “Bill Rammell MP, Column 337W pt 24,” London: TSO, March 16, 2005, www.parliament.uk. ———. “Bill Rammell MP, Column 971W pt16,” London: TSO, February 28, 2005, www.parliament.uk. ———. “ Tom Harris MP, Column 156-157,” London: TSO, January 25, 2005, www.parliament.uk. Hill, C. Foreign Policy In The Blair Effect: The Blair Government 19972001, Edited by A. Seldon, 331-353. London: Little, Brown and Company, 2001. Hoffman, M. “Normative International Theory: Approaches and Issues in Groom”, In Contemporary International Relations: A Guide to Theory Edited by A. R J. and M. Light. London: Pinter Publishers, 1994. Human Rights Watch. World Report 2005. New York: Human Rights Watch, 2005. ———. “Open Letter to Tony Blair, Prime Minister: Recommendations for the upcoming E.U.-China Summit,” www.hrw.org.uk, August 30, 2005. Kim, S. “China as a Great” Current History September (1997): 246-251. ———. “China and the United Nations in Economy” In China Joins the World: Progress and Prospects edited by E & M. Oksenberg, 43-89. New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1999. Kingham, T. “Wanted: Ethics in Foreign Policy” Socialist Campaign Group News 164 (2001). Kissinger, H. American Foreign Policy 2. New York: W. W. Norton, 1997. Light, M. & K. Smith, (eds.) Ethics and Foreign Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001. Little, R. and M. Wickham-Jones, M,.(eds.) New Labour’s Foreign Policy: A New Moral Crusade? Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2000. Mearsheimer, J. The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: W. W. Norton, 2001. Nathan, A. “China and the International Human Rights Regimes in Economy” in China Joins the World: Progress and Prospects edited by E. and M. Oksenberg, 136-160. New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1999. Oxfam. Lock, Stock and Barrel. Oxford: Oxfam, 2004. Pei, M. From Reform to Revolution. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1994. Pope, G. Early Day Motion 891: Arms Embargo in China No. 2. London: TSO, 2005. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 61 Rachman, G. Containing China in Washington Quarterly 19, no. 1 (1996): 129-140. Ross, R.S. “Engagement in US China Policy in Johnston” In Engaging China: The management of an emerging power edited by A.I. Johnston and R.S. Ross. London: Routledge, 1999. Saferworld. Taking Control. London: Saferworld, 2004. Schweller, R. “Managing the Rise of Great Powers: History and Theory” In Engaging China: The management of an emerging power edited by A.I. Johnston and R.S Ross. London: Routledge, 1999. Segal, G. “East Asia and the constrainment of China” International Security 20, no. 4 (1996): 107-135. Shambaugh, D. (ed.) Greater China: The Next Superpower? Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995. ———. “Containment or Engagement of China? Calculating Beijing’s Responses International Security 21, no. 2 (1996): 180-209. Shimm, J. Weaving the Net: Conditional Engagement with China. New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1996. Sutter, R. Why Does China Matter? Washington Quarterly 27, no. 1 (2004): 75-89. The Guardian. “Labour Drops ‘Ethical Tag’”, September 4, 2000. ———. “Europe Risks Sanctions Over China Arms Sales”, March 3, 2005. ———. “ The Lure of Beijing”, May 25, 2005. ———. “ Tiananmen Review Rejected,” June 7, 2005. The International Herald Tribune. Don’t Lift the Arms Embargo on China”, February 23, 2005. ———. “EU To Put Brakes on Lifting the EU Arms Embargo to China”, April 13, 2005. The New Statesman. “ The New Statesman Interview”, April 3, 2000. The Times. “British Arms Firm Will Spurn China If Embargo Ends”, February 22, 2005. Tkacik, J. “ The East Asia Security Act: A Step Towards Consensus Against Arms Sales To China” The Heritage Foundation, 2005. US Department of State. “Introduction,” US Dept. of State, http://www.state.gov/g/drl/rls/hrrpt/2004/41586.htm. Waldron, A. “Deterring China” Co mmentary 100, no. 4 (1995). Waltz, K. Theory of International Politics. Boston: McGraw Hill, 1979. Wang, F. and Y. Deng. In the Eyes of the Dragon: China Views the World. Lanham, MD: Brown & Littlefield, 1999. Williams, P. “ The Rise and Fall of the ‘Ethical Dimension’: Presentation and Practice in New Labour’s Foreign Policy” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 15, no. 1 (2002). 62 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W APPENDIX 1 Copy of the original declaration of the EU arms embargo to China Presidency Conclusions European Council Madrid, 26 and 27 June 1989 Declaration on China The European Council, recalling the Declaration of the Twelve of June 6, strongly condemns the brutal repression taking place in China. It expresses its dismay at the pursuit of executions in spite of all the appeals of the international community. It solemnly requests the Chinese authorities to stop the executions and to put an end to the repressive actions against those who legitimately claim their democratic rights. The European Council requests the Chinese authorities to respect human rights and to take into account the hopes for freedom and democracy deeply felt by the population. It underlines that this is an essential element for the pursuit of the policy of reforms and openness that has been supported by the European Community and its Member States. The Twelve are aware that the recent events have caused great anxiety in Hong Kong. In the present circumstances, the European Council thinks it necessary to adopt the following measures: • raising of the issue of human rights in China in the appropriate international for a; asking for admittance of independent observers to attend the trials and to visit prisons, • interruption by the Member States of the Community of military cooperation and an embargo on trade in arms with China, • suspension of bilateral ministerial and high level contacts, • postponement by the Community and its Member States of new cooperation projects, VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 63 • reduction of programmes of cultural, scientific and technical cooperation to only those activities that might maintain a meaning in the present circumstances, • prolongation by the Member States of visas to the Chinese students who wish it. Taking into account the climate of uncertainty created in the economic field by the present policy of the Chinese authorities, the European Council advocates the postponement of the examination of new requests for credit insurance and the postponement of the examination of new credits of the World Bank. THE DOMESTIC POLITICS OF THAILAND’S BILATERAL FREE TRADE AGREEMENT POLICY Pajnapa Pea msilpakulchorn ‡ A BSTRACT This paper describes and explains do mestic socio-economic actors’ responses to the Thai government’s liberalisation agenda and bilateral Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) policy. Using the theoretical framework of domestic politics and internationalisation, the theoretical supposition is that a country’s exposure to the international market will change domestic actors’ preferences and will prompt them to respond in such a way that their preferences can be fulfilled. However, this process of adjusting to new developments is subject to institutional factors, which will mediate between actors’ preferences and their ability to organise or form coalitions to further their agenda. This in turn will determine the pattern of do mestic political coalitions or align ments that will emerge in response to the challenge of liberalisation. Findings from Thai experiences both validate and expose limitations to theories of do mestic trade politics as well as suggesting new forces and other factors that have to be accounted for, so that domestic politics of trade in the age of globalisation can be better understood. It concludes that do mestic trade policy is intricately linked with the politics of globalisation. Far-reaching impacts of trade liberalisation in the current international context have resulted in a political cleavage between supporters of free trade policy, arguing in terms of econo mic interests and those opposing the policies, who have based their preferences on the social impacts of trade policy. This political ‡ M.Sc. (International Public Policy), School of Public Policy, University College London. Contact with questions/comments: pajnapap@yahoo.com. INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC POLICY REVIEW , vol. 2, no. 1 (May 2006): 74-120. [ ISSN 1748-5207] © 2006 by The School of Public Policy, University College London, London, United Kingdom. All rights reserved. 64 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 65 divide is fundamental and structural both in terms of the international setting as well as the structure of national politics and the economy. 1. INTRODUCTION One of the most significant developments in the international trade landscape in Asia Pacific since 1998, is the proliferation of bilateral preferential trading agreements, or Free Trade Agreements (FTAs). 1 Thailand is one of the countries that has been actively pursuing trade liberalisation through these bilateral trade agreements. FTA policy in Thailand is gaining attention for its pace, numbers, content and the implications for the country’s international strategy, as well as its impact on the domestic sphere. One of the central concerns in studies of international political economy is the interaction between international and domestic forces. On the issue of trade, what goes on in the domestic sphere is intricately linked with the feasibility of liberalisation in the international trading regime.2 From the opposite direction, a country’s response to international developments is of crucial importance on the domestic political stage. In Thailand, the interface between international and domestic forces comes into full play and turns the FTA policy into a highly controversial issue garnering widespread interest and provoking intense political debate. The politicised nature of trade policy is not surprising due to its redistributive nature. Although economic theory promises welfare gain for the whole country, gains to some sectors always come at the expense of others and losers are rarely compensated.3 Without adequate and fair measures to assist losers, free trade effort by a government can result in mass protests from disadvantaged groups lacking resources to relocate to new industries or change occupations. Moreover, as trade liberalisation today is part of broader and deeper globalisation and anti-globalisation 1 Christopher M. Dent, “The New Economic Bilateralism and Southeast Asia: Region-Convergent or Region-Divergent?” Institute of Political and Economic Governance (IPEG) Papers in Global Political Economy, No. 7 (April 2004); John Ravenhill, “The New Bilateralism in the Asia Pacific, ”Third W orld Quarterly vol. 24, no. 2 (2003): 299-317 and P.J. Lloyd, “New Regionalism and New Bilateralism in the Asia-Pacific,” Visiting Researchers Series No. 3, Institute of Southeast Asian Studies (2002). 2 Dani Rodrik, “Feasible Globalizations,” John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University (2002) via http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~drodrik/Feasglob.pdf. 3 In economic theory, free trade is expected to create positive net welfare gains in the country by allowing market forces to encourage the shift of scarce resources from unproductive activities towards more productive ones. Gains will accrue both to consumers and those in the already productive sectors. Losers are producers in unproductive sectors that have been previously shielded from market forces. 66 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W processes, political complications of any government’s free trade policy are guaranteed. In the international arena, new trends and developments such as the entrance of new actors, like NGOs in WTO negotiations, provide a complex setting for domestic events. In addition, the aggressive agenda of ‘deep’ integration of the current global trading policy 4 points to a need in understanding the new dynamics of trade politics, which extend into nontraditional space. Participation from the civil society sector generates debate about the prospect of global governance and the emergence of a global civil society and also challenges the political viability of economic integration policy within a country. Concerns for negative consequences of deeper economic liberalisation and unfair global economic governance will have political repercussions not only on the global scene but also on the domestic front. The enthusiasms and intensities of the politics surrounding FTA policy provide an interesting framework to question the dynamic and conflicting forces in Thailand’s current international trade policy. Moreover, in a democratic society, how a government responds to international imperatives through appropriately engineered foreign economic policy, which can satisfy the majority of its constituency, can have a definitive effect on government viability. Discerning the social, political and economic forces behind FTAs could give insights into how domestic societal actors interact with international forces and how policy makers can pursue FTA with the domestic political support necessary for such an international undertaking to be successful. 2. B ACKGROUND In order to understand the political forces behind Thai government’s FTA policy, this paper aims to: 1) examine and describe the domestic politics of free trade agreement policy in Thailand; and 2) explain why such a pattern of domestic politics emerges. Domestic politics of trade have many facets and areas of focus. Oatley 5 distinguishes two approaches to domestic politics of trade: the ‘state-centred approach’ and ‘society-centred approach’. The focus of this paper is on the society-centered approach, which looks at the preferences and political responses of societal actors or interest groups. Therefore, the questions this paper addresses are: how do domestic interest groups respond to the challenge of trade liberalisation through the government’s FTA policy and what is the pattern of interest group 4 Rodrik, “Feasible Globalization”, 2. Thomas Oatley, International Political Economy: Interests and Institutions in the Global Economy (New York: Pearson-Longman, 2004). 5 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 67 constellation? How do supporting or opposing coalitions emerge and in what patterns? And why such patterns of political cleavage emerge in response to the liberalisation challenge. The analysis will be explanatory but will also contain descriptive elements. It will rely on both primary and secondary data. The primary data include governmental documents, policy papers or position papers from private sector organisations, both economic and non-governmental organisations (NGOs), newspaper reports etc. The secondary data will be drawn from journal articles, academic papers, magazine articles, newspaper articles etc. The scope of this study is not a single FTA but overall FTA policy. However, it will mainly focus on and draw from the two most important FTAs, which are the Thailand-US FTA and the Thailand-Japan FTA. The paper is organised as follows: the next section (three) discusses the existing literature on domestic politics and its limitations in remaining relevant to a new phenomena seen in trade politics. Also in this section, the theoretical framework that will be used to analyse empirical evidence will be set out. Section four will provide a basic background on Thailand’s political economy and Thailand’s FTA policy. Section five will present empirical evidence of the politics surrounding Thai FTA policy. Section six will analyse how theories can be used to explain the empirical evidence. The last section (seven) will then summarise the findings and arguments as well as drawing some implications for further research and for policymakers. 3. EXISTING LITERATURE Literature on the domestic politics of international trade policy attempts to identify how domestic interests and institutions shape the domestic politics of a nation’s international trade policy. The literature can be categorised into five categories and will be discussed accordingly. Economic Approaches to Trade Policy Preferences Early literature, based on economic models, discusses how exposure to trade shapes the interests and trade policy preferences of economic actors through changes in incomes. The simple economic welfare analysis proposes that trade involves transfer of income from previously protected producers to consumers and it should give rise to a political contest between producers and consumers. For a more sophisticated analysis, two economic models are used to show the distributional consequences of trade and how different societal groups derive trade policy preferences. 68 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W The first model is the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem (factor income model), based on the Heckscher-Ohlin trade model,6 which concludes that returns to the owners of abundant resources will rise absolutely and disproportionately from trade. The logic is that their factors will be used intensively in the production of goods whose prices will rise from increasing exports. The returns to owners of scarce resources will fall absolutely and proportionately, since their factors will be used intensively in the production of goods whose prices will fall from increasing imports. Hence, a political cleavage will form between owners of abundant vs. scare factors, or class conflict will foment between labour and capital regardless of industry. 7 The second model is the Ricardo-Viner model (or Specific Factor Model), which predicts sectoral conflict. Because factors cannot be smoothly reallocated in response to trade (factor immobility assumption), 8 return to all factors in an industry will be affected by openness in the same way.9 Therefore, the political cleavage will be aligned along the boundary between the export-oriented or competitive sector (free traders) and import-oriented or uncompetitive sectors (protectionists). 6 The Heckscher-Ohlin model begins with the assumption that factor endowment or factor proportion will determine a country’s pattern of comparative advantage. A country will export products that employ its abundant resource relatively intensively in production while importing products that employ its scare resources relatively intensively. 7 Robert Gilpin, Global Political Economy: Understanding International Economic Order (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001), 206-207; Jeffrey A. Frieden, and Ronald Rogowski, “The Impact of International Economy on National Policies: An Analytical Overview” in Internationalization and Domestic Politics, ed. Robert O. Keohane, and Helen V. Milner, 37 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Oatley, 89; Ronald Rogowski, Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989), 7. 8 This assumption of factor immobility is set out to contest the assumption of perfect factor mobility in the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. The Ricardo-Viner model argues that, in reality, factors are not mobile and once they are employed in a certain industry, they are specific to that industry so that when an industry is in decline, they cannot, in the short run, move to a more profitable industry. 9 Oatley, 91-92; Frieden and Rogowski, 38; James E. Alt and Michael Gilligan, ‘The Political Economy of Trading States: Factor Specificity, Collective Action Problems, and Domestic Political Institutions’ in International Political Economy: Perspective on Global Power and Wealth (4 th ed), ed. Jeffry A. Frieden, and David A. Lake, 327 (Boston: Routledge, 2000). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 69 Table 1. Two Models of Interest Group Competition over Trade Policy The Factor Model (Heckscher-Ohlin) The Principal Actors How Mobile are Factors of Production? Winners and Losers from Trade Liberalisation Types of Political Cleavages Factors of Production or Classes Perfectly Mobile Across Sectors of the Economy Winners: Abundant Factor - Capital in advanced economies - Labour in developing economies Losers: Scarce Factor - Labour in advanced economies - Capital in developing economies Class Cleavages Advanced Economies: Protectionist Labour vs. Liberalising Capital Developing Economies: Protectionist Capital vs. Liberalising Labour Source: Adapted from Oatley, 93. The Specific Factors Model (Ricardo-Viner’model) Industries or Sectors Immobile Across Sectors of the Economy Winner: Labour and Capital Employed in Exportoriented Industries Loser: Labour and Capital Employed in Importcompeting Sectors Sectoral Cleavages Protectionist ImportCompeting Industries vs. Liberalising Export-Oriented Industries Complex Preference Formation and Roles of Institutions Economic approaches provide an insightful account of political cleavages by looking at economic benefits as a basis for predicting different economic groups’ preferences for trade. However, it cannot 70 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W account for more complex patterns of interest configuration or preference formation. Individuals can belong to several economic and social groups at the same time and do not form their preferences so straightforwardly. For example, Oatley 10 discusses how the secondary impact from trade on wider social and economic groups can influence trade policy preference, 11 and Jayasuriya12 notes how side payments can offset losers’ negative preferences.13 Moreover, it has been suggested that focusing on preferences alone is not sufficient. The way preferences are aggregated also matters in deciding which preferences can be materialised and how well they will be represented. The supply side of coalition formation will determine how preferences in trade policy will be transmitted through political systems and institutional settings. Two main factors in this transmission process are, firstly, the problem of collective action and, secondly, the role of political institutions.14 The collective action problem refers to “the difficulty of mobilising or organising resources in order to secure a favourable political decision”. 15 If a collective action problem exists, coalitions based on preferences alone may not be formed. The well-known example of the collective action problem is how a small number of producers can have strong political weight to protect their narrow but intense interests compared to a large number of consumers who stand to gain from trade, but cannot organise and mobilise support for free trade. Goldstein and Martin 16 observe that the concentrated benefits of trade barriers and their diffuse costs contribute to the problem of mobilising pro-free-trade coalitions. Alt and Gilligan 17 conclude that collective action problem makes it more likely for sectoral conflict (the Ricardo-Viner model) to form rather than the class conflict predicted by Stolper-Samuelson model.18 10 Oatley, 127-128 Ibid. 12 Kanishka Jayasuriya, ‘Embedded Mercantilism and Open Regionalism: the Crisis of Regional Political Project’.Third World Quarterly vol. 24, no. 2 (2003): 346 13 Jayasuriya (2003), 346 argues that because interests from liberalization will be accrued to the tradable sector of the economy, the tradable sector can offset political opposition from losers in non-tradable sectors by giving them side payments and this pattern of compensation was evident in the Southeast Asian politics of liberalization. 14 Oatley, 94-99; Frieden and Rogowski; Alt and Gilligan, 27. 15 Alt and Gilligan, 336. 16 Judith Goldstein and Lisa L. Martin, ‘Legalization, Trade Liberalization, and Domestic Politics: A Cautionary Note’, International Organization vol. 54, no. 3 (2000): 609. 17 Alt and Gilligan. 18 This is because factor mobility has direct effects on the possibility of collective action. Mobility disperses the benefits of trade policy across owners of a particular factor. This leads to the problem of non-excludability and free-riding because the benefits of 11 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 71 Institutional factors also matter in trade politics because they allow actors to resist or promote change by facilitating the organisation of groups to advance their policy preferences. Institutions are adopted as an intervening variable in the study of internationalisation and domestic politics in the volume edited by Keohane and Milner. 19 Globalisation: New Actors and New Issues in Trade Politics In the globalisation context, the landscape of trade politics has transformed, thus rendering analyses focusing on economic issues/actors alone as being too limited. Hocking20 demonstrates the changing nature of trade politics due to the emergence of new issues (e.g. the environment, labour, intellectual property, national sovereignty etc.) and new actors, specifically NGOs, whose concerns “now firmly impinge on the trade politics agenda”. 21 This transformation of trade politics where actors are driven not by economic calculation but by social and political values has not yet received much attention in the study of the domestic politics of trade, but it is emerging elsewhere. Solingen 22 uses a coalitional perspective to explain international behaviour at the regional level of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and points out that actors forming the coalitions can come from a diverse range of economic and social groups. This is because “internationalisation (or economic liberalisation) does not merely pose threats to material interests, but also to cultures, identities and values”.23 The growing importance of NGOs in trade politics is also gaining more attention. The debate on the legitimacy of the WTO and the pattern of participation by NGOs in the WTO negotiating process also exemplifies this change at the global level. 24 lobbying can easily be enjoyed by non-participants. But if a factor is immobile, the benefits of lobbying will accrue only to specific factors employed in that particular industry. See Alt and Gilligan, 336-337. 19 Robert O Keohane,. and Helen V. Milner, ‘Internationalization and Domestic Politics: An Introduction’ in Internationalization and Domestic Politics, ed. Robert O. Keohane, and Helen V. Milner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996). 20 Brian Hocking, ‘Trade Politics: Environments, Agendas and Processes’ in, Trade Politics: International, Domestic and Regional Perspectives, ed. Brian Hocking and Steven McGuire, (London: Routledge, 1999). 21 Hocking, 2. 22 Etel Solingen, ‘ASEAN, Quo Vadis? Domestic Coalitions and Regional Cooperation’ Contemporary Southeast Asia vol. 21, no. 1 (1999): pp30-53. 23 Ibid, 32. 24 see for example: Daniel C Esty, ‘The World Trade Organization’s Legitimacy Crisis’ World Trade Review vol. 1, no. 1 (2002): 7-22; David Henderson, ‘WTO 2002: Imaginary Crisis, Real Problems’ World Trade Review vol. 1, no. 3 (2002): pp277-296; Andrew H. Charlton and Joseph Stiglitz, ‘Common Values for the Development Round’ 72 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W In parallel with new actors, new issues25 in the international trade agenda have also contributed to the emergence of new forces in trade politics.26 The main characteristic of these new issues is that they will reach more deeply into national institutional arrangements and communities than older border measures like tariffs implying large political repercussions.27 As trade politics are rooted in the growing integration of the global economy, 28 it is necessary to consider the sources of the preferences of economic and social actors, not just from changing relative prices due to exposure to trade, but also from the content and rules of the international economic order that will affect national regulatory regimes, national economic and social practices, as well as cultures and values. Historical and Regional/Country-Specific Perspectives The treatment of preferences and institutions can be analytically rigorous as a theoretical framework, but it should be complemented by the political economy literature, which looks at how particular patterns of economic interests and institutions affect the politics of trade policy in specific national settings. In relation to the case of Thailand, literature on the domestic politics of economic liberalisation in Southeast Asia paint a distinctive picture of the politics of liberalisation in the region because of its unique combination of economic interests, the political influence of interest groups, and political systems. 29 Traditionally, studies usually assume a unitary character of Southeast Asian states in carrying out (2004). Via http://www1.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/jstiglitz/download/website/Common_Values_for_ the_Development_Round.htm; Bernard Hoekman and Michel Kostecki, The Political Economy of the World Trading System: WTO and Beyond (2 nd ed.) (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 69-72. 25 The new trade agenda includes the three new issues included in the Uruguay Round which are: intellectual Property Rights (the Agreement on Trade-related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights -TRIPS); investment (the agreement on Trade-related Investment Measures – TRIMS); and services (the General Agreement on Trade in Services - GATS) as well as emerging issues such as environmental and labour standards, human rights, competition policy etc. 26 Hocking, 8; Gilpin, 2255-231; Dani Rodrik, “Has Globalization Gone Too Far?” (Washington D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1997), 5. 27 Hocking, 8; Rodrik, “Feasible Globalization?” and Rodrik, “ Has Globalization Gone Too Far?” 28 Rodrik, “Feasible Globalization?”; Hocking. 29 See for example Jayasuriya; Alasdair Bowie and Danny Unger, The Politics of Open Economies: Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines and Thailand (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 73 government-led trade policies30 and are oriented toward the state-centred approach to trade policy rather than the society-centred approach which assumes high level of economic pluralism. However, recent studies suggest that there is a significant political divide in liberalisation policy and the competing forces of anti-liberalisation and pro-liberalisation are likely to have a significant impact on theses countries’ liberalisation agendas in the future. 31 Domestic Politics of Bilateral Trade Liberalisation Literature on the domestic politics of trade discussed above is usually discussed generally in terms of ‘free trade’ versus ‘protection’. However, on many occasions, trade policy is specific and might vary in terms of the content, pattern and level of economic liberalisation that could have a distinctive impact on domestic interests and subsequent political alignment. Studies identify different patterns of political responses specific to bilateral free trade agreements. Ravenhill32 argues that by allowing for liberalisation to be completed separately, sector by sector, a bilateral free trade agreement is expected to gain business support more easily because it inflicts minimal pain on uncompetitive sectors while allowing those industries, which are internationally competitive, to pursue their interests with negotiating partners. Baldwin 33 believes that preferential trading arrangements will gain domestic support from exporters trying to alleviate the discriminatory effects of such policies in foreign markets. Grossman and Helpman 34 identify the political conditions necessary for FTAs to be politically viable. These conditions are: when a negotiated deal can generate substantial welfare gains for the average voter and adversely affected groups fail to mobilise; or when agreement can create gains for exporters in excess of the losses to be suffered by import-competing groups plus the welfare harm to the average voter. In addition, if some industries can be excluded from an FTA, the prospects of an agreement will improve. By looking at the case of Thailand, where the challenges are evident, this paper aims to contribute to an understanding of the new challenges in the politics of economic liberalisation present in the climate of globalisation. It will do this by critically examining the utility of the existing approaches, as well as exploring and furthering the understanding 30 Ravenhill, 303. Ibid. 303. 32 Ibid. 303, 307. 33 Baldwin in Ravenhill, 313. 34 Gene M. Grossman and Elhanan Helpman, “The Politics of Free Trade Agreements,” The American Economic Review, vol. 85, no. 4 (1995): 667-690. 31 74 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W of domestic politics in areas that are still in their early development. Selecting Thailand as a case study should contribute to a better understanding of the domestic politics of trade in developing countries. This will depart from the detailed discussions in the existing literature, which have focused mainly on developed countries. 4. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK As mentioned above, the theoretical framework used here will be the society-centred approach to trade policy. This approach is based on the assumption that policy formation corresponds to a model of pluralistic government, where social forces exert their influence during the policy process.35 The theoretical foundation of this approach is based on Gourevitch 36 who argues that there are international sources of domestic politics37 and that the effects of the international system on domestic politics can result in a range of outcomes, one of which involves coalition patterns that incorporate social forces and the political relationships among these coalitions. This effect is important because there is conflict among powerful groups themselves. Gourevitch 38 observes that the need to secure support for policy will always affect its final content. There is, thus, a need for coalitional analysis to investigate the content of group interests and the efforts to form alliances among them. 39 To conduct this analysis, the theoretical framework used in this paper is based loosely on the analytical framework of internationalisation and domestic politics advanced by Frieden and Rogowski and Garrett and Lange40 . This begins the analysis of domestic politics of internationalisation by looking at: 1) how internationalisation affects the policy preferences of domestic actors and 2) how preferences are aggregated or filtered through a political system to form political coalitions so that political cleavages can be observed. 35 Peter Gourevitch, “The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic Politics,” International Organization vol. 32, no. 4 (1978): 902. 36 Ibid. 37 Gourevitch attempts to forge a new conceptual linkage between domestic and international politics beyond the traditional focus on either: 1) using the international system to explain domestic politics or 2) using domestic politics to explain the international system. He argues instead that the international system is not only a consequence of domestic politics but also a cause of them. 38 Ibid, 903. 39 Ibid, 907. 40 Frieden and Rogowski; Geoffrey Garrett and Peter Lange, “Internationalization, Institutions, and Political Change” in Internationalization and Domestic Politics, ed. Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 75 Trade Policy Preferences The theoretical framework begins with the linkage between FTA policy, and the potential effects of economic liberalisation, which are the source of actors’ trade policy preferences. In the case of Thailand, as in most developing economies, the economy is characterised by relative abundance of labour and a relative scarcity of capital. According to the Heckscher-Ohlin model/Stolper-Samuelson theorem, 41 free trade policy in Thailand should enable labour to reap most benefits from expanding trade opportunities and they should rally to support FTA policy while business or capitalists will lobby against the policy. Alternatively, according to Ricardo-Viner model,42 FTA policy should lead to politics characterised by export-oriented sectors supporting FTA policy while the voice of opposition will come from import-competing sectors. Institutional Roles Understanding social responses by concentrating on preferences alone rests on the implicit assumption of economic pluralism where constellations of economic preferences will be automatically reflected and represented in the national political arena. 43 Trade policy preferences, like other policy preferences, are not always automatically transformed into political demands44 and not all groups that are potentially affected by trade will lobby the government to advance their preferences. Because “the ability of actors sharing common interests to overcome collective action problem is critical to their effective political capacity, and institutions can play important roles in facilitating collective action”, 45 institutional analysis is used here to examine how institutional settings can mediate between preferences and political activities in response to FTAs. Institutions act as a mediating factor because they can insert a structural effect on the process of coalition formation and the pattern of political cleavages by “rewarding or punishing specific groups, interests, visions and persons”,46 and “affecting the extent to which political actors can impose its views and the possibility of realising certain policies”.47 The incorporation of the role of institutions will extend mostly to ‘socio-economic institutions’ because they are more relevant to the study of the role of interest groups which are the unit of analysis here, while 41 Frieden and Rogowski, 38. Ibid. 43 Garrett and Lange, 49. 44 Oatley, 94. 45 Frieden and Rogowski quoted in Garrett and Lange, 53. 46 Gourevitch, 904. 47 Ibid. 42 76 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W formal political institutions (e.g. the electoral system) will be attended to only when it can contribute answers. While Garrett and Lange48 examine the extent to which institutions mediate the preferences of actors and policy outco mes, due to the scope of this study the theoretical framework adopted here will focus on the role of institutions as structural factors that mediate between preferences of actors and the formation of political coalitions. That is, how institutions can help to explain the pattern of political coalitions surrounding the politics of FTA policy and not the influence groups have on the final negotiation of FTA. 5. THAILAND ’S POLITICAL ECONOMY: A H ISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE Economic Transformation Thailand’s economic development is considered a success story by international standards. The Thai economic structure has been transformed from a traditional agrarian-based economy to an internationally-oriented industrialised economy in the space of fifty years.49 Thailand’s modern political economy and industrialisation went through two broad phases; import substitution industrialisation (ISI) and export-oriented industrialisation (EOI). ISI in Thailand began in the 1950s. Before this, Thailand’s economy and its relationship with the international economy revolved around agricultural commodity exports such as rice. Under an authoritarian political system and with support from the US and the World Bank, 50 the military government attempted to legitimise its rule through economic growth by means of economic development led by the private sector and industrialisation. 51 Following this, the ISI regime, composed of investment incentives to foreign and domestic investors and protective barriers,52 was initiated. During this period, manufacturing’s contribution to GDP rose significantly. 53 Although the ISI regime was successful in setting Thailand on the path of industrialisation, its capacity to drive long-term growth became less 48 Garrett and Lange. Thailand is the world’s 23rd largest exporter and exports and imports account for about half of the country’s GDP. In 2003, Thailand’s exports hit US$80.23 billion (Bt3.33 trillion). 50 Kewin Hewison, “Thailand’s Capitalism Before and After the Economic Crisis” in Politics and Markets in the Wake of the Asia Crisis, ed. Richard Robinson, Mark Beeson, Kanishka Jayasuriya and Hyuk-Rae Kim, 196 (London: Routledge, 2000). 51 Danny Unger, Building Social Capital in Thailand: Fibres, Finance, and Infrastructure (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998), 61. 52 Hewison, “Thailand’s Capitalism Before and After the Economic Crisis”, 197. 53 Ibid. 49 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 77 certain by the 1970s.54 Factors such as a domestic economic slowdown, deteriorating profitability, the exhaustion of domestic demand and fluctuating prices of agricultural commodity exports pushed bankers, businessmen and technocrats from the state’s planning and development agencies to pressure the government to replace ISI with EOI. 55 However, forces resisting liberalisation remained among protected industries and in the Ministry of Finance, which feared a diminished ability to collect state revenue. It was not until the 1980s that a major shift toward EOI was made possible by series of external shocks due to high energy prices and deteriorating prices for commodity exports. The subsequent global recession exposed the country’s accumulated weaknesses further and rendered the economy highly vulnerable to external shocks. Business attempted to restore profitability by expanding export capacities56 and kept pressing the government for more support for exports. 57 In parallel with these developments, the devaluation of the Thai baht in 1984 and appreciation of the Japanese yen in 1985 meant that Thai goods became more competitive in the world market. These events triggered a major reorientation of the Thai economy and by the mid 1980s the government became fully committed to an EOI strategy in the pursuit of economic reform. 58 The shift toward EOI paved way for the future boom years in the period from 1985 until the 1997 crisis.59 Besides economic growth, there are two real implications of the boom years. The first is the structural transformation of the economy, which mainstreamed the manufacturing and service sectors while the agricultural sector became marginalised60 . The second is the deeper integration of the Thai economy in the international economy. Moreover, a structural shift of the economy resulted in a shift in the significance of exports in contributing to economic growth and changing the pattern of export performance. 54 Hewison, “Thailand’s Capitalism Before and After the Economic Crisis”, 197; Pasuk Phongpaichit and Chris Baker, Thailand: Economy and Politics (2n Ed.) (Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press, 2002), 147-156. 55 Phongpaichit and Baker, “Thailand: Economy and Politics,” 147, 154. 56 Unger, 67. 57 Phongpaichit and Baker, “Thailand: Economy and Politics,” 154. 58 Ibid. 59 The rate of real GDP growth in Thailand surged to double-digits in 1988 and this was maintained until 1990. In the period 1987-1995, the Thai economy never experienced real GDP growth of less than eight percent. In 1997, Thailand was the first country affected by the Asian Financial crisis to devalue its currency. The crisis led the country into a distressing economic recession. 60 In 1960, agriculture accounted for around 40 percent of GDP as well as being the major contributor to exports and employment. With rapid industrialisation, manufactured exports grew from 1 percent of total exports in 1960 to 80 percent by the mid 1990s (see Hewison, “Thailand’s Capitalist Development and the State,” 198). 78 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W Thailand’s comparative advantage in early industrialisation lay in agricultural exports and labour-intensive industrial goods such as textiles and garments. 61 As industrial development matures, Thailand has begun to develop competitiveness in medium-high-technology goods such as computer accessories, electronic parts and products, and motor vehicle parts.62 In 2004, the share of manufacturing in export was 85.8 percent while the share of agricultural exports was 10.7 percent. Thailand’s top export products are electrical machinery, motor vehicles, food-processing products and garments and textiles. Foreign direct investment (FDI) was one of the engines of the boom and one of the foundations of the structural transformation of the economy as appreciation of the yen brought in massive flows of Japanese FDI. 63 This was especially directed towards the auto, electronics and electrical industries. FDI continues to be an important source of growth, employment, technological transfer and economic upgrading.64 Japanese investors are the largest investors in the Thai economy followed by the United States with most of the investment concentrated in manufacturing and service sectors. International trade, exports and FDI, therefore, are the pillars that define the country’s international economic strategy. Political and Social Transformation Economic transformation also brought about a remarkable socioeconomic transformation. Thailand’s capitalist transformation gave rise to a domestic capitalist class, which mostly had roots in the banking sector, but continued to expand and diversify into other sectors.65 New waves of the capitalist classes from the media, communications, electronics, manufacturing, retailing, and finance and securities began to emerge and gain more influence in the economy. 66 Although the Thai economy is market-driven and highly internationalised, the distinctive feature of it is still one of strong clientelistic links between business and 61 The Economist, “Country Briefings: Thailand,” www.economist.com (accessed July, 2005). 62 Ibid.; Richard F. Doner and Ansil Ramsay, “The Challenges of Economic Upgrading in Liberalizing Thailand” in States in the Global Economy: Bringing Domestic Institutions Back In, ed. Linda Weiss, 127 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003). By 1995, the export value of medium-high-technology products was 40 percent greater than labour-intensive goods (Chalongphob, 7 in Doner and Ramsay, “The Challenge of Economic Upgrading in Liberalising Thailand,” 127). 63 Pongpaichit and Baker, “Thailand: Economy and Politics,” 159. 64 At the end of 2003, the cumulative level of FDI in Thailand was around $31 billion. 65 Hewison, “Thailand’s Capitalism Before and After the Economic Crisis,” 199. 66 Ibid. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 79 politics.67 Macintyre 68 relates the clienteslistic feature of the Thai political economy (as with other countries in Southeast Asia) to the fact that the business community is made up of people of Chinese descent who, due to indigenous resentment, seek to avoid high profile collective political action and rely instead on a more covert form of political representation provided by clientelism. The replacement of the authoritarian regime by electoral politics also forged new alliances between business and elected politicians.69 Nevertheless, political democratisation has also created political space for a diverse range of social groups to take more active roles in national politics. Organised groups among business people were established to participate more actively in economic policymaking.70 Other social groups mobilising on issues such as community and village livelihoods, rural movement, environmental protection, natural resource management, alternative development, gender etc., have increasingly penetrated and provided counterbalancing forces to mainstream politics. These social movements represented the emergence of civil society, which has become a significant social force in contemporary politics in Thailand.71 6. C HALLENGES OF TRADE/ECONOMIC LIBERALISATION: THAILAND ’S FTA POLICY In order to conceptualise the linkage between FTA policy and the political responses from social groups, this section will discuss some key features of Thailand’s FTA policy and its implications for economic and trade liberalisation. Since 2003, the government of Thailand under the leadership of Prime Minister Thaksin Shinawatra, has adopted bilateral FTAs as one of the centrepieces of Thai international economic policy and significant progress has been made with five agreements signed and five more are under negotiation (see table 2). 67 Andrew MacIntyre, “Business, Government and Development: Northeast and Southeast Asian Comparisons” in Business and Government in Industrializing Asia, ed. Andrew MacIntyre (New South Wales: Allen and Unwin, 1994); Pongpaichit and Baker, “Thailand: Economy and Politics.” 68 Macintyre. 69 Hewison, “Thailand’s Capitalism Before and After the Economic Crisis,” 200. 70 Macintyre. 71 Phongpaichit and Baker, “Thailand: Economy and Politics,” 385-413; Unger. 80 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W Table 2. Thailand’s Free Trade Agreem ents Thailand’s Free Trade Agreements as of June, 2005 Agreements Signed China, India, Bahrain, Australia and New Zealand Agreements Under US, Japan, Peru, BIMSTEC (Bangladesh, India, Negotiations Myanmar, Sri Lanka, Phutan, Nepal and Thailand), and the EFTA (the European Free Trade Association which includes Switzerland, Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein) Source: Thai Ministry of Commerce The Thai government’s FTA policy is often justified by three main reasons: • FTAs can accelerate the process of trade liberalisation, given the slow progress of the WTO. Because FTAs are negotiated between two partners, it can provide flexibility as well as advancing liberalisation in the sector of strong interest for the country. 72 • FTA policy is vital in maintaining the competitiveness of Thai exports in existing markets (US, Japan and ASEAN) and potential markets (China, India and etc.). • FTA policy is instrumental in attracting FDI and placing Thailand as a regional trade and investment hub.73 While the government usually validates FTA policy on these grounds, political motives behind FTAs are commonly recognised, especially in the case of the Thailand-US FTA. This is of strategic significance for both countries given that Thailand is a key military ally with the US74 and the relationship with the US remains strategic in Thailand’s security equation. 75 Traditional features of free trade agreements are the reduction and elimination of tariff and non-tariff barriers between two negotiating 72 Thaksin Shinawatra (in Thai), “Free Trade Agreement: Opportunities for Business,” Keynote Speech by Prime Minister Thaksin Shinawatra, February 19th, 2004 at the Federation of Thai Industries’ Seminar on Free Trade Agreements, UNESCAP (2004); Dent, 5. 73 Shinawatra; Fumio Nagai, “Thailand’s Trade Policy: WTO plus FTA?” IDE APEC Study Centre, Working Paper Series 01/02-No.6, APEC Study Centre, Institute of Developing Economies (2002), 12. 74 Thailand provided support on the US war on terrorism and also sent troops to Iraq. 75 Richard E. Feinberg, “The Political Economy of United States’ Free Trade Agreements,” Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, University of California, Sandiego (2003); USTR (United States Trade Representative), ‘Letter to House of Representatives on Intent to Negotiate FTA with Thailand’, USTR (2004) at www.ustr.gov and USTR (United States Trade Representative), “ Letter to Senate on Intent to Negotiate FTA with Thailand,” USTR (2004) at www.ustr.gov. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 81 partners and the major challenge it will bring to the domestic economy in the freer flow of goods and changes in relative prices between domestic and foreign goods. However, the current wave of ‘new age FTAs’ will take the form of comprehensive agreements 76 expanding the scope of trade agreements beyond trade in goods to include new trade issues such as intellectual property rights, service liberalisation, investment, environment and labour issues etc., and sometimes by committing negotiating partners beyond the existing WTO regime (or being ‘WTOplus’). For comprehensive agreements, the implications of economic liberalisation include possible changes in the domestic regulatory regime. For example, if Thailand agrees to the US demand for more stringent protection of intellectual property, Thailand will have to upgrade its domestic intellectual property laws to the US standard. Overall, it can be said that the challenge generated by FTA policy is the challenge of wholesale economic liberalisation, change in domestic commercial practices and deepening economic integration within the international economy. Although Thailand is pursuing many FTAs simultaneously, the FTAs that would have major impacts on the country and have commanded intense public interests are the Thailand-Japan FTA and the Thailand-US FTA and they will be discussed briefly here. The Thailand-Japan FTA is classified as a partnership agreement with negotiations covering a wide range of issues from trade barrier reduction, investment, and services as well as other areas of economic cooperation including industrial development. 77 The main interest for Thailand is the opening up of Japan’s highly protected agricultural sectors, e.g. rice, chicken, sugar and fisheries,78 while Japan’s main aim is getting market access to the Thai industrial sector, particularly the electrical, auto and steel sectors. Thus, the major domestic impact from the Thailand-Japan FTA is trade liberalisation in Thailand’s industrial sector. The Thailand-US FTA is a comprehensive agreement meaning that the agreement will specify timing and conditionalities, which are binding for each party. 79 The main goals of the agreement identified by the United States Trade Representatives (USTR) include open market access for US 76 J.R. Ponciano Intal, “Bilateral and Multilateral Trade Negotiations and Business,” Paper prepared for ‘Business for Development’ Conference hosted by Department of Trade and International Trade Center, 21-22 October, 2004, Philippine Trade Training Center, Manila (2004). 77 Narongchai Akrasanee, “The FTA Architecture of Thailand,” Presentation at Pacific Economic Cooperation Council (PECC) Trade Forum Meeting 22 nd-25 th May, 2005, Jeju Island, Korea; Narongchai Akrasanee is the Chairman of the government’s FTA Monitoring Committee. 78 Ibid. 79 Ibid. 82 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W agricultural producers, the protection of intellectual property rights and upgrading Thai labour and environmental standards.80 Other issues normally included by the United States in FTAs with other countries, such as government procurement, competition policy, service, investment, and custom procedures are likely to be negotiated as well. The Thailand-US FTA is bound to be legalistic in nature as much of the US agenda, from intellectual property rights to government procurement, would require negotiating partners to make changes to domestic law. Empirical Evidence: the Domestic Politics of Thailand’s FTA Policy Examining the social and political responses to the challenge of economic liberalisation presented by FTA policy in Thailand, there are two main political coalitions that have emerged: an economic coalition and a social/political coalition. Each will be discussed in turn. 7. THE ECONOMIC COALITION The main economic actors in Thailand’s economic policy-making are the three main business associations consisting of the Thai Chamber of Commerce (TCC), the Federation of Thai Industries (FTI) and the Bankers’ Association. However because financial liberalisation is beyond the scope of this study, the opinions of the Banker’s Association, which mostly concern the financial sector, will not be presented here. Since the government established and incorporated these three institutions into a regular government-business consultative system in the 1980s, these associations have remained the voice of the business community in national policymaking whose demands and opinions are heard by the government, and feature prominently in the press.81 Generally, business has shown support for the reasoning behind FTAs in line with the government. This concentrates on the benefits to Thai exports, complementing the slow WTO process and maintaining the competitiveness of Thai products in the world market. In a speech, the Chairman of the FTI clearly stated that “the private sector understands and supports the government’s move (i.e. FTA policy) to maintain Thai competitiveness and ensure advantage over competitors for Thai products 80 USTR, “Letter to the House of Representatives on Intent to Negotiate FTA with Thailand” and USTR, “Letter to Senate on Intent to Negotiate FTA with Thailand.” 81 Anek Laothamatas, “From Clientelism to Partnership: Business-Government Relations in Thailand” in Business and Government in Industrializing Asia, ed. Andrew MacIntyre (New South Wales: Allen and Unwin, 1994); Medhi Krongkaew, “The Economics of Institutional Change: Making Economic Policy in Thailand” in Institutions and Economic Change in Southeast Asia: the Context of Development from the 1960s to the 1990s, ed. Colin Barlow and Edward Elgar (UK: Cheltenham, 1999). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 83 in key markets”.82 Moreover, he also pointed out the merits of comprehensive FTAs, stating that “many FTAs that Thailand is negotiating will be comprehensive and this will be a good starting point to create and deepen mutually beneficial relationships between Thailand and its trading partners”.83 The leading figure in the TCC showed similar support commenting that “Dr. Somkid (Deputy Prime Minister in charge of FTA policy) has assured us about positive results from the FTAs, so we'll go ahead”.84 The economic coalition also includes support from other leading economic and business figures outside formal business representation, emphasising the benefits from the economic side of free trade. One prominent economist in Thailand summed up that: “It’s hard to argue against the economic benefits of FTA. But because of their social and political impacts, FTAs will always be a controversial issue in any country”. 85 Other economists also support the trade liberalisation policy in principle, but still remain skeptical about the benefits from the pact in reality, which depend on the government’s commitment and ability to extract benefits from the negotiations.86 Although businesses tend to be supportive of the government’s overall attempt to liberalise the economy, they also strongly opposed the FTA if it directly threatens their interests. Strong business resistance from import-competing sectors was evident with the Thailand-Japan FTA. Political alignment opposing the deal was found among local steel producers, local auto parts producers and non-Japanese carmakers. Domestic steel producers protested that opening the domestic market to Japanese producers would be unfair considering the fact that the Japanese steel industry had been developed far longer than the Thai industry, with heavy subsidies from the Japanese government 87 and demanded a longer adjustment period than Japan had requested. The TCC and the FTI joined forces to organise a joint press conference to criticise the government for considering ending tariffs on Japanese hot-rolled steel imports and insisted that protection was needed in order to avoid the Thai industry being controlled by Japan and the whole country suffering from an increased trade deficit caused by a flood of Japanese imports. 88 82 Speech delivered by the Chairman of the Federation of Thai Industries at the ‘Free Trade Agreements: Opportunities for Business’ seminar at Bangkok, February, 2004. Author’s translation. 83 Ibid. 84 Ibid. 85 Pichaya Changsorn and Usanee Mongkolporn, “No Running Away from FTAs,” The Nation, April 2, 2004. 86 Jeerawat Na Thalang, “Advice From Economists: Focus FTAs on Major Markets,” The Nation, September 25, 2004. 87 Busrin Treerapongpichit, “Local Manufacturers Cry Foul over Change in Stance on Steel,” Bangkok Post, April 4, 2005. 88 The Nation, “Furore over Steel ‘Cave-in’”, April 5, 2005. 84 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W The prospect of cutting tariffs on completely built-up (CBU) automobiles and car components under the Thailand-Japan FTA also raised strong concerns among domestic car component manufacturers. The Thai Auto Parts Manufacturers Association has petitioned the Prime Minister and related ministers to exclude autos and parts from the FTA framework, fearing that removing import tariffs on CBU cars and parts would result in lower demand for locally made products and customers shifting to consume imported instead of locally assembled cars. This will also reduce incentives for Japanese automakers to expand local production facilities, which would have hurt the overall development of the industry. Domestic auto parts producers also saw their interest in protecting the domestic auto industry aligned with the interests of American and European automakers. This was because opening up the car market to Japan would give significant price competitiveness to imported Japanese cars and, in effect, discriminate against European and American cars. One representative from Europe quickly aligned their interests with the domestic auto parts producers warning that, “Any action that could minimise the significance of the auto-parts production industry, through the import of ready-built cars needs to be very carefully considered. The decision relates to such an important issue that it should not be rushed into”. 89 Besides potential losers in import-competing sectors, dissatisfaction also increased even from potential winners in the export sector when it became likely that the negotiation would not grant benefits to possible Thai products as much as had been hoped for. For instance, business showed great disappointment with the Japanese market access offered to Thai farm products, when the government caved in to Japanese insistence on excluding rice from the talks. 8. THE SOCIAL/POLITICAL COALITION FTAs have become a hotly debated issue in Thailand since 2004 when negative impacts from concluded agreements were deeply felt among farmers. The consequences caused concern when significant progress had been made in FTAs with the United States and Japan. Outside the business circle, the government’s FTA policy has generated strong negative responses from diverse social groups. Opposition to FTA policy comes from NGOs/activists dealing with issues ranging from rural development, AIDS and access to drugs, consumer protection, intellectual property and sustainable farming, as well as from academics, senators, opposition politicians and parts of the private sector. The most formal and 89 Comment made by BMW Group (Thailand). See The Nation, “Thai-Japan FTA Talks: Warning from Carmakers,” April 8, 2005. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 85 systematic coalition to rally against FTA was initially formed by NGOs under the name ‘FTA Watch’ and came to find increasing support from such groups as academia, senators 90 and members of congress. This coalition’s focus has been to pressure the government on issues relating to the Thailand-US FTA in particular as well as issues of legitimacy and accountability in the conduct of the government’s overall FTA policy. The dissenting camp has opposed FTAs on many grounds. Because the concluded FTAs bypassed any process of public scrutiny by parliament or the senate, the first issue of contention has been the lack of good governance and transparency in the government’s conduct of FTA negotiations. Senators and members of parliament in the opposition party accused the government of hiding information from the public and expressed fear that the government might illegally bypass constitutional processes to conclude the FTA. 91 With the government holding a majority in parliament, one critic described the political climate as “parliamentarian dictatorship by capitalists" 92 which facilitates FTAs being negotiated in a way that would bring benefits mainly to associates of the government. 93 Conflicts of interest embedded in FTA policy were brought to the attention of the public with the Thailand-Australia FTA. Some NGOs suspected that this deal benefited the personal business interests of groups related to the government in the telecoms and auto sectors at the expense of local dairy farmers.94 Opposing voices also raised concerns about the potential adverse impact economic liberalisation could have on small farmers and entrepreneurs, which make up a large proportion of the population. 95 Activists working on the small-scale sustainable agriculture movement 90 Senators in five key upper house committees – on foreign affairs, agriculture, finance and banking, economics, commerce and industry, social development, and human security showed opposition to the government’s FTA policy. 91 Achara Asgatagacgat and Chatrudee Theparat, “Free Trade Has Its Many Costs,” Bangkok Post, February 16, 2004. In the article, Kalaya Sophonpanich, a member of the opposition Democrat party referred to articles 3 and 224 of the constitution that any international obligation that might affect Thailand's sovereignty must have the endorsement of the parliament, thus, ‘… the parliament is entitled to a special committee to study the pros and cons before binding ourselves to any country, especially the US’. The chairman of the Senate Foreign Affairs Committee also shared similar concerns (Nophakhun Limsamarnphun, “Bilateral Free Trade is A Game of High Stakes,” The Nation, February 23, 2004). 92 Rungrawee Pinyorat, “Activists Want New Law to Control FTAs Process,” The Nation, March 20, 2004. The phrase was from a law academic. 93 Achara Asgatagacgat and Chatrudee Theparat, Bangkok Post, “ Free Trade Has Its Many Costs,” February 16, 2004. This concern was expressed by a leading academic in Thailand. 94 Bangkok Post, “Explanation of FTA Is Lacking Woefully,” July 6, 2004. 95 FTA Watch (in Thai), Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand (Bangkok :FTA Watch, 2004). 86 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W insisted that small-scale farmers’ earnings and ways of life were likely to be severely affected due to their limited ability to adjust to new kind of crops and without sufficient adjustment assistance programs from the government. 96 Opposition is strongest to the Thailand-US FTA and to intellectual property rights protection. It is expected that the US will demand Thailand tighten beyond the current TRIPS agreement. This is singled out as the issue of deepest threat, and various groups have shared concerns. The Thai Network of People Living with HIV/AIDS feared that yielding to Washington’s request would result in limited access to drugs by AIDS patients. 97 Other consumer organisations also feared that more stringent protection of drug patents would result in higher drug prices. Those working on local biodiversity argued that if Thailand accepted the US demand, it would result in a monopoly on seeds by the US which would hurt Thai farmers, and lead to long-term exploitation of local biodiversity by US MNCs.98 FTA Watch and its allies later formally demanded the withdrawal of intellectual property issues from the Thailand-US FTA. Opposition groups also demonstrated a certain amount of nationalism. For example, concern over the loss of Thai sovereignty occupies quite a significant space in their arguments. In fact, FTA Watch named their campaign against Thailand-US FTA “Sovereignty Not for Sale”99 and declared in their official statement that the Thailand-US FTA would lead to the country being colonised by the US and the Thai state will lose economic and legal sovereignty to the US.100 These groups have resorted to various measures in order to pressure the government into adhering to their demands: from street protests, signature gathering and sending letters to the governments of the negotiating countries warning them of undemocratic processes in FTA negotiations. In June 2005, FTA Watch’s political strategies took a further step by submitting a letter to the UN Human Rights Committee pledging that the Thai government’s FTA policy involved violations of 96 Bangkok Post, “Free Trade or One-way Street,” December 2, 2004. Rungrawee C Pinyorat, “Trade Negotiations: FTA Opponents Plan Rally,” The Nation, June 30, 2004. 98 FTA Watch (in Thai), Thailand-US Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand (Bangkok :FTA Watch, 2004), 53-55; Vasana Chinvarakorn, “Free or Even Fair?” Bangkok Post, July 11, 2005. 99 FTA Watch, “Thailand-US Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand” and FTA Watch, “Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand.” 100 FTA Watch, “Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand,” XII. Author’s translation 97 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 87 human rights, especially the people’s right to health 101 in relation to the intellectual property issue under the Thailand-US FTA. Analysis: Political Cleavages and Coalitions Using the empirical evidence, the politics of FTAs will be explained using the theoretical framework set out above. First, the response of the economic coalition will be explained. Second, the response from social and political coalitions will be discussed. Finally, the overall pattern of political cleavage and coalitions will be discussed and summarised. 9. EXPLAINING THE ECONOMIC C OALITION The Sectoral Model and the Economic Coalition The economic approach is useful in explaining business responses in which the economic effects of trade liberalisation trigger economic actors to reformulate their preferences. Businesses were receptive to the government’s initiative as opening markets for exports directly enhances the potential income of exporters. Moreover, liberalisation through preferential trade agreements such as FTA allows even more explicit gains to the export sector than unilateral or multilateral liberalisation. With bilateral liberalisation, exports benefit indirectly from lower prices of imported raw materials and, hence, lower costs of production. Under the GATT/W TO, the principle of multilateralism means that trade rules will be extended without discrimination to all members of the GAT T/WTO. 102 Therefore, even if exports can enjoy lower barriers in trade regimes around the world, multilateral liberalisation does not give them a competitive edge over competitors in the way that preferential arrangements from FTAs can. Ravenhill103 emphasises the point that, because preferential agreements create exclusivity of market access between member countries, exporters in non-member countries will invest in political activity to push their government to establish preferential agreements with trading partners in order to avoid the discriminatory effect of being excluded in the first place. Therefore, in addition to general preferences toward free trade or protectionism, the nature of how market opening is pursued and through which policy instrument, can intensify the preferences of actors. FTAs can alleviate discriminatory effects in the current trend towards 101 FTA Watch, “Thailand’s Free Trade Agreements and Human Rights Obligations: Letter for Submission to the 84 th Session of the UN Human Rights Committee” (2005) at www.ftawatch.org. 102 Gilpin, 218. 103 Ravenhill, 313. 88 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W competitive regionalism while simultaneously creating a competitive edge for Thai products in important markets. Traditionally, the preferences of protectionists have been more intense because free trade generates diffuse benefits but concentrated costs for protected industries.104 Free trade policy via FTAs, however, has the opposite effect by generating concentrated benefits to exporters while costs to importers are more diffuse given that it can provide for gradual liberalisation and an adjustment period for sensitive products. 105 With concentrated benefits to exporters giving exporters a higher preference and intensity toward free trade, FTAs can easily secure support from exporters for liberalisation. Because the economic impact of FTAs is estimated in terms of competitiveness, interests among business were aligned along the importexport cleavage as predicted by the Ricardo-Viner model. Export interests were identified as the main beneficiaries from the policy by the business associations and they were explicit in expressing their support for the policy. The FTI consistently pointed out that FTAs would lead to the expansion of producers with already high export volume such as the textile and electronics industries.106 The automobile club of the FTI emphasised that the local vehicle industry would gain greatly from the Thailand-Australia FTA and Thailand-US FTAs.107 Politics unfolding around the Thailand-Japan FTA also testified to the pattern of political alignment along the lines of import-export interests. As discussed earlier, opposing interests’ political alignment consisted of domestic steel producers, auto parts manufacturers and non-Japanese car companies, which are import-competing sectors vis-à-vis Japan, while exporters, especially the food industry, supported the Thailand-Japan FTA initially but their support plummeted when the negotiation did not seem to advance their interests. Such a pattern is consistent with both trade data and estimates from a TDRI (Thailand Development Research Institute) study about the potential impact of the Thailand-Japan FTA. 108 The TDRI consistently estimates that industries that will be able to expand exports to Japan are agricultural products and food-processing products 104 Goldstein and Martin, 608. Grossman and Helpman, 669. 106 Speech delivered by the Chairman of the Federation of Thai Industries at the “Free Trade Agreements: Opportunities for Business” seminar at Bangkok, February, 2004. Comment made by the chairman of international economic committee of the Federation of Thai Industries in Benjaprut Akkarasriprapai and Achara Pongvutitham, “FTAs to Boost GDP by 26%, Official Says,” The Nation, 11 October 2004. 107 The Nation, “Push for FTAs with US, Australia and Japan by Year’s End,” 20 February 2004. 108 TDRI (in Thai), “Sub-topic Study Number 2: Preliminary Analysis on the Impact from Thailand-Japan Free Trade Agreement,” Thailand Development Research Institute (2005) at www.ftadigest.com. 105 VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 89 while industries that will be hardest hit from increasing Japanese imports are auto parts, chemical and metal products (see table 3). Table 3. Estimates of the Impact of the Thailand-Japan Free Trade Agree m ent on Change in Productions by Sector Sector Agriculture Food-processing Textiles Leather-related Paper Petroleum Chemical Mining Metal Vehicles and Parts Transportation Equipments Electronics Engine Average Source: adapted from TDRI (2005) Cha ng e in percentag e) 9.02 12.15 -0.12 -0.83 -0.18 0.25 -3.85 -0.90 -3.03 -15.12 1.02 0.15 -0.44 1.16 Production (by Institutional factors add explanations to the pattern of political alignment based on industry. Within the business associations, the organisation of members along industry lines facilitates industry in overcoming collective action problems in their political mobilisation. It also explains the relative silence of import-competing industries vis-à-vis other countries beside Japan. Export sectors are the most prominent and powerful in the economy and within the business associations. Major export industries such as food, textiles and garments, auto, electronic and electrical industries have firm control in business associations and they are active participants in FTA policy forums. Thus, it is possible that the weaker industries which are mostly import-competing industries may oppose the liberalisation policy but their preferences will not be fully transmitted through their representative organisations. Limitations of the Factoral Model Another theoretical puzzle is why business responses correspond more to the sectoral than the factoral model. In a capitalist economy like Thailand, where owners of factors can be divided along class line of 90 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W capitalists and labour,109 why are interests not aligned along the line of class? To answer this, it will be shown that the Heckscher-Ohlin model/Stolper-Samuelson theorem is insufficient in predicting the preferences of economic actors, and institutional factors also prevent the political mobilisation of some groups. The first part of puzzle is preference formation. As set out in section 3.2, according to the model, it is predicted that the owners of capital will oppose while labour will favour free trade policy in Thailand. However, empirical evidence indicates that the opposite is true. Capital owners in business associations showed support for free trade while positive responses from labour representatives were not to be found. Why is this the case? The first critical point of the Heckscher-Ohlin model is that it predicts a country’s comparative advantage on the level of the abundance and scarcity of resources. As a developing country, factor proportionality in Thailand is one of low capital-labour ratio. 110 However, as Thai industrialists have embarked upon industrialisation in the international setting, the rapid transnationalisation of modern sectors and the scale of output tend to favour capital/technology-intensive techniques that discourage the use of labour.111 Consequently, the country’s competitive advantage has diverged away from its factor endowment. As the abundant factor is not sufficiently utilised in domestic production, owners of the abundant factor may not benefit from the prospect of free trade. And since capital-intensive industries are mostly concentrated in the exportoriented sector, it is the case, as observed, that capital owners’ preference is toward free trade in Thailand. In addition, as Bowie and Unger112 state: “to understand the political impact of relative factor scarcities, we need to know something about who controls them.” The capitalist pattern in which dominant capitalists in Thailand have diversified their investments 109 Kewin Hewison, “Emerging Social Forces in Thailand: New Political and Economic Roles” in The New Rich in Asia: Mobile Phones, McDonald’s and MiddleClass Revolution ed. Richard Robinson and David S.G Goodman, 139-142 (London and New York: Routledge, 1996). 110 Juanjai Ajanant, “Trade and Industrialization of Thailand in 2020” in Restructuring Asian Economics for the New Millennium, Research in Asian Studies vol. 9B, ed. J.R. Behrman, M. Dutta, S.L. Husted, P. Sumalee, C. Suthipand and Wiboonchutikula, 748 (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V., 2001). 111 Ajanant, 748; Vali Jamal, “NIKKEI Interviews: Employment in Asia” in Liberalisation and Labour ed. Rajah Rasian and Norbert von Hofmann, 31 (Singapore: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung, 1996). As Ajanant argues, this is partly because the availability of technology that is most suitable to the market size and financial capacity of a firm may not be the one that corresponds with the country’s factor proportion. For example, labourintensive production technologies may not lead to cost optimisation on a long-term basis. Since labour-intensive techniques that can match market demand are not always available, business has to utilise available technologies whether it is capital-intensive or not. 112 Bowie and Unger, 20. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 91 and spread their business interests across various sectors with different relative factor intensities makes it problematic to predict trade policy preferences based on factor endowment. 113 The capacity of groups to overcome collective action problems and institutional factors also explain the limited application of the factoral model regarding the response from labour. Thai labour organisation is relatively weak 114 and worker or class organisations are not institutionalised enough to build political strength. 115 Goldstein and Martin 116 note that the role of information regarding distributional implications from trade agreements is important in providing incentives for groups to mobilise. As FTAs are carried out in the realm of international economic policy where public debate takes place in the narrow circle among the urban class and political and business elites, labour groups lack knowledge about the potential impacts of FTAs. This has hindered them from effectively formulating their preferences toward policy and diminished their ability to mobilise.117 Thai labour experts further point out that lack of leadership and unity among many labour unions as well as clear political targets are factors that explain the absence of labour in the contemporary Thai political scene. 118 Nevertheless, labour mobilisation in response to FTAs may come long after the policy announcement or even its implementation. As the Thai Labour Campaign 119 speculates: “when the worst comes to the worst (the situation of labour), and adverse consequences from FTAs actually happen in the future, many factories may have to close down and workers will be laid off. Only then will it be known whether or not any labour movement will occur. Only in a time of crisis can the real power of labour be seen.” Therefore, institutional weakness may lead to a lag in response by some groups toward trade policy but circumstances may help groups to 113 Ibid., 21, 134. Unger, 59; Bowie and Unger, 20; Phongpaichit and Baker, “Thailand: Economy and Politics,” 187-221; Shigeru Itoga, “Labor Issues and APEC Liberalisation: Case of Thailand and Malaysia,” IDE APEC Study Centre Working Paper Series No.1 Fiscal Year 1996/1997, Institute of Developing Economies, Japan External Trade Organisation (1997) at www.ide.go.jp. 115 Thailand has had one of the lowest rates of formal union membership among democratic countries; See Phongpaichit and Baker, “Thailand: Economy and Politics,” 215, 221. 116 Goldstein and Martin. 117 This point is made by the Thai Labour Campaign; see Bangkokbiz News, “Keep Watch: FTAs Might Give Rise to Thai Labor Mobilisation,” May 2, 2005 (in Thai). 118 Interview with the Director of Thai Labour Campaign (a Thai NGO working on labour rights with association to Chulalongkorn University) and Chairman of the Senate Committee on Labour and Social Welfare in Bangkokbiz News, May 2, 2005. 119 Ibid. 114 92 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W overcome collective action problems and pursue their preferences in a more confrontational manner, such as by massive protests or strikes. Partial Economic Pluralism: the Thai Political Economy Even in the sectoral model, political coalitions and mobilisation among economic interest groups are not very clear and systematic, especially if compared to their Western counterparts,120 nor are there acute political cleavages among businesses themselves. Business could more or less maintain a coherent voice in supporting or criticising the FTA policy. Rogowski 121 notes that one possible reason political cleavage might not arise as the result of greater exposure to trade is when government can reallocate gains from winners to compensate losers so that their income remains unchanged.122 As Rogowski also observes, this is unlikely and rather, “the natural tendency is for gainers to husband their winnings and to stop the ears to the cries of the afflicted.”123 Likewise in the Thai case, there are no governmental trade adjustment assistance programs in place that can change the preferences of the losers. This provides a critical point for both theoretical models. The theory of the domestic politics of trade policy that emerged mostly in Western democratic societies can satisfactorily predict the preference formation of economic actors. However, the institutional factors, especially in a political context that does not fit perfectly with a model of democratic economic pluralism, plays an important mediating role in determining the actual formation of domestic political coalitions and the role of interest groups in the politics of the liberalisation process. In the Thai context, it is not that the preferences of actors, both importers and exporters, have not been affected. Although exporters are more politically visible, business groups often also express concerns about potential losers. The pattern and institutional nature of Thai public policymaking can explain the relatively weak and less visible interest representation of Thai interest groups even when preferences are formed. One important institutional feature is the business-government relationship. Patterns of private sector representation under peak associations (the TCC and the FTI) mean that the private sector usually presents quite a coherent voice in their support or opposition toward policy. Moreover, the cooperative nature of government-business 120 For example, US business formed a formal and systematic coalition in support of the Thailand-US FTA: the US-Thailand Free Trade Agreement Business Coalition. 121 Ronald Rogowski, “Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments” in International Political Economy: Perspective on Global Power and Wealth (4 th ed.), ed. Jeffry A. Frieden and David A. Lake (Boston: Routledge, 2000). 122 Ibid., 325. 123 Ibid.,325. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 93 relationships explains overall business support for FTA policy even when losers can be identified. Laothamatas124 summarises that “business associations have generally employed non-confrontational tactics in seeking to induce policy cooperation from the government. Occasionally though, they have resorted to more aggressive means to advance their policy preferences.” In the policy process of FTA negotiations, business associations can secure an insider status and have influence over the government’s position during negotiations.125 They can advance their preferences in the policy-making process without forming explicit coalitions or taking public stances to pressurise the government. An ‘occasional case’ of confrontation is exemplified by the Thailand-Japan FTA case. This case stimulated business to publicly announce their positions because the negotiation became highly politicised with the Japanese side trying to lobby cabinet members and the prime minister, while the Thai business sector felt threatened that their opinions would be overruled. Such direct criticism against the government’s behaviour, rather than trade liberalisation per se, seems to be needed to ensure that industry’s interests are protected. Outside the formal channels of business political influence, it is widely accepted that part of economic policy in Thailand is still being formulated through ad hoc clientelistic channels rather than formal, inclusive associations with legitimate consultative mechanisms. 126 Laothamatas 127 argues that although a growing influence of organised business interest has been present, “with electoral politics…corrupt dealings between government and business again picked up,”128 however, “clientelistic networking and corruption have not thus far obstructed the search for efficient economic strategies.”129 Another academic contends that, “the significant liberalisation in Southeast Asia has not been driven by new domestic coalitions of pro-market business or middle-class interest groups.”130 In the case of Thailand, the adapted although existing patterns 124 Laothamatas, “From Clienelism to Partnership: Business-Government Relations in Thailand,” 204. 125 Wynn Grant, Pressure Groups and British Politics (London: Macmillian Press, 2000), 19 distinguishes between insider and outsider groups. Insider groups are “regarded as legitimate by government and consulted on a regular basis.” In contrast, outsider groups “either do not wish to become enmeshed in a consultative relationship with officials, or are unable to gain recognition.” 126 Unger, 72; Laothamatas, “From Clienelism to Partnership: Business-Government Relations in Thailand”, 209. 127 Laothamatas, “From Clienelism to Partnership: Business-Government Relations in Thailand.” 128 Ibid., 209. 129 Ibid. 130 Greg Felker, “Globalization and Southeast Asia” (Draft Paper), Stanford 94 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W of state-business relationships between family-oligarchic business structures and business-backed parliamentarism has remained the defining feature in the politics of liberalisation. 131 Such factors are not the whole story, given the active participation by business associations in the FTA policy process. However, one conclusion that can be confirmed is that the semidemocratic capitalist system of Thailand makes it tricky for all relevant economic actors to fully form political coalitions, align their interests and be fully represented according to their policy preferences. 10. EXPLAINING THE SOCIAL/POLITICAL C OALITION While the economic approach has explanatory power in relation to the economic coalition, it can only provide limited insights about the change in non-economic interests and the motivation for non-economic actors to attempt to influence trade policy. Oatley 132 elaborates that: The society-centred approach tells us nothing about why groups that focus on the environment or human rights spend resources attempting to influence trade policy. Nor does it provide any basis with which to make sense of such groups’ trade policy preferences. In the past, such a weakness could perhaps be neglected because non-economic groups played only a small role in trade politics. The contemporary backlash against globalisation suggests, however, that these groups must increasingly be incorporated into society-centred models of trade politics. Developments in the international economic and political order, whether in the broader context or specific to the trading regime, lead to new factors and forces that have to be included in the trade politics equation. Understanding the politics of trade today is intricately linked with the politics of globalisation. Committing a country to a certain liberalisation regime often entails changes in commercial laws in order to make them compatible with the rules in those regimes. More than ensuring that trade will be freer, trade liberalisation in this context seeks to ensure that international trade relations will be governed. Consequentially, liberalisation will affect and constrain commercial practices and production and consumption patterns, both through changes in price and changes in regulations. Changes in economic activities have a more fundamental impact on peoples’ ways of life and societal values. In this chain of reactions, trade policy extends its realm of influence beyond the economic space of actors’ interests. Institute for International Studies, 17 (2004) http://iisdb.stanford.edu/evnts/3878/Felker_SEAF_paper.pdf. 131 Ibid. 132 Oatley, 108. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 95 Previously, political coalitions necessary to open up the country in Thailand were composed only of the state (such as military leaders or bureaucrats) and business elites while the rest of the country was dragged along with them. 133 Today, the empirical evidence shows that participants from civil society sectors have become the new main actors in trade politics and their support will be an important variable in maintaining enough political backing for the liberalisation agenda. In the analytical framework of preferences and institutions, sources of preferences, which bring social actors into trade politics, are traced and institutional backgrounds facilitating the forceful rise of this new coalition are discussed. This will be employed in the hope that a certain level of systematic analysis can be satisfied. However, the exploratory nature of the analysis in this unfamiliar area of trade politics should be equally productive. Since the social/political coalition actively opposes FTAs specifically in the case of the Thailand-US FTA, this FTA will be focused on as a case representative of new trends in the domestic politics of trade. Sources of Preferences In the trade arena, national policy is closely linked with processes at the international level, which set the framework for a country to pursue its policy preferences. The global trading regime and international trade policy landscape provide a particular context and condition for liberalisation. The context in which bilateral FTAs are being pursued is partly characterised by the proliferation of comprehensive agreements, which is part of the United States’ grand strategy of using FTAs to stimulate competitive liberalisation in a manner consistent with US interests. The US expects to use US-modelled comprehensive bilateral FTAs to establish precedents for wider agreements at the multilateral level.134 To pursue a bilateral FTA strategy with a more powerful strategic partner like the US, it is inevitable for Thailand to accept the terms and conditions imposed by the US. As discussed above, that comprehensive agreement involves deep economic liberalisation and results in farreaching impacts on the domestic economy and society. Policies of liberalisation in the form of comprehensive FTAs have strong social implications, are thus the first source of preferences for non-economic actors. 133 Bowie and Unger. Richard E. Feinberg, “The Political Economy of United States’ Free Trade Agreements,” Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, University of California, Sandiego (2003), 2. 134 96 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W Richardson 135 discusses the importance of incorporating knowledge about experiences elsewhere in public policy making and notes that policy transfers from one country to another is an increasingly important component of the policy learning process. In a similar vein, Bowie and Unger 136 note that in a complex global environment, predicting future impacts and estimating one’s own utilities toward a policy can be difficult and often, actors’ interests are not clearly articulated even to themselves. Thus, when the external model of those that experience similar events is available, actors are prone to draw parallels from experiences elsewhere in estimating their expected gains and losses and mobilising political pressure based on their interests, estimated through use of such analogies, which they term the “demonstration effect.” 137 Most of the arguments by opponents to FTAs from NGOs and civil society show that their preferences are drawn from events in the international arena both as a global political space and from other countries. Using the legitimacy and participation issues related to the W TO, they opposed Thai government on similar grounds. Resistance and resentment against free trade pacts, especially in relation to US-involved North-South agreements in other regions also provided the demonstration effect for NGOs, who predicted that similar consequences were likely in the Thai case. FTA Watch often support their case by pointing to disastrous consequences of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) 138 and how the US can force less powerful negotiating partners to accept terms unfavourable to them but to the benefit of the US, using the example of the US-Chile FTA. 139 And as Latin American NGOs have actively engaged in political mobilisation and established themselves as significant actors in the trade politics140 of NAFTA and the Free Trade Agreement of the Americas (FTAA), political mobilisation by FTA Watch can be seen as being partly influenced by their counterparts. 141 135 Jeremy Richardson, ‘Government, Interest Groups and Policy Change’ Political Studies vol. 48 (2000): 1006-1025. 136 Bowie and Unger. 137 Ibid., 23. 138 NAFTA is often used as a sample case to show ill consequences of trade agreements between developing countries and the US. Critics of NAFTA often point out that the flood of cheaper agricultural goods from the US have hurt Mexican farmers, US FDI has damaged the environment, industrialization headed by US MNCs forced indigenous people to relocate from their land and change their livelihoods etc. 139 FTA Watch, “Thailand-US Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand” and FTA Watch, “Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand.” 140 Karen Brock and Rosemary McGee, “Mapping Trade Policy: Understanding the Challenges of Civil Society Participation,” Institute of Development Studies Working Paper 225, Institute of Development Studies, England, 2004, 13. 141 Although this cannot be said for certain, there are strong linkages and networking among Thai NGOs and their international counterparts, especially those from South VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 97 Therefore, when existing examples from other countries can be drawn with a high level of compatibility, knowledge from other countries is important as a source for social actors to formulate their policy preferences. Although actors from the social/political coalition come from a diverse range of sectors, their interests are well-aligned in their opposition to FTA policy and in particular the issue of excluding intellectual property rights from the Thailand-US FTA. Their political alignment, as reflected in FTA Watch’s statements, suggests that the role of ideas is important in uniting social actors in contrast to how interests unite economic actors. The coalition’s aims are clearly stated: “(FTA Watch’s) aim is to provide the public with in-depth information and analyses of the FTAs, particularly on their potentially adverse effects on the more vulnerable sectors of Thai society, i.e., small businesses, people living with HIV/AIDS and the poor in general.” The fundamental ideological element detected here is the issue of the legitimacy of the government in representing the people. Most of the organisations involved with FTA Watch definitely see themselves as representatives of the marginalised groups. The idea of justice and fair representation (or lack of it) is, thus, the common ground uniting them. However, if this coalition is placed in the larger context of Thailand’s political climate, this pattern of interest constellation is quite predictable. Moreover, the diversity of actors who see their political interests aligned implies that there is a larger trend and broader trajectory to which this opposition is related or which it is trying to address. As Thailand finds itself immersed in the globalisation process as well as trying to come to terms with the 1997 economic crash, a political divide that has characterised the country has been termed by Thai academics and the press as a global-local divide.142 This global-local tension is rooted in the dualistic structure of Thai economic development, where export-oriented industrialisation and financial liberalisation gave rise to an urban-based, internationally-oriented, capital-intensive and technology-driven modern economy that is detached from the agrarianbased economy in the rural area which still inhibits the majority of the America. For example, FTA Watch organised a conference and invited speakers from activist from Mexican Action Network on Free Trade and Global Trade Watch. 142 Pasuk Phongpaichit and Chris Baker, “Democracy, Capitalism and Crisis: Examining Recent Political Transitions in Thailand,” Chulalongkorn University, Bangkok (2001); Natasha Hamilton-Hart, “Thailand and Globalisation” in East Asia and Globalisation, ed. Samuel S. Kim (Maryland: Rowman and Littlefield, 2000); Kewin Hewison, “Resisting Globalization: A Study of Localism in Thailand,” The Pacific Review, vol. 13, no. 2 (2000): 279-296. Alternatively, this could be read as a globalizercommunitarian divide (Hamilton-Hart, 191). 98 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W population. 143 The modern economy is populated by ‘globalisers’ (see table 4), consisting of commercial interests that promote corporate capitalism and advocate the advantages of liberalisation and the operation of the market. 144 At the other extreme, deeper globalisation often has negative consequences on the less flexible and less powerful local portion of society. Rodrik 145 observes that globalisation accentuates asymmetries between those who have the skills and mobility to flourish in global markets and those who either don’t have these advantages or perceive that the expansion of the market is inimical to social stability and deeply held norms. These consequences have been reinforced throughout the modern period as social implications have been consistently neglected by governments and people feel that the welfare of the masses has been subordinated the benefit of the wealthy few. Localists, with NGOs and social movements as significant participants 146 emerged in reaction to these consequences. They opposed globalisation, called for “justice in the international system and within individual nation-state,” 147 sought to break away from the domination of the neo-liberal model of economic growth and are suspicious of liberalisation and market economies.148 143 Phongpaichit, “Democracy, Capitalism and Crisis: Examining Recent Political Transitions in Thailand,” 11. 144 Hewison, ‘Resisting Globalization: A Study of Localism in Thailand’, 279 145 Rodrik, ‘Has Globalization Gone Too Far?” 2-3. 146 Hewison, “Resisting Globalization: A Study of Localism in Thailand,” 282. 147 Ibid., 282. 148 Ibid., 285-286. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 99 Table 4. Sum mary of Globalists vs. Localists tension in the Politics of Globalisation in Thailand Globalists Issues • • • Actors • Market orientation Deepening globalisation and economic integration with the international economy Promote corporate capitalism and advantages of globalisation Localists/Opponents of Globalisation • Opposition to economic growth, urban and industrialism • Advocates of local community/rural culture • Conservative nationalists aiming to protect Thai culture • Economic self-reliance, alternative developmental path such as selfsufficient economics or sustainable development • Critical of materialism and consumerism • NGOs and social movements • Farmers • Environmentallyconcerned groups • Buddhist monks Newly emergent and long-established Bangkok-based business families • Well-established urban capitalism • Foreign capital • Technocrats in economic bureaucracies Source: Hart; and Hewison. Tabulation created by author. In this broader and deeper setting, it can be seen that the global-local divide spilled over into the politics of trade policy and influenced the preference formation of social actors. Opponents of FTAs argue that they are undertaken for the benefit of narrow commercial interests at the expense of the rest of the population. They argue that the poor and socially disadvantaged groups like small farmers and small and medium enterprises (SMEs) will find it hardest to adjust, as the Thai government rushes the country into yet another trap set by the US to advance their neo-liberal agenda. The Thailand-US FTA undermines Thai sovereignty while Thai culture and heritage will be further destroyed by greater penetration of society by capitalistic forces and exploitation by foreign investors. 100 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W Institutional Factors: NGO Movements Given that NGO and civil society are new actors in the arena of trade policy, the institutional factor is especially important in facilitating their entrance to the area. An emerging institutional background that facilitates social actors and NGOs actively engaging in trade politics as well as assisting diverse actors to form a fairly cohesive and unified coalition against an FTA, lies at the heart of the establishment of new social forces and their immersion in the public policy making process. In Thailand, as social movements have developed into a loose, but identifiable set of interlocking networks, activists have begun to debate how to deliver their politics into the formal arena of parliamentary democracy. Political mobilisation and networking activities among NGOs, as well as their participation in the national political arena, have become more institutionalised.149 Such institutional structures have paved the way for their active role in trade politics, in an environment where trade policy has become strongly related to traditional areas of concerns for Thai civil society, such as the rural community, development, and poverty. 11. POLITICAL CLEAVAGE : THE ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL DIVIDE To summarise, the two coalitions that have emerged in response to the government’s FTA policy can be explicitly distinguished by their different foci and how their preferences have changed due to the potential impact of trade liberalisation. However, the two coalitions cannot be definitely determined by the political stances of proponents and opponents. Even if the economic coalition is characterised largely as supporting the policy, they voice opposition once elements of the policy deviate from their interests. Nevertheless, it can still be said that the government can secure support for FTA policy from business while it has to deal with outright resistance from the social/political coalition. The pattern of coalitions that has emerged reflects a more fundamental divide between groups in response to the challenge of free trade. The main factors characterising the two coalitions are their preferences and the arguments supporting their cases. While the first group argues mainly about the economic benefits and costs of the policy, the second group’s preferences and arguments are grounded in the social impacts. This political divide of the economic vs. the social coalition is structural both in terms of the national political economy and the international setting. The formation of preferences toward the FTA is 149 Phongpaichit and Baker, “Thailand: Economy and Politics”; Pasuk Phongpaichit, “Civilizing the State: State, Civil Society and Politics in Thailand,” The Wertheim Lecture 1999, Centre for Asian Studies Amsterdam (1999). VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 101 structurally rooted in the pattern of liberalisation in a context of globalisation and the landscape of international trade. Deeper globalisation as a result of FTAs promised benefits for market-oriented actors, but it has raised concerns among social actors about the social implications of free trade policy. The dualistic pattern of economic development in Thailand resulting in an economic and social asymmetry in the country further reinforces social concerns about free trade policy at the same time as export interests are advanced through the neo-liberal agenda and marketled economic development policies. Table 5. Political Cleavages in Response to FTA Policy in Thailand Source of Preferences Main Actors Political Argument/ Rationale Supporting their political stances Political Strategies/Position Economic Coalition Economic Interests Social/Political Coalition Business Associations Some Economists Leading Business figures International Competitiveness Fair Competition (when opposing liberalisation e.g. steel industry in Thai-Japan FTA) Social movements, local NGOs, international NGOs, politicians, academics Insider Status – regular consultative system with government agencies during negotiation Outsider Status – excluded from formal and regular consultative system with government agencies, street protests, sending letters to The Role of Ideas Concerns for fairness and justice Unfair trade deal on international stage Adverse social effects on the disadvantaged from globalisation and deeper economic integration Unfairness for the disadvantaged groups Lack of representativeness of the government in negotiating FTAs Loss of Sovereignty Capitalism profits at the expense of grassroots sufferings 102 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W Economic Coalition process. FTA of Co ncern Issue of Concern Political Dema nds for FTA negotiation Social/Political Coalition foreign governments (negotiating partners) and international organisations (the UN) FTA Thai-Japan, FTA Thai-China FTAs with major economic implications Tariff Reduction Unfair trade practices after liberalisation FTA Thai-US FTAs with major social and political implications Longer Adjustment Periods for sensitive sectors Government assistance programs to upgrade industries by increasing production efficiency and upgrading product quality and competitiveness Suspend the negotiation Withdrawal of certain issues Deep economic integration involving change in regulatory and institutional arrangements such as: Intellectual property rights Investment regime 12. C ONCLUSION This paper has attempted to look at interest configuration and the subsequent political activities of domestic socioeconomic actors in response to the Thai government’s liberalisation agenda and bilateral FTA policy. Using the theoretical framework of domestic politics and internationalisation, the theoretical underpinning of the paper is that the exposure of the country to international markets will change domestic actors’ preferences which will cause them to respond in such a way that their preferences can be fulfilled. Institutional factors will then act as a VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 103 mediating factor between actors’ preferences and their ability to organise or form coalitions. Investigating the case of FTA policy in Thailand, this paper concludes that the established theory of the domestic politics of trade based on economic models can provide insights into the way preferences of economic actors are formed, but it has less to say in terms of the emergence of a new non-economic coalition whose preferences are affected by free trade agreements in non-economic terms. Moreover, attention to preferences alone is not sufficient. Institutions are a significant intervening factor which helps to explain the actual formation of political coalitions which might deviate from actors’ preferences, the pattern of representation and the roles of interest groups in the politics of trade policy. In the case of Thailand, partial economic pluralism explains the lower degree of interest representation and political coalition by business compared to what can be observed in Western countries, especially the US. On the other hand, increasing democratisation, the institutionalisation of social forces and the emergence of civil society explain the entrance of NGOs and other social actors into this area of trade politics. The paper also argues that the political cleavages characterising the domestic politics of Thai FTA policy is the divide between the economic and social/political coalitions. Actors in each coalition have different sources of preferences. While actors in the first coalition base their preferences solely in terms of economic interests, those in the second draw their preferences from ideas and values and oppose the policy based on the social implications of free trade. The distinction between economic and political coalitions implies that under globalisation and in order to embark upon liberalisation, governments have to garner political support by managing the social and political implications of liberalisation policy. The emergence of the cleavage between the business coalition, which emphasises an economic justification of liberalisation, and those who are anxious about the social and political effects will change the whole political equation of the liberalisation process. Attention to the issue of legitimacy, and the assurance for the general population that the government will not trade narrow economic benefits for the suffering of the masses, has become a major requirement for successful liberalisation efforts. Using a society-centred approach to domestic politics, the limitation of this paper lies in its scope: by not giving due attention to the state that the state-centred approach would afford. The state-centred approach should be used to complement the society-centred approach in order to arrive at a more complete analysis of the domestic politics of trade, especially by looking at the patterns of influence that each interest group 104 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W has on policy outcomes. Given that the state may not respond with equal enthusiasm to different social groups’ demands, further research should aim to understand why the demands of certain groups are attended to while the influence of other groups is limited even when their preferences are represented in a democratic society. As for Thai NGOs, although they have established themselves as significant actors in the politics of FTAs, it is as yet inconclusive whether their participation in this area will become institutionalised. They also face the challenge of how to ensure that their political mobilisation will be influential enough so that the capitalist-oriented government will realise its obligation to achieve a better balance between the economic and social impacts of economic liberalisation policy. REFERENCES Ahearn, Raymond J. and Wayne M. Morrison. “U.S. - Thailand Free Trade Agreement Negotiations.” the United States Congressional Research Service (2004). http://us-asean.org/us-thaifta/RL32314.pdf. Ajanant, Juanjai. “ Trade and Industrialization of Thailand in 2020” in Restructuring Asian Econo mics for the New Millennium, Research in Asian Studies vol. 9B, edited by J.R. Behrman, M. Dutta, S.L. Husted, P. Sumalee, C. Suthipand and Wiboonchutikula, 743-772. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V., 2001. Akkarasriprapai, Benjaprut and Achara Pongvutitham, “FTAs to Boost GDP by 26%, Official Says.” The Nation, October 11, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. Akrasanee, Narongchai. ‘The FTA Architecture of Thailand’, Presentation at Pacific Economic Cooperation Council (PECC) Trade Forum Meeting 22 nd -25 th May, 2005, Jeju Island, Korea, 2005. Alt, James E. and Michael Gilligan. “The Political Economy of Trading States: Factor Specificity, Collective Action Problems, and Domestic Political Institutions” in International Political Economy: Perspective on Global Power and Wealth (4 th ed), edited by Jeffry A. Frieden and David A. Lake. Boston: Routledge, 2000. Asgatagacgat, Achara and Chatrudee Theparat. “Free Trade Has Its Many Costs.” Bangkok Post, February 16, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. Baldwin, Robert E. “The Political Economy of Trade Policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives vol. 3, no. 4 (1989): 119-135. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 105 Bangkokbiz News. “Keep Watch: FTAs Might Give Rise to Thai Labor Mobilization,” Bangkokbiz News, May 2, 2005 (in Thai) via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. Bangkok Post. “Explanation of FTA Is Lacking Woefully,” July 6, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. ———. ‘Free Trade or One-way Street’, December 2, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. Bowie, Alasdair and Danny Unger. The Politics of Open Economies: Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines and Thailand. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997. Brock, Karen and Rosemary McGee. “Mapping Trade Policy: Understanding the Challenges of Civil Society Participation.” Institute of Development Studies Working Paper 225, Institute of Development Studies, England, (2004). Changsorn, Pichaya and Usanee Mongkolporn. “No Running Away from FTAs,” The Nation, April 2, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. Charlton, Andrew H. and Joseph Stiglitz. “Common Values for the Development Round” (2004), http://www1.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/jstiglitz/download/website/Co mmon_Values_for_the_Development_Round.htm. Chinvarakorn, Vasana. “Free or Even Fair?” Bangkok Post, July 11, 2005. Choudry, Aziz. “The Elephant, the Rabbit, the Cobra and the Gold: Fighting the US-Thailand Free Trade Agreement,” Scoop Independent News, March 29, 2004, http://www.scoop.nz/stories/HL0403/S00306.htm?mode=print. Coughlin, Cletus C., Alec K. Chrystal and Geoffrey E. Wood. “Protectionist Trade Policies: A Survey of Theory, Evidence and Rationale” in International Political Econo my: Perspective on Global Power and Wealth (4 th ed.) edited by Jeffry A. Frieden and David A. Lake. Boston: Routledge, 2000. Cox, Ronald W. “Explaining Business Support for Regional Trade Agreements” in International Political Econo my: Perspective on Global Power and Wealth (4 th ed), edited by Jeffry A. Frieden, and David A. Lake. Boston: Routledge, 2000. Dent, Christopher M. “ The New Economic Bilateralism and Southeast Asia: Region-Convergent or Region-Divergent?” Institute of Political and Economic Governance (IPEG) Papers in Global Political Economy, No. 7 (April 2004). Department of Trade Negotiations, the Ministry of Commerce, “FTA: Free Trade Agreement,” www.thaifta.com. Doner, Richard F. and Ansil Ramsay. “Postimperialism and Development in Thailand.” World Development vol 21, no. 5 (1993): 691-704. 106 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W ———. ‘The Challenges of Economic Upgrading in Liberalizing Thailand’ in States in the Global Economy: Bringing Domestic Institutions Back In, edited by Linda Weiss. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003 Dornbusch, Rudiger. “ The Case for Trade Liberalization in Developing Countries.” Journal of Economic Perspectives vol. 6, no. 1 (1992): pp 69-85 Dunleavy, P. and Brendan O’Leary. Theories of the State. London: Macmillan, 1987. Dunleavy, P. Democracy, Bureaucracy and Public Choice, Hemel Hempsted, Harvester (1991). Esty, Daniel C. “The World Trade Organization’s Legitimacy Crisis.” World Trade Review vol. 1, no. 1 (2002): 7-22. Feinberg, Richard E. “ The Political Economy of United States’ Free Trade Agreements.” Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, University of California, San Diego (2003). Felker, Greg. “Globalization and Southeast Asia” (Draft Paper), Stanford Institute for International Studies (2004) at http://iis-db.stanford.edu/evnts/3878/Felker_SEAF_paper.pdf. Frieden, Jeffrey A. and Ronald Rogowski. “The Impact of International Economy on National Policies: An Analytical Overview” in Internationalization and Domestic Politics, edited by Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996. FTA Monitoring Committee, the Fiscal Policy Research Institute, “FTA Monitoring”, www.ftamonitoring.com. FTA Watch coalition, “FTA Watch”, www.ftawatch.org. FTA Watch (in Thai). Thailand-US Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand. Bangkok :FTA Watch, 2004. ———. Free Trade Agreement: Impacts on Thailand. Bangkok: FTA Watch, 2004. FTA Watch. “ Thailand’s Free Trade Agreements and Human Rights Obligations: Letter for Submission to the 84 th Session of the UN Human Rights Committee” (2005) at www.ftawatch.org. Garrett, Geoffrey and Peter Lange. “Internationalization, Institutions, and Political Change” in Internationalization and Domestic Politics, edited by Robert O. Keohane, and Helen V. Milner. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996. Gilpin, Robert. Global Political Economy: Understanding International Economic Order, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001. Goldstein, Judith and Lisa L. Martin. “Legalization, Trade Liberalization, and Domestic Politics: A Cautionary Note.” International Organization vol. 54, no. 3 (2000): 603-632. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 107 Gourevitch, Peter. “ The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic Politics.” International Organization vol. 32, no. 4 (1978): 881-912. Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman. “ The Politics of Free Trade Agreements.” The American Economic Review vol. 85, no. 4 (1995): 667-690. Grant, Wynn. Pressure Groups and British Politics. London: Macmillian Press, 2000. Hamilton-Hart, Natasha. “Thailand and Globalization” in East Asia and Globalization, edited by Samuel S Kim. Maryland: Rowman and Littlefield, 2000. Henderson, David. “W TO 2002: Imaginary Crisis, Real Problems.” World Trade Review vol. 1, no. 3 (2002): 277-296. Hewison, Kewin. “Emerging Social Forces in Thailand: New Political and Economic Roles” in The New Rich in Asia: Mobile Phones, McDonald’s and Middle-Class Revolution edited by Richard Robinson and David S.G Goodman. London and New York: Routledge, 1996. Hewison, Kewin. “Thailand: Capitalist Development and the State’ in The Political Economy of South-East Asia: An Introduction, edited by Garry Rodan, Kewin Hewinson and Richard Robinson. Melbourne: Oxford University Press, 1998. ———. “Resisting Globalization: A Study of Localism in Thailand.” The Pacific Review vol. 13, no. 2 (2000): 279-296. ———. “Thailand’s Capitalism Before and After the Economic Crisis” in Politics and Markets in the Wake of the Asia Crisis, edited by Richard Robinson, Mark Beeson, Kanishka Jayasuriya and HyukRae Kim. London: Routledge, 2000. ———. “The Politics of Neo-Liberalism: Class and Capitalism in Contemporary Thailand.” Working Paper Series: No. 45, Hong Kong Southeast Asia Research Centre, The City University of Hong Kong (2003) at http://www.cityu.edu.hk/searc/WP45_03_Hewison.pl. Hocking, Brian. “ Trade Politics: Environments, Agendas and Processes” in Trade Politics: International, Domestic and Regional Perspectives, edited by Brian Hocking and Steven McGuire. London: Routledge, 1999. Hoekman, Bernard and Michel Kostecki. The Political Economy of the World Trading System: WTO and Beyond (2 nd ed.) Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001. Intal J.R., Ponciano. “Bilateral and Multilateral Trade Negotiations and Business.” Paper prepared for ‘Business for Development’ Conference hosted by Department of Trade and International 108 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W Trade Center, 21-22 October, 2004, Philippine Trade Training Center, Manila. Itoga, Shigeru. “Labor Issues and APEC Liberalization: Case of Thailand and Malaysia.” IDE APEC Study Center Working Paper Series No.1 Fiscal Year 1996/1997, Institute of Developing Economies, Japan External Trade Organization (1997) at www.ide.go.jp. Jamal, Vali. “NIKKEI Interviews: Employment in Asia” in Liberalization and Labor, edited by Rajah Rasian and Norbert von Hofmann. Singapore: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung, 1996. Japan-Thailand Economic Partnership (JTEP) Office. “Japan-Thailand Economic Partnership Agreement.” www.mfa.go.th/jtepa. Jayasuriya, Kanishka. “Embedded Mercantilism and Open Regionalism: the Crisis of Regional Political Project.” Third World Quarterly vol. 24, no. 2 (2003): 339-355. Keohane, Robert O. and Helen V. Milner. “Internationalization and Domestic Politics: An Introduction” in Internationalization and Domestic Politics, edited by Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996. Krongkaew, Medhi. “ The Economics of Institutional Change: Making Economic Policy in Thailand” in Institutions and Econo mic Change in Southeast Asia: the Context of Development from the 1960s to the 1990s, edited by Colin Barlow and Edward Elgar. UK: Cheltenham, 1999. Laothamatas, Anek. “From Clientelism to Partnership: BusinessGovernment Relations in Thailand” in Business and Government in Industrializing Asia, edited by Andrew MacIntyre. New South Wales: Allen and Unwin, 1994. Laothamatas, Anek. Business Associations and the New Political Econo my of Thailand, Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1992. Limsamarnphun, Nophakhun. “Bilateral Free Trade is A Game of High Stakes,” The Nation’, February 23, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. Lloyd, P.J. “New Regionalism and New Bilateralism in the Asia-Pacific.” Visiting Researchers Series No. 3, Institute of Southeast Asian Studies (2002). Low, Linda. “ The Political Economy of Trade Liberalization.” AsiaPacific Develop ment Journal, vol. 11, no. 1 (2004): 1-23. MacIntyre, Andrew. “Business, Government and Development: Northeast and Southeast Asian Comparisons” in Business and Government in Industrializing Asia, edited by Andrew MacIntyre. New South Wales: Allen and Unwin, 1994. Ministry of Commerce (in Thai). FTA Fact Book. Bangkok: Department of Trade Negotiations, Ministry of Commerce, 2004. VOL. 2 , NO. 1 —MAY 2 0 0 6 109 Nagai, Fumio. “ Thailand’s Trade Policy: WTO plus FTA?” IDE APEC Study Centre, Working Paper Series 01/02-No.6, APEC Study Centre, Institute of Developing Economies (2002). Na Thalang, Jeerawat. “Advice From Economists: Focus FTAs on Major Markets,” The Nation, September 25, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. Oatley, Thomas. International Political Economy: Interests and Institutions in the Global Econo my. New York: PearsonLongman, 2004. Phongpaichit, Pasuk. “Civilizing the State: State, Civil Society and Politics in Thailand.” The Wertheim Lecture 1999, Centre for Asian Studies Amsterdam (1999). Phongpaichit, Pasuk and Chris Baker. Thailand: Economy and Politics (2n Ed.) Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press, 2002. ———. “Democracy, Capitalism and Crisis: Examining Recent Political Transitions in Thailand.” Bangkok: Chulalongkorn University, 2001. Pinyorat, Rungrawee C. ‘Activists Want New Law to Control FTAs Process’, The Nation, March 20, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. ———. “Trade Negotiations: FTA Opponents Plan Rally, The Nation,” June 30, 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgibin/content/newse/list.pl. Ravenhill, John. “ The New Bilateralism in the Asia Pacific.” Third World Quarterly vol. 24, no. 2 (2003): 299-317. Richardson, Jeremy. “Government, Interest Groups and Policy Change.” Political Studies vol. 48 (2000): 1006-1025. Rodan, G. The Political Economy of South-East Asia: Conflicts, Crises and Change, Melbourne: Oxford University Press, 2003. Rodrik, Dani. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1997. ———. “Feasible Globalizations.” John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University (2002) at, http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~drodrik/Feasglob.pdf. Rogowski, Ronald. Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Do mestic Political Align ments. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989. ———. “Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments” in International Political Economy: Perspective on Global Power and Wealth (4 th ed.), edited by Jeffry A. Frieden and David A. Lake. Boston: Routledge, 2000. Shinawatra, Thaksin (in Thai). “Free Trade Agreement: Opportunities for Business.” Keynote Speech by Prime Minister Thaksin Shinawatra, 110 IN TE RN A T I O N AL P U BL I C P O L I CY R E VIE W February 19 th , 2004 at the Federation of Thai Industries’ Seminar on Free Trade Agreements, UNESCAP (2004). Solingen, Etel. ‘ASEAN, Quo Vadis? Domestic Coalitions and Regional Cooperation’ Contemporary Southeast Asia vol. 21, no. 1 (1999): pp30-53. TDRI (in Thai). “Report of the Study on Impacts from Thailand-United States Free Trade Agreement.” Thailand Development Research Institute, Bangkok, Thailand (2003). ———. “Sub-topic Study Number 2: Preliminary Analysis on the Impact from Thailand-Japan Free Trade Agreement.” Thailand Development Research Institute (2005) at www.ftadigest.com. TDRI, “FTA Digest”, www.ftadigest.com. The Economist, “Country Briefings: Thailand,” 2004. www.economist.com. The Nation, “Furore over Steel ‘Cave-in,’” April 5, 2005 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. ———. “Push for FTAs with US, Australia and Japan by Year’s End,” February 20. 2004 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgibin/content/newse/list.pl. ———. “Thai-Japan FTA Talks: Warning from Carmakers,” April 8, 2005 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgibin/content/newse/list.pl. Treerapongpichit, Busrin, “Local Manufacturers Cry Foul Over Change in Stance on Steel,” Bangkok Post, April 4, 2005 via FTA Watch, http://www.ftawatch.org/cgi-bin/content/newse/list.pl. Unger, Danny. Building Social Capital in Thailand: Fibres, Finance, and Infrastructure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998. USTR (United States Trade Representative). “Letter to House of Representatives on Intent to Negotiate FTA with Thailand.” USTR (2004) at www.ustr.gov. ———. “Letter to Senate on Intent to Negotiate FTA with Thailand.” USTR (2004) at www.ustr.gov. US-Thailand FTA Business Coalition. “US-Thailand FTA Business Coalition.” http://www.us-asean.org/us-thai-fta/ World Bank. “Thailand Economic Monitor.” World Bank Thailand Office (2005) www.worldbank.org.