COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS IN THE DEVELO PfiE NT OF WATEq P.ESOURCES CECIL CRAWFORD KUHNE, III Cost-Benefit Analysis in the Development Of Water Resources I. Cost-Benefit Analysis: An Overview A. General Economic Principles Price theory deals with the flow of goods and services from resource owners to businesses and eventually to the ultimate consumer, with the consequent effect of pricing on the factors of that flow. l Price theory also seeks to demonstrate how resource prices allocate resources among different users and geographical areas. Only if pure competition prevails in both product markets and resource markets will resources automatically be allocated to maximize net national 2 product. From an individual firm's standpoint, it is most advantageous to use resources at their least-cost combination and to use only the absolute amounts necessary in order to pro.? uce at a level which maximizes profits. 3 Price theory, then, assures an efficient allocation of resources in private markets, but c~rtain goods which society as a whole desires will not be produced by the private sector. The government seeks to provide for t:E!rtain beneficial goods or services known as "merit goods." The political process provides for such merit goods as compulsary education, subsidized housing, and compulsary health service. These meri t goods are· furnished by the government ·, regardless of economic efficiency. But collective goods, such as flood control and national defense, are not furnished by private firms because of the prohibitive costs. Collective goods are provided by the government due to the inability of the marketplace to produce them, and it is thus necessary that a formula for economic efficiency be developed in order to get the greatest possible return on governmental investments. 4 Cost-benefit analysis has its beginnings in welfare economics, which seeks to improve the well-being of consumers and producers as persons by means of policy recommendations,S and as a part of welfare economics,' cost-benefit analysis is the application of pure allocation theory.6 Welfare economi.cs had its beginnings in what is commonly known as the Pareto theory. The Pareto theory concerns itself with an economic rearrangement in which the economic gains can be so distributed as to make everyone in the community ' better off ~ This, however, is an actual Pareto improvement. A potential Pareto improvement deals with economic change which leaves some persons better off, while leaving others worse off • . If those who gain are willing to compensate the losers, then there is a potential Pareto improvement.' It must be ' noted that although there is a gain in the analysis, this is a quantitative gain, with some persons still suffering 8 10sses. And, it may happen that those who lose will not be compensated. 9 Th'is theory ( as a result, has been criticized for causing a change in the distribution cif' income since those individuals with lower incomes may be affected more by · economic changes than those in the higher income brackets. Cost-benefit analysis, too, seeks only to aggregate the benefits of. a project and balance them against aggregate costs, and if benefits exceed 'c osts, then the plan is eco• • nomically justified, despite certain" aClverse effects. B. Assumptions and Procedures Cost-benefit analysis, like price theory, assumes perfect _ competition and the abse~ce of external diseconomies. lO Any changes in aggregate inc~me, income distribution, and market form have a resultant effect on both prices and a cost-benefit ll analysis. Cost-benefit analysis also assumes that maximization of national income is the I primary, if not the only, .g oal of water resource allocation. 12 The purpose 'of a cost-benefit analysis is to require an effective evaluation of the values of a proposed government , project, which will in turn lead . to an improved expe_ndi ture of public funds. 13 It seems however that the purpose has broadened considerably to encompass other factors. 14 The method also serves two other basic functions. First, if the cost-benefit ratio is to be maximized, such factors as the size of the project 'may be altered in order to provide the "greatest benefits. Thus, the analyst can ascertain how much capaci ty a ' dam s'hould contain or how much navigation or recreational facilities should be expanded. Second, cost-benefit analysis provides a meansJ for comparing alternatives if the project has a specific purpose. For example, if a project is to be constructed to provide electric power, then cost-benefit analysis allows a determination of whether a hydroelectric I dam, a plant using coal, or an atomic plant would be the most economically efficient. 1S Not all economists agree, however, that' the cost-benefit ratio can be used to compare different projects. One commentator points out that using 'the cost-benefit ratio to compare one project with another is fallacious and would be analagous, in the commercial world, of using a ratio . t t' d eC~S10n. •. 16 . t s t 0 gross ' expenses . o f gross rece~p ~n an ~nves men A cost-benefit: ratio may cause a misalloca'tion of resources if projects are not analyzed in a comparative manner. For example, suppose that two mutually exclusive projects are ' compared, one having a benefit of $S and a cost of $1 (ratio is 5) and the other having a benefit of $1,200 and a cost of $1,000 (ratio is 1.2). The first project has a greater ratio, l , 17 but it would be undesirable to lose a ~200 gain for a $4 gain. While cost-benefit analysis has largely replaced price theory in government investments, it has ,been proposed that cost-benefit analysis could be expanded beyond public investments and could be used, for example, in ,private litigation over riparian water rights. 18 The actual procedure of cost-benefit analysis is relatively simple. The first step requires an estimation of installation costs and annual operating costs over the life of the project. Then the value ' of the project's output must be estimated by ascertaining the nuinber of units to be produced and their value. Finally, secondary, or indirect costs and benefits are computed. All of the costs and benefits are then discounted with the appropriate rate in order to arrive at the present value. 19 The costs are either subtracted from the benefits, or the results are expressed in a ratio (benefits as numerator, costs as denomihator), in which a value greater than unity indicates an economically justifiable . 20 proJect. The concepts of what constitutes a benefit and what constitutes a cost are indespensible to the analysis. The terms are usually divided into primary (direct) and secondary (indirect) benefits and costs, and then there is a further s'ubdivision wi thin each of those two major divisions, with these subdivisions labeled as tangible and intangible benefits and costs. confused. The concepts are distinct, although frequently Primary (direct) .costs include the initial expenditures required to construct and maintain a project. These costs also include the value of any adverse effects, whether they are compensated or not. The primary benefits are the value of those goods and services which result -from the expenditure 21 · o f . t h e d 1reCt costs. Secondary (in~irect) costs are costs of further processing or any other costs "stemming from or induced by" the project. These costs include the value 'of goods and services necessary . to make goods available for use or s 'a le. Secondary benefits are the benefits to the nation as a result of activities "stemming frcm or induced by" the projece. 22 The words "stemming from or induced by" are significant; the former include processing such as transporting power, and the latter, 23 any change in technology or shifts in supply and demand. The primary and secondary dichotomies i.nclude both tangible and intangible benefits and costs. Tangible benefits would include the value of cotton produced as a result of new irrigation sources/ tangible costs are. the costs of the darn. The rehabilitation of a drinking ground for waterfowl might be an intangible benefit arising from a project, while -5- the same proje.ct would create an intangible cost by the construction of a dam which would interfere with anadromous fisheries. 24 C. "Willingness to Pay" and Alternative Costs The benefits of goods and services produced by the market system are easily ascertained, but benefits without market values a.re determined by the concept of "willingness to pay." In the Pareto theory, the willingness to pay is that amount which the winners of economic change must pay to the losers if the change is to take place. 25 The willingness to pay may be estimated by the analyst, or it may be obtained from those individuals who are to be affected by the change in environmental quality, either through a referendum approach or opinion polls.26 Thus, the welfare economist is able to provide for a means of det.ermining value in the absence of market mechanisms. Economists have also expanded upon the definition of ., costs. Outlay costs are those costs required for construction - and maintenance of a project, such as wages, equipment, taxes, and so forth. The alternative costs, or opportunity costs, are normally· defined as "the value of the benefit foregone by choosing one alternative rather than another." This is an important concept since the real cost of any activity is measured by its alternative costs, not its outlay costs. 27 Due to the scarcity of resources, those resources used by a firm in the manufacture of a product ~ause the total amount of available resources to diminish, if only slightly. If units of a certain type of specialized labor can only be used to asserr~le washing machines or refrigerators, then the costs of ~he resources to the firm are the values in their alternative uses. The firm which decides to manufacture washing machines- must pay the value of refrigerators that the labor could have produced. I.£ the manufacturer of washing machines refuses to pay the alternative costs, then the labor will remain in refrigeration producticn. 28 Alternative cos.t s are measured by means of input-output tables, which show the, flow of goods and services from industrial sector to the ultimate purchaser. 29 The input-output analysis can also be used to assess the contributions of various sectors of .the economy to' the disturbances in t,he ecosystems. 30 ,Alternativ.e costs are used not' only to ascertain total costs but also benefits. In cost-benefit analysis the benefits are equal to ,the alternative cost, or the "cost of providing comparable output by ' its cheapes,t alternatl.vc mer-me." These alte1'nativc costs are widely used in power. ftlunicipal waste supply, and naviga,tion. 311 The use of cost-benefit analysis in the allocation of resources is ",lsc· infhlE,nccd by the concept of utility. Apparent,ly, the su,bjectiye utility of society which is derived frem consuming 9,o ods and seJ:vices is greater than the disutility associated with disturbances to 'the e!Tlvironment. Once the marginal utility of consumption levels off with the resulting disutility, the system shouldlllove ' back to eqllilibtium. 32 'This disutility results from externalities which are ' the " ' prl.va . t e cos t s. 33 Oft en th ese result of social costs exceed i ng externalities result from a firm producing at overcapacity " 34 ' ' levels. These externalities, or spillovers, include noise 'a~d , pollution of industry and the adverse effects upon plants. Often the externalities are accidental and are 35 placed upon individuals who are unable to avoid their effeots. .~ }\ II. Statutory and Judicial Responses A. water Resources Council Cost-benefit analysis is a well-settled theory, having been used in ' a general way in the early part of the , century. 36 In the field of water resources development, it was first noted in the Flood Control Act of 1936. 37 The Act recognized that destructive floods: constitute a menace to national welfare; •• that the Federal Government should improve or participate in the improvement of navigable waters ••• for flood control purposes if the benefits to whomsoever the'y may accrue are in excess of the costs, and if the lives and social securitY38 of people are otherwise adversely affected. One economist has observed that the legal requirements of the Act are impossible to meet becaus,e economic analysis is not refined enough to measure all costs ' and benefits "to whomsoever they may accrue," and furthermore, such an assessment requires Act. 39 sp~cific methodology Which is not specified in the The next development in the cost-benefit analysis for water projects was the Proposed Practices for Economic Analysis of River Basin Projects (1958), also known as the Green Book. 40 This work was important because it defined primary and secondary costs and benefits. The Green Book was soon superseded by Policies, Standards, and Procedures in the Formulation, Evaluation, and Review of Plans for Use and Development of Water ' and Related Land Resources,4l which , became the ,official adoption of cost-benefit analysis. Senate Document 97 is detailed in its, definitions of benefits (tangible benefits; intangible benefits; primary benefits; secondary benefits)and costs (project economic ' costs; installation costs; operation, maintenance, and replacement costs; ' induced costs; associated costs; taxes). 42 Standards of , measurement are given for each type of benefit resulting from water projects, inclu~:i;.ng: (1) domestic, municipal, and industrial water supply benefits, benefits, (3) water quality control benef~ts, benefits, (5) electric power benefits, prevention benefits, drainage benefits" (2) irrigation (4) navigation (6) flood control and (7) land stabilization benefits, (9) recreation benefits. 43 (8) This methodology of measurement for water projects became the most sophisticated of the resource fields. Most importantly, the statement provides for economic projections of the project on both the regional and national economies. 44 The statement is not without shortcomings, however. It has been c 'r iticized 'as plac'i ng undue emphasis upon benefits of a project by its preoccupation with the quantity of goods and services produced. While ' mentionin,g economic. growth; the statement provides no real analysis for this resulting growth. 45 A later report of the Water Resources Council in 1971 overcame many of the difficulties of its predecessor by its practical approach. The Proposed Principles and Standards for Planning Water and Related Land Resources 46 0utline four broad objectives which are to be considered in relation to a water project: (1) national economic development, (2) , environmental quality, (3) regional development, (4) social factors. It should be noted at the outset that each area requires the application of the "with and without" principle, which requires the estimation of the beneficial and adverse effects of a particular project after completing the project and comparing these results ,with the situation existing if the project were never constructed. The analyst is also aided by the tables in the Proposed Standards which give examples "of beneficial .and adverse effects of projects, as well as the ramifications o'n the economic development of the area. The first ob'jective of analysis, national economic development, conserns' itsetf with the increase of goods and services. ' These increases in economic efficiency are to be balanced against the increase in environmental quality which , ' would occur by decreasing the use of' r 'esources ordinari ly used in the production of consumer goods. The adverse effects on national eqonomic developme'n t are determined by measuring the 'economic value that the resources would have in alternative uses, and while these externalities are difficult to measure, they should be recognized. The second consideration, environmental quality, requires the measurement of the deterioration of environmental quality. The Proposed Standards enumerate cla's ses of environmental entities, such as wild andsceriic rivers, lakes, mountains,. and estuaries, and with,i n each class there are factors , to , be , measured to determine the detrimental effects, Le. (for es,t uarie8) the , . size of the estuary, biological significance asa breeding or feeding ground, and improvements. 47 The beneficial and adverse effects on regional development constitute the next 'category of measurement. Beneficial factors are increased productivity of goods and services, value of output to 'users residing in the region as a result of external economies or expansion ,of resource use, and additional net income resulting from the project. Adverse effects include taxation, external diseconomices (externalities), and the displacement of resources. The fouth class of effects are those social effects resulting from a project, SUCh as distribution of wealth,or improved safety (as provided by flood control, for example). The P~oposed Standards also discuss the problems involved in determining the life of the project and the discount rate. The life of the project is to be the lesser of "(1) the period of time over which the plan will serve a useful purpose considering probable technological trends affecting various alternatiVes; or (2) the point of time when further discounting of beneficial and adverse effects will have no appreciable result on design.,,48 After determining the period of analysis, the discount rate -is the average rate of return on private investments, including taxation. 49 B. NEPA and the Courts 1\ Athough the National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA) does not explicitly require a cost-benefit analysis, the Act does ,require that "presently unquantified environmental amenities and values may be given appropriate consideration _ . , an d tec h ' 1 conS1. d era t'10ns. ,,50 in decisionmaking along w1th econom1a n1ca The legislative history, in discussing ,the duties of the Cou-n cil on Environmental Quality (CEQ), lends substance to the -use , of the cost-benefit analysis: One way in which this [consideration of environmental amenities] might be done would be to develop a , sophisticated cost and benefit analysis in which the total (and often not strictly economic) consequences of Federal activities .~ may be assessed. The environmental auditing function of the Council falls squarely within the functions specified in this subsection.5l 52 The CEQ Guidelines are of little assistance, however, in defining what is required in such an analysis, but the Guidelines do reques't that the Environmental Protection Agency be consul ted , where water .quality s 'tandards have been set. 53 And the Environmental Protection Agency, in its ' proposed guidelines, which were later adopted, requires a cost benefit analysis. 54 The courts first interpreting NEPA were reluctant to ,find a cost-benefit analysis invalid unless it was shown that the actua'l balance of costs and benefits was arbitrary or ' clearly gave insufficient weight to environmental values. 55 The court in Sierra Club v. Froehlk~~6 however, held a more aggresive view in regard to the analysis, after finding a deficiency in the determination of the costs by the agency: ' However, when the claimed ' ratio is comprised, in part, of environmental amenities which Congress has required under current law to be given careful attention and consideration, then the courts have an obligation to act, where necessary. The standard for judicial review is the same as for 'other features of environmental law, being one of "substantial inquirYi"57 • ., ~ The court in Sierra Club pointed out that no environmental costs were considered but that in addition to economic benefits, the agency claimed recreational benefits -and benefits stemming from navigation, ' water 'supply, and salinity control. 58 And in spite of a large increase in costs over the years, the 59 cost-benefit ratio remained the same. 'III. Cost-Benefit All,alysis and Water Resources I An Evaluation A. The Use of Economic Theory and Quantification , Many problems associated with cost-benefit analysis stem from the use of economic theory. Cost-benenefit analysis assumes that the market is perfectly competitive and that no externalities exist, ' so that once there is ,a change in these' assumptions, the analysis becomes less reliable. 60 The goal of any projec,t is the maximization of nutional income, while the constrained variable is represented by the budget of the 61 ' federal government. The population, however, is not interested in the absolute size of the Gross National Product but is interested in the income distr'i bution 'a s .it affects them , ' 62 personally. And, while it it is recognized that some bUd'g etary restraint must be taken into account, the restraint used has a sizeable effect on the cost-benefit ratio. If some budgetary' restraint is not defined, a project may be constructed to an excessive scale, which will result in .,the dec~ease of funds available ' for projects more economically desirable. 63 And furthermore, two projects might appear similar since they have equal benefits, even though there is a large disparity in costs. 64 since the values employed in cost-beneft analyaio are related to values iil the mark'e tplace, their validity assumes that the ' present distribution of wealth and in,come in the lI'arket is acceptable. If , the purpos'e of a project is to raise water quality in an urban area, then the lower income groups are the milin bElneficiaries siAde they live in the cities; but if \~ilderne5s preservation are the primary benefitl\, then benefits are overstated because t.hey · flow to those in , 65 . higher incomes. Thus, the task of economic evaluati.on is a complex one: The water resource economist now frequently faces a truly imposing array 'of problems evalua ting water resources whose market purchas e at best generates only indirect indications Of / the relative value people place on them; tra(:ing and evaluating complex ' interdependencies on sys 't ems e ,f fects, often over very large geographical areas; and helping to guide decisions involving great uncertain TY due to the rapid ,pace of economic and tAchnical data. 66 Much of this difficulty results from the information included ' in the analysis. Cost-benefit analysis has heAn criticized as containing a bias of the analyst, which is aften the government. 67 The statements prepar.ed by the government, which often distort aetual benefits, seem to support this criti~ism.68 These conscious evaluations, however, are ' reflected in the analysis. But often a proj e ct produces results that were never ' anticipated when the analysis was prepared. If the market fails to provide fol;' all of the alternatives, then it is impossible to obtain the most efficient analY6is. 69 The analysJs, therefore, may demonstrate that welfare has increased, but it does not indicate whether the m~ximum benefits have been achieved. 70 The use of economic analysis requires the quantification of costs and benefits into monetary terms in order for the , resul ts to be AXp,r esse'ct as a mathematical t:atio. ,Monetary amounts are placed on' environmental ame nJ.tit>s as a measure' of their value. This uSe of the price system as ' a means of evaluation, howevp.r, is complicated, since many benefits an~ costs ' connected with environmental ' issues have no market value, such as "the joys of ' a free flowing stream.,,71 ,Kenneth Boulding, a lloted economist, believes that human values can be reconciled jand comput"'c;l ,.with economic values. 72 The final result of the analysis is a single mathe~aticai figure. Finding a ll11mez:ical expression to represent the "standard of 1 iving, ',' for example, presents the same pZ'ob lems. The many facets of environmental quality make it impossible to interrelate all of the criteria, much of which i~ subjective, and produce a measure of overall environmental quality to fit into the cost-benefit ratio. 73 Assuming that environmental all\onities can be quantified " the problem is easier when the analyst is deciding among alternative programs; theoretically, at least, errors 'are consistent in all of the 'factors and will hI'! reflected equally in each. In Ii broader sense, even if there ~s an a.bso~ute measure available in tho resources field, the problem remains of comparing the benefits and costs in the , resources field with ' those of other fields of government expenditures in order to arrive at the most effi 'c ient use of government funds. 74 Despite the complexity and arbitrariness of cost-beneflt analysis, quantific~tion forces the analyst to carefully examine all possible alternatives, to account responsihly for his own preferences, and to perceive the relations between variables and mar~et restrictions in economic analysis. The preparation of the analysis serves an important function in com75 pelling an interdisciplinary study of the proposed project. B. Measuring Ben~fits and Costs Hany of the limitations of cost-benefit a,n<1lysis rest within the inherent restrictions of economic analysis in measuring benefits and ebsts. Since the economist can only accurately estimate short run costs,76 the analysis will overstate costs and unde'rstate benefits. For example, the short term solution of placing a device on an existing plant to abatA pollution is more expensive than 'a long term proposal of designing a plan't for pollution abatement. As a result, long term costs may be omitted, and the benefits which result from expenditures may be estimated despite a reliable method ' t 10n. ' 77 , O'f quan t'1 f 1ca ., 1. Benefits A water resource project may prbduce several benefits which have counterparts in the mark et system. In projects for irrigation and flood control, ,the analyst can determin e how much the fa rmer, has i llcre'a sed his ' productivity by c omparing ' yields before and afl:er the project. 78 or the amount of flood damage that would have resulted to 10'Ncr riparinn landowners in the abs e n ce of a dam. 79 In other instances the , benefits are eas i ly identifiable , ' but are very di.Cficult t p measure, such as the economic advantage which industry gains as a result of a decrease in treatment costs 8 2r the economic advantage wh i ch il1dust ,r y 'gains 8l from the greater availabi f ity of recreational servic;:es. In regard to certain eecondary benefits, it i3 often possible to d~termine tho economic effects of a project in a regional analysis, but it is beyond the capabilities of cost-benefit analysis to determine the economic ramifications of a project on the national economy, even though admitt,,,J1y the national income is increased by tho~:e projects. 82 And in the water resources field; it is not only difficult to measure certain intangible benefits but to develop causal relationships I these benefits include: land values, (1) increases in private (2) increases in employment, (3) profits o.f businesses dealing with water recipients, (4) value of water above that paid by the recipient. 83 De5pite th£> difficulties of evaluation of water quality improvoment, recreation, and improved industrial and municipal water supply·, the government has increased i ·ts reliance on such benei ts in justifying projects. The area of recreational benefits comprises an increasing justification for the development of water projects. 84 The usual procedure for evaluating outdoor recreation is by means of a value between $0.50 and $1.50 per man-day for general Qutdoorrecreation an.d between $2.00 and $6.00 per · man-day for speci.alized · ·outdoor recreation. 85 These values of rec- · reational benefits have been criticized because they are . arbitrary and fail · to take intoconst~eration such factors as the proximity of· the . population to reservoirs offering recreational benaf£ts. 8& The~e recreational benefits are also claimed without allowing for the costs to free flowing . . 87 stream recreat10n. Th1 visitors t.o these recreational areas may be few in number, but. since they are considered high priority visitors, . the benefits may be overstated. On the other hand, there may be social benefits in encouraging outdoor recreation. The individuals who attend these recreational projects pay littie or nothing for the privilege, so that they may benefit . d t 0 pay. 88 more th an 1. f th ey ware reqlure As noted . above, the willingness to pay principle has been used in cost-benefit analysis to d~t~rmine · the va.l ue of benefits: The mere use of this criterion gives preferential r.ights to those who are using the ' environment for waste dispoSlll,S3 Then the analyst must make a comparison of the benefits accruin9 to different persons, 'l'he usual procedure is to ,a dd the ben'Jfits of all people with each person given an equal '''<"light. EVfln with this procedu're, ther" is a ,U fficult valUe judgment required to make ,these interpersonal comparisons. 84 How much a person is willing to pay for benefits is often determined through a referendum approach or opinion polll3. SAveral problems may arille in this process of questioning indIviduals. If the individual expects to be charged for what he is willing to pay, then it is logical to iUlflume that he wOll,ld Hant to pay the least possible amount. If he then undervalues his willingness to P."'I.Y, he will expect to pay less. On , the other hand, if an indi.vidUal kn('ws that his payments for a proje1t w.o'lld be small and that the project would be financed by the federal 90vernment, there is tendency to overstat.~ Uti! , t.' construc10n 0f benefits in an, effort to encourage tht! 1 ,ft5 tIe proJect. ' , " The willi,n gnElss to p~y approach may also be undp.restimated in ano,ther way, Since 'the , preservation of the environment is an important part of the real income of many indivi.duals, the amount of compensation these individuals would require if future generations were to be dep.f~ved of environmemtal amenities would be much greater than the w,i llingness to pa~' for the present benefits of the pr.oject. U6 ,In adclit,ion to ' 'the concept of wi.llin-"ness to pay, benefits may be valued by alternative c'o~t.s, ~lhich are the costs of prol1idi.ng comparable output by means of the least expensive 'alternative. ' Th'lS, the val,ie of b~nefits of a federal power project are equated with the CO'!lts of a prj,v,d-,e utility's providing the same level of output. S7 Determing benefits by means of alternative costs is 'not only employed in' power projects I but projects for municipal ~later supply and navigation. SS This, practice of alternativEl costs is often misleadin,], i.t is based on t.hE. assumpt.ion that soclety would 'mdertake to provide · t.hose. benefits with th,;. alter·n ative meana. R9 Sinco tho project. may involve coJ.loctive goods, i .t. has been noted that the private sAC!tor would ·have never undertaken the proj~ct due to .l.t8 prohibitive costs. 2. CO" ts From a theoretical standpoint. costs are easier to compute than bonefits. It is not difficult·. 1.: 0 e .. timate how much it ,~ill cost to construct and . operate a treat.ment plant. But the major problem in estimating future costs consists in predicting the amount of pollution control and the effects of technological changes. 90 Thp. analyst needs i.nformation which will indicate the costs of industrial praco.sHs at each level ·. ~f effJ. uen~dischargo, · for such information isnecassary to the planning of water quality cont.r .ol fly·stems. 91 ilS The cost-benefit ra~ios can be altered by the costs · . included. . In many ratio~, indirect benefits are e~umerated, but indi.rect costs are excludod; t.hus givin'] a more favorable ratio. 92 B'lt ·the Corps of 1>.l Igineers, .accordin.,)" to ·some ·economists, is understatirtg its ratios by placing local contr:i.butions of cash, land, and easements on the aide of projed t co~ts instead of considering them as be nefits. 93 . Since the cost concept includes consideration of a.lternative costs, the agency may tend to ·disregard these 10wAr cost alternatives. In most cases, 3in .~~ ·I::lie federal water planning agancy is also involvec in th~ construction of projects, there is Hvid'3nce t.hat these agenci(~ s "re- biaaed in favor of ·alt.ernatives requiring construction. These ;;'9E"",1.eS are criticizf.'d for fa.i.Jing to consider measures not involVing con"t.1"'.lC·r:ion, ,;uch · as the ·regulation of a flood pla·in instead of a dam. Tn the area of wal·.er quality improvement, those agencies have neglected sunh alternatives as in-plant treatment or infrequent degradation · of water quality.94 The agency which d.isregards ·these alternative costs often ignores .the external.i.ties resulting from a project·, such as the soci",l costs .of ·taxation. ·The federal projects, of course, require funds which are obtained through taxation; i f the taxation is great, misallocations of resources may result, . 9C, . often as a consequence of inflation • . . These advserse effects rosul ting from taxation inay be minimi zed in projects which produce th~ir own revenues . In these projects, the costs arA confined to the amount borrowed from the government, so that the oretically tax cl.lts will result. 96 ·C. Forecasting The th~ory of cost-benefit analysis rests upon the assumption that future conditions can in some way be predicted with reasonable accuracy. The seC"!ondary benefits of a water project assume . that there will be " . suffici~nt demand for the goods and service.s prodti.ced • . Most studies involving project analysis rely upon the posulate that the demand for industrial anct municipal waste will i ·ncrease at a rate proportionate to population growth or economic change. Behind this assumption is the belief th.a t the . demand for water is inelastic, '.'hieh is incorrect according to economic theory.9"l Not only may the mf rkets disappear, but requil'ed inputs may become scarce, population patterns may change, operating .costs may increase, or com·p eting demands for land may intervene. Demand for a project in th,~ present may alao shift as a result of technological challges wh:l.cb render certain industrial proce'lses obsolete. 9 8 .. ., Influenced by future economic conditions, forecasting also involves speculation as to the useful life of a project and a discounting of the costs and benefits in order to arrive at the present value. An increase in the nominal life of a project has a considerable impact upon · the ratio if a low discount rate is used. 99 But the impor.tanee of the life ·of the project may be diminished by the practice of giving time per.iods in th .. future less importance than the present by means of the discount rate. lOO The selection of the d ~ scount rate requires speculation . . .. . 101 of future demand and technological changes. . Inmost government projects the discount rate ha s been the average rate 'a t which the government can borrow. which is usually between five and six per cent. This rate has been defHnded on the grolind that it is the social cost of capital and ill, the retul:1I realized' on capital invested in alternative uses. The rate is also supported as being realistic since the government is able , to bor.row at long tern, government bond r~tAs.I02 The use of this inlerest rale, however, han heen critir:::ized a:l (~xa'.:lgerating the value of a project by under' stating the costs which are ill<.lurred in the private 'sect:or ~s a rcsult of risks and corporate taxes. 103 The same project in the private s<)ctor, to be deemed effici e nt, wOllld require at least a lHn per cent discount rate. 104 Thu3, projects which are efficient in the public ucctor would be uneconomical if attempted hy private firnls, and as a result, there is a misal'location of resources. It has been argued that.]. discount rate based upon alternative costs would be a mo ,t'e accurate measure .105 The pI'oblBRt of discount rates is particularly acute in the de'lelopmoni: of willl3r resources. In most water projects majo,r i ty of expenses are incurr~d in th .. early yeac.l of project, and benefits are spread over a long period, twenty or fifty years. Thus, a low interest rate makes project seem favorable, while a high rate lowers the . e ff"l.Cl.ency . 0 f th e proJec . t • 101; r 1\ many proJects, . economl.C, lohe the say the the higher rates would not have caused the ratio' to result in a value less than unity, but it woulcfhave caused a decrease in the level off development or a considt!ration of ' . , 107 ot h er a 1. ternat1ves. IV. Recommp.ndations The theory of cost-benefit analysis is based upon the economic concepts of marginal costs and benefits, Which . have their normal application in market behavior. The limitations of ' using this economic theory as a rigid rule, ,without qualifications, must be recognized. lOB The necessity of value judgments will cause the costbenefit ratio to reflect the point of view of its analyst. AS.more consistent ' procedures are developed, the problem of bias will diminish" but the analysis should remain flexible enough to allow amendments if it proves unreliable. 109 And if a single ratio tends to be misleading, then the analysis ' could be prepared as a partial quantification with qualitative effects being stated in an addendum. , The end result of a cost-benefit analysis is a numerical , ratio. As noted above, the comparisons of the ratios , of two , projects will fail to take into account the relative costs of each project. 110 This misleading aspect of the analysis is ~liminated if the analyst assumes that capital resources are defined by, the federal budget. The purpose of ' cost-benefit analysis is to maximize the returns on public funds, so the , analysis ' shouldseperate capital costs fr'om operating costs and exclude these operatirigcosts. Ih this way, projects having the highest ratio will result in the maximum net 111 benefits. The absolute nature of the ratio must be subordinated to its relative economicevaluation. 112 Thus, when two projects are to be compared, there must be corresponding entries for each benefit and cost. The analysis ' can be prepared as a " .~ such procedure allows balance sheet with analagous entries; greater objectivity and accountability for value' judgments. The costs enumerated must be consistent ,with one another in , order to avoid "variations of capital intensity." f ' must also possess this same type of uniformity. Benefits And, lastly, the life span of the project must be approximately the same to avoid disparity in the ratios.11 3 ' ~f s~ch internal consistencies are maintained by the analyst , then the errors which result from economic measurements will be reflected in , all of the ratios for, a particular project and will produce greater uniformity. Even if the relative aspects of economic analy~is are stressed, the project finally chosen may fail to allocate resources in the most efficient manner. As a result, a seperate study of marginal net benefits must be made; the marginal net benefits of the project must be equal zero fpr the maximum benefits to be realized. At a certain point, a project has maximum benefits which will be decreased by a change in the size of the project, I.e. lowering or raising the height of a dam. This type of analysis has , been undertaken by the Corps of Engineers in studying the changes in navigation , channel depth. But in most instances the agencies, which favor construction, tend to build projects to utilize all available resources to the point where incremental costs greatly ou'tweigh benefits .114 ' The use of multi-purpose reservoirs has also become a dominant feature of water resource planning. ,And Yet i t i s often more efficient to locate a single purpose ~eservoir close to an urban area than to develop a multi-purpose reservoir further away from 11S those areas. The economic criterion provided by cost-benefit analysis serves well to justify projects as economically efficient, but it revea1s ' little about the subsequent effects of those projeCts. ,With a few alterations, ,an input-output analysis can provide a means for determinihg the effects of a project by placing waste disposal facHitteli jpn the input side. The effects on production as a result of these facilities can be , 116 noted, as ,well as the effects of alternative proposals. This input-output analysis points to the deficiency of the cost-benefit analysis in stressing increases in national income as its goal instead of stressing multiple objectives, such as the preservation of flowing water resources. ll ? The problem of forecasting future demands is an important factor in the anal~sis of any ~roject, and cost-benefit analysis should improve period analysis rather than develop new ideas 1 of what constitutes secondary benefits and costs. l 8 And since technology often renders a project ' obsolete, the analyst should eonsider alternative de~ign8 which allow , for these changes, such as less durable structures or general purpose designs which can be altered. 119 Discount rates determine present value, but the rates used fail to provide inf~rmation to begin a project. For the present year and several for determing the best year succeding y ears, an estimate of net benefits for each year should be made. If the estimates are then discounted to , the present year, the year which indicates the greatest amount of net benefits, or largest ratio, is the optimal ye ar to ' t he proJec ' t • 120 b eg1n The discount rate applied to federal projects has been underestimated, so the discount rate should include such factors as economic risk and corporate taxes, both of which are met by private developers. l2l since the public is taxe d to . provide funds fo.r these projects, the national income is maximize d only in those instances where a public project will be as good an investment as a private undertaking. l22 And frequenl:t:'Iy; as a result of this taxation, there is a shift in the distribution of ihcome. To avoid undue shifts to those in lower income groups, the estimate of the benefits should be measured in relation to those individuals with incomes close to the mean. Such a correction would tend to lower the ratio of projects · which serve primarily to benefit those in upper income l .e vels .123 .~ 1t The final effectiveness of any cost-benefit ratio, .. no matter how refined the economic procedures, depends upon the containment of political forces, which may override the determinations of the analysis and encourage the implementation of undesirable projects. l24 V. Conclusion Cost-bene fit analysis performs well as an indicator of economic efficiency. Problems are encountered when the analysis is used to compare different projects .; in which intangible benefits and costs are measured. Valu.e judgments must, of necessity, be made when the price system has failed to provide for many of the results of a federal project. These · value judgments lead to certain abuses ) . by the analyst. such as f ·ailure to consider alternatives with lower costs or alternatives more susceptible to changes in technology. Determining the technology of the future, as well as its market demands, requires pr·e dictions by the analyst, who needs this information to calculate the discount rate and the life of the · project. Again, the economic analysis needs refinement, but the: analyst must strive to avoid inflating the benefits. Furthermore, the destruction of the environment must be recognized as asocial cost, despite difficulties in quantification. In the field of water resources, the Proposed Standards have implemented a practical approach with specific examples of adverse effects, which should result in greater consistency among results. Until procedures are further refined, cost-benefit analysis must be recognized as what it is - economic theory. The analysis may not solve all problems in the water ' -resources field, but it does force the decisionmaker . to evaluate the project carefully with asystematic methodology. Footnotes lR. Leftwich, The Price System and Resource Allocation 9 (4th ed. 1970). 2 Id • at 335. 3For a discussion of least-cost combination, see R. Leftwich, The Price System and Resource Allocation 139-41 (4th ed. 1970). l29-~1, 40 . Eckstein, Water Resource Development 38-40 (1958), S. Nath, A Reappraisal of Welfare Economics 164 (1969). 5w• Ramsay & C. Anderson, Managing the Environment 86-87 (1972) • 6E • J. Mishan'; Cost-Benefit , Analysis 316 (1971). 7Id • at 316. 8 Id • at ,317. 9Note , Cost-Benefit Analysis and the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969, 24 Stan. L. Rev. 1092, 1099 (1972) • 10see generallyR. Leftwich, The Price System and Resource Allocation ' 195 (4th ed. 1970). . ), ilCiriacy-wantrup, Cost-Benefit Analysis and Public Resource Development,in Economics and Public Policy in Water Resource Development 12 (S. · Smith ed ~- · 1964). 12 J. Sax, Water Law: Planning and Policy, ', CaSes and M~terials 30 (1968). 13A• Reitze, Environmental ,Law Introduction-30 (1972). l4 Id • l5J- . Sax, ' Water Law: Planning and Policy, Cases and Materials 29-·30 (1968). 16Hammond, convention and Limitation in Benefit~ Cost Analysis, 6 Nat. Re"!!. J. 202 (1966). 17J~ Hi r shleifer, J. De Haven, & J. Milliman, Water Supply 137 (1960). 18 J. Sax, Water Law: Planning and Policy, Cases and Materials 30 (1968). 19Note , Cost-Benefit Analysis and the National Environmental ~olicy Act of 1969, 24 Stan . L. Rev. 1092, li91 (1972). 20 " For a discussion of the applicability of these methods, see O. Eckstein, Water Resources Development 65-69 (1958). 21proposed Practices for Economic Analysis of River Ilasin Projects, Report of the Subcommittee on Evaluation Standards to the Inter-Agency Committee on Water "Resources (1958). 22 Id • 23ciriacy-wantrup, Cost-Benefit Analysis and Public Resource Deve lopment, in Economics and Public policy in Water Resource Developmen~ 15-17 (s. Smith ed. 1964). 24 Id. at 12. 25 E • J • Mishan, Cost-Benefit Analysis 316 (1971). . 26 J • Hirshleifer, J. De Haven, & J. Milliman, Water Supply 86-87 (1960). ) 27 M• Spe ncer, Contemporary Economics 361 (1971). S"pencer gloves this sJ.mplified example "of alternative costs: To a student, the cost of getting a full time college education includes not only his outlay costs, i.e. costs for tuition and books, but also the income he fore"goes by not working full time. 28 R . " Leftwich! The Price System and Resource Allocation 144 (4th ed. 1970). " 29 See generally Leontief, JThe Review of Economics and Statistics 262~69 (1970). 30 . Other uses of input-output tables include the establishment of priorities in environmental polici, the impact of ecological technology on economic and ecological systems in general, and the measurement of alternative costs in a particular ecological stabilization system. W. Ramsay & C •. Anderson, Managing the Environment 80-81 (1972). 31 0 • Eckstein, Water Resources Development 52-53 (1958). 321'1. Ramsay & C. Anderson, Managing the Environment 85-86 (1972). ·33 The economic theory involved in externalities is discussed in R. Leftwich, The Price System and Resource Allocation 195 (4th ed. 1970). 341'1. Ramsay & C. Anderson, Managing the Environment 88-89 (1972) . 35E.J.Mishan, Cost-Benefit Analysis 102 (1971). 36For a discussion of early statutes and decisions which employed .what · amounted to cost-benefit analysis, see Tre1ease, Policies for Water Law: Property Rights, Economic Forces, and Pub1io Regulation, 5 Nat. Res. ,J. 1, 17-18 (1965). 37 Act of June 22, 1936, Pub. LI, 1.No. 74-738,49 Stat. 1570. 38 Id • 390 • Eckstein, Water Resource Development 47-48 (1958). 40proposed Practices for Economic Analysis of River Basin Projects, Report of the Subcommittee ' on Evaluation Standards to the Inter-Agency Committee ,on Water Resources '(1958) . 41Water Resources Council, Policies, Standards, and Procedures in the FormulatIon, EvaluatIon, and Review of Plans for Use and Development of Water and Related Land . Resources, S.Doc. No. 97, 87thCong., 2dSess. (1962). [hereinafter re'ferred to as Senate Document 97) 42 Id . , at 8-9. 43 Id • at 10. 44 Id • at 7. 45 Fcilz ,' .Public and Private Investment in Resources Development, in Land and Water, Use 333-34 (W. Thorne ed. i 1963) • . 46 Proposed Principles and Standards for Planning Water and Related Land Resources, 36 Fed. Reg. 24144 (1971). (hereinafter referred to asPrciposed Standards) 47 Id • at 24160. 48 Id • at 24167. 49. Id • at 24166. 50National Environmental . Policy Act, 42 U.S .C. ~ 4332 (1969) • , 51 H.R. Rep. No. 91-378, 91st Cong., 1st Sess. 2751, 2760 (1969) • , .. S2 CEQ Gliidelines, 36 Fed. Reg. 7723 (1971). 53 Id • at 7724. 54Environmental Protection Age99¥' Environmental Impa c t Statements, Procedures for Preparation, 37 Fed. Reg. 883 (1972) • 55 . EDF v. Corps of Engineers, 470 F.2d 289, 300(8th Cir. 1972); Calvert Cliffs' Coordinating Comm. v. United States A.E.C., 449 F.2d . 1109, 1115 (D.C. Cir. 1971). 56sierra Club v. Froehlke, 359 F. Supp. 1289 (S.D, Tex. 1973) • 57 Id • at 1365. 58 Id • at 1368 • . 59 Id .' at 1369. 60 R • Leftwich, The Price Syatem and Resource Allocation '195 ' (4th ed. 1970); Ciriacy~Wantrup, Cost-Benefit Analysis and P,ublic Resource Development, in Economics and Public Policy in Wat.er Resource Development 12 (s. Smith ed. 1964). 61The effects ofbadgetary restraint are discussed in O. Ecksteiri, Water Resource Development 70-80 (1958). 62 R. Hav e man, Water Resource Investment and the Public Interest 98 (1965). 63 0 • Eckstein~ , Water Resource Development 62-63 (1958). 64Hammond, Convention and Limitation in Benefit-Cost Anal¥.si s , 6 Nat. 65Freeman, Re~. J. 195, 202 (1966'). Dis~ribution of Environmental Quality, in Environmental Quality" Analysis 248 (A. Kneese & B. Bower ' ed. 1972). 66Kneese, Economic and Related Problems in Contemporary Water Resources Management,S Nat. Res. J. 236, 237 (1965). 67 Bohm , A Note on the Problem of Estimating Benefits ,from Pollution Control, in Problems of Environmental Economics 85 (1972). 6BNote , Cost-Benefit Analysis and the National Environmental Policy Act 'of 1969, 24 Stan. L. Rev. 1092, 1104 (1972). 69coddington, Some Limitation ~ bf Benefit-Cost Analysis in 'Respect of Program.mes witl! Environmental Consequences, in Problems of Environmental Economics ' 120 (1972). 70Trelease, Policies for Water Law: Property Rights, Economic Forces. and Public Regulations,S Nat. Res; J. 1. 12 (196 5) . 71 ' W. Ramsay & C. Anderson, Managing the Environment 73 (1972). 72See Boulding, The Basis of Value Judgments in Economics, in Human Values and Economic Policy 64-71 (s. Hook ed. 1967). 73 Bohm , A Note on the Problem of Estimating Benefits from Pollution Control, . in Problems of Environmental Economics 85 (1972). 74 . O. Eckstein, Water Resource Development 50-51 (1958). ' . 75 C ~r~acy-Wantrup, . Cost-Benef~t Analys i s and Public mesource Devclopment, in Economics and Public Policy in .Water RGsource Development 11 (S. Sm~th ed. 1964). 76Assuming, of course, that long t<;lrm total costs are lower than short term average total costs. 77 LaVe, . A~r ' Po.1 1 ut~on Damage: Some . ff~cult~es ' . . ~n D~ Estimating the Value of Abatement, in Environmental Quality Analysis 238 (A. Kneese & B. Bower ed. 1972). 78The "with and without" principle refers to the procedure in which the project is analyzed in terms of economic change after the project has been completed and in the situation existing if the project was never constructed. See O. Eckstein, Water Resource Development 51-52 (1958). 79 O. . Ec k ste~n, . Water Resource Deve lopment 52-53 (1 958. ) 80Kneese, Ec onomic and Related . Problems in Contemporary Water Resources I~anagement, 81 A.Fre e man. R. 5 Nat •. Res. J. 236, 246 (1965). & A. Kneese. The Economics of Environmcnt<0. Pohcy 109 (1973). ." ,~ Haveman~ 82Harnrnond. Convention and Limitation in Benefit-Cost Analysis, 6 Nat. Res. J. 195, 212-13 (1966). 83 J. . H~rs hI' e~ f er. J. De Haven, & J. Milliman. Water Supply 162 (1960). 84 Kneese, . Econom~c d P ro . bl ems ~n . Con temporary an d Reiate Water Resources Management, 5 Nat. Res. J. 236, 242 (1965). 8S A • Reitze, Environmental Law Introduction-30 (1972), Interagency Committee on Water Resources, H.R. Doc. No. 276. App. V (1965). 86Kneese, Economic and Related Problems in Contemporary Water Resour c es Management, 5 Nat. Res. J. 236; 2 42- 4 3 (1965). 87 S~erra ' ' C1 u b v. Froehkle, 359 F. Supp. 1289, 1379 (S.D. Tex. 1973); EDF v. Corps of Engineers, 325 F. Supp. 749, 759 (E.D. Ark. 1971). 88 ' Tolley, Future Economic Research on Western River Resources - Wi th Particular Reference to, California, 5 Nat. Res. J. 259 :, 271-72 (1968). 89 Note , Cost-Benefit Analysis and the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969, 24 Stan. L. Rev. 1092, l.105 (1972). 90 A. Freeman, R. Haveman, & A. Kneese, The Economics of Environmental Policy 10 (1973). 91Kneese, Economics and Related Problems in Contemporary Water Resources Management, 5 Nat. Res. J. 236, 246 (1965). 92Harnrnond, Convention and Limitation in Benefit-Cost Analysis, 6 Nat. Res. J. 195, 212 (1966). 93 0 . Eckstein, Water Resource Development 65 (1958). 94 Fox , Efficiency in the Use of Natural Resources: Attainment of Efficiency in Satisfying Demands for Water Resources, in American Economic Review 190; 201, 205 (May, 1964) • 95 0 . Eckstein, Water Resource Development 49 (1958). 96 Id. , at 50. 97 F,o x, Efficiency in the Use of Natural Resources': Attainment of Efficiency in Satisfying Demands for Water Resources, in American Economic Review 190, 201, 205 (May, 1964) • 98 J . Hirsh1eifer. J. De Haven, & J. Milliman, Water Supply 160 (1960). 99 ' Fox, Eff'ici e ncy in the Use 'of Natural Resources: Attainment of Efficiency in Satisfying Demands for Water Resources, in 1964) • ~erican Economic Review 190, 201, 205 (May, lOOJ. Hirshleifer, J. De Haven, & J. Milliman, Water Supply 160 (1960). 101Fox, Efficiency in the Use ' of Natural Resources: Attainment of Efficiency in Satisfying Demands for Water Resources, in American Economic Review 190, 201, 205, (May, 1964) • 102R . Haveman, Water Resour'c e Investmen,t and the Public Interest 9B-99 (1965). 103Hammond, Convention and Limitation in Benefit-Cost Analysis, 6 Nat. Res. J. 195, 211 (1966). 104 J . Hirshleifer, De Haven, & J. Milliman, Water Supply 160 (1960). 105 . , Hammond, Conventl.on and Limitation in Benefit-Cost Analysis, 6 Nat. Res. J. 1.95, 211 (1966). 106 J . H ' ~rs , hl e1' f ar,' J . De Haven, & J; ' Milliman, Water Supply 160 (1960). 107 F ox, Efficiency in the Use of Natural Resources: Attainment of Efficiency in Satisfying Demands for Water Resources, in American Economic Review 190, 201,205 (May 1964) • 10BHammond, Convention and Limitation in Benefit-Cost Analysis" 6 Nat. Res. J. 195, 201 ,<:1.\966) • 109 Id • at 214. 110For the view that the relative factors of projects will remain the same, despite errors in forecasting, seeO. Eckstein, Water Resource Development 50 (1958). lllHammond, Convention and Limitation in Benefit-Cost Analysis, 6 Nat. Res. J. 195, 202 (1966). 112 0 • Eckstein, Water Resource Development 50 (195B). 113 Id • at 55. 114 J • H!.rshleifer, J. De Haven, & ,J. Milliman, Water Supply 160 (1960). l15Kneese, Economic and Related' Problems in Contemporary Water Resources Management, 5 Nat. Res. J. 236, 242-243 (1965) • l16coddington, Some Limitations of Benefit-Cost Analysis in Re spect of Programmes with Environmental Consequences, in Problems of Environmental Economics 121 (197,2). l17 R . Have man, Water Resource Investment and the Public Intere st 98 (1965). ll8Ciriacy-wantrup, Fast-Benefit Analysis and Public Resource Dev e lopme nt, ~n Economics and Public Policy in Water Resource Developme nt 18 (S. Smith ed. 1964). 119 p ox, Efficiency in the Use of Natural Resources: Attainment of Effi6iency in Satisfying Demands for Water Resources, ' in American Economic Review 190, 201, 205 (May 1964) . l20Tolley, Purure E60nomic Research on Western River Resources - With Particular Reference to ' California, 5 Nat. , Res. J. 259, 271 (1968). l21 J • Hirshleif e r, J. 'De Haven, & J. Milliman, Water Supply 160-61 (1960). l22 R • Haveman, Water Resource Ihvkstment and the Public Inter e st 101 (1965). 123preeman, Distribution of Environmental Quality, in Environmental Quality Analysis 248-49 (A. Kneese & B. Bower ed. 1972). 124p o 1 z, Public and Private Investment in Resources Development, in Land and Water Use 334 (W. Thorne ed. 1963).