The Society for Japanese Studies Leader or Strategic Follower: What Role for the Japanese State? Japan's Capitalism: Creative Defeat and beyond by Shigeto Tsuru; Strategic Capitalism: Private Business and Public Purpose in Japanese Industrial Finance by Kent E. Calder; The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy Review by: John Zysman and Eileen M. Doherty Journal of Japanese Studies, Vol. 22, No. 1 (Winter, 1996), pp. 234-245 Published by: The Society for Japanese Studies Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/133074 . Accessed: 26/02/2014 05:09 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . The Society for Japanese Studies is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Japanese Studies. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 234 Journalof JapaneseStudies 22:1 (1996) Whatis missing from the picturehere is some analysis of news content on key topics. The book relatesthe patternsof interactionbetweenreporters and politicians without demonstratingexactly what sort of reportingthis interactionproducedon key subjects such as corruption,elections, or new taxes. The authorcollected a wealth of data to provide the clearestpicture yet of the relationshipsbetween Diet membersand newspaperpeople, but the book doesn'tlink these relationshipsadequatelyto newspapercoverage of specific issues. The characterizationseems abstractin parts,not relating concretelythe impactof the relationshipsthatthe book documentsso well. The challengethatremainsis to integratethe patternsof interactionbetween reportersand politicianswith the substanceof political news stories. What the book omits is far less noteworthythan what it offers. Despite the paucityof anecdotes(the authoris carefulto protecthis sources),readers will come away with the feeling thatthey have looked over the shouldersof some of Japan'smost importantpolitical actors as they went about their work. The author'spainstakingresearchhas producedan intimateinsider's accountof the process of political reporting.The only majorplayersto remain out of sharpfocus were Japan'sbureaucrats,who are evidently less prone than conservativepoliticians to bare their operationsto the prying eyes of the press or foreign scholars. LEADEROR STRATEGICFOLLOWER: WHATROLEFOR THE JAPANESESTATE? Japan's Capitalism:CreativeDefeat and Beyond.By Shigeto Tsuru.CambridgeUniversityPress,New York,1993. xii, 277 pages. Strategic Capitalism:Private Business and Public Purpose in JapaneseIndustrialFinance. By KentE. Calder.PrincetonUniversityPress,Princeton, 1993. xxii, 373 pages. $35.00. TheEast Asian Miracle: EconomicGrowthand Public Policy. OxfordUniversityPress,New York,1993. xvii, 389 pages. $19.95. Reviewedby JOHN ZYSMAN AND EILEEN M. DOHERTY Universityof California,Berkeley Those interestedin the Japanesepolitical economy must answerfor themselves threequestions.First,what model does one hold aboutthe operations This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ReviewSection 235 of the Japanesepolitical economy at the apex of its high-growthera? The demarcationsof thatera are admittedlyfuzzy; nonetheless,studentsof contemporaryJapanmust have a baselineby which to compareJapan'spolitical economy duringits developmentalheydaywith thatof today.One reference point is the perioduntil roughly 1975, before Japanbegan to loosen its tight capitalcontrols,therebydismantlingsome formalinstrumentsof protection. The model must depict the criticalinstitutionsandpolicies thatdefineda set of constraintsand possibilities for the centraleconomic actors.It must identify the "marketlogic" ' that emerged from the interplayof actors as they respondedto that set of incentivesand constraints.The growthmodel must also demonstratehow the costs and benefits of growth, the pain and gain, were allocated.How were the losers kept frominterferingwith the processes of development?If they were compensatedor insulated,then how were the marketincentives for winners kept sufficientlystrong to generatenew economic activities, firms,and sectors? Second, with that baseline in mind, how substantiallyhas the market logic that characterizedthe pre-1970s period changed? Certainly,formal governmentregulationshave been loosened in Japan.More recently,the rise in the value of the yen has drivenproducersto reorganizeproductionwith significantoperationsoutside Japan.Japaneseimportshave also increased. Yet for the most part, Japan'stightly woven supply networks seem to be firmly in place. Japaneseinstitutionsand practices have certainly evolved since the developmentalheydaybaseline,but which changes aresignificant? Third,how extensively does the story of Japaninterminglewith that of the rest of Asia? Until recently,Asia was neithera significantmarketnor a significant source of components and subsystems for Japanese firms. Increasingly, it has become both. What does the development of the Asian marketimply for Japan'seconomic and political arrangements?And what does Japan'seconomic success imply for the rest of Asia? Japan's Capitalism addresses the first of our three questions head-on and presents an exceptionally valuable discussion of the creation of the postwar Japaneseeconomic system, how its critical mechanisms worked, and the marketdynamics that resulted. Shigeto Tsuru,formerpresidentof the InternationalEconomic Association and professoremeritusof Hitotsubashi University, was also vice-minister of the Economic Stabilization Board in the immediate postwar years. He does a masterfuljob of combining the insight of an insider with the analytic tools of an academic professional. Standingout in Tsuru'sstory of the reconstitutionof postwarJapanis the influence of the U.S. government,which was determinedto rebuildJa1. See John Zysman, "How Institutions Create Historically Rooted Trajectories of Growth,"Industrialand CorporateChange, Vol. 3, No. 1 (1994). This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 236 Journalof JapaneseStudies 22:1 (1996) pan as the "workshopof Asia" to standagainstcommunismin the region. Equallyapparentis U.S. naivete.For example,the decision to apply American civil service rules to traditionalJapanese institutions reinforced the power of the elite bureaucrats,an ironic turn given the powerful influence that bureaucratic"administrativeguidance" played in Japan'spostwarindustrial growth. Similarly,with regardto exchange-ratedecisions, Tsuru remindsus that althoughthe yen/dollarrate was bound to be very low, the exceptionallylow valuationof the yen was an Americandecision. ThatundervaluationamplifiedJapan'sindustrialdevelopment. Tsuru'sanalysis of rapidgrowthincludes, of course, a discussion of Japan's high saving rates. But he pushes beyond the ritualisticto ask other basic questions.Whatwere the majorsourcesof demandthatwarrantedthe high rate of growth?Whatwas the role playedby the governmentto stimulate growth? What were the implications of postwar changes for Japan's industrialstructure?What was the evolution and consequence of business organizationalstructures?And what was the role of exports in drivingJapan'sgrowth?The result is an argumentabout the critical role of exports, combinedwith domestic competitionin an insulatedmarket,in creatinginternationallycompetitivemanufacturersin a series of sectors. Tsuru'smost valuablecontributionis that he discusses throughthe sophisticatedeyes of a Japanesegovernmentinsiderthe criticalinstitutionsof the economy and theirinterplay.For instance,he tracesthe recreationof the zaibatsu system (note that he uses the term zaibatsu ratherthan the less loaded postwarterm keiretsu)but emphasizesthe emergence of the "oneset" principle by which each corporategroup established a firm in each majorsector.Before the war,the majorzaibatsuwere specialized and hesitated to launchnew industrialventures.The one-set principleprompteddiversificationin the keiretsu,with banksas the majorsourceof medium-and long-termfinancefor industries.This sparkeda distinctivepatternof competition. Groupscompeted with each other by vigorously pursuingmarket share.The result was overinvestmentand excess capacity,followed by the developmentof governmentstrategiesto managecompetition. Using the story of the sewing machineindustry,a firstinstanceof "targeting," Tsuru suggests how distinctive features of Japanese industry emerged.Governmentsubsidies-aimed both at assuringadvancedproduction technology and at supportingexports-created a distinctivedynamic of domestic competition and aggressive exports in that sector: "Japanese governmentofficials assisted and backed the sewing machine industry at every step of this process to become virtually the first successful export industryin the postwaryears" (p. 81). In reviewing other sectors that became export staples-steel, autos, ships-Tsuru concludes that "we find thatthe basic elementin the success storyof the sewing machineindustrynamely how paternalisticadministrativeguidance enabled it to strike a This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Review Section 237 happy balance between competition at home and governmentsupportfor sales abroad .... was essentially repeatedin the leading industriestoo" (p. 82). At the core of governmentaction was a policy of administrativeguidance. According to Tsuru,the ability of the governmentto direct or induce privatefirms or persons to take or refrainfrom taking certain actions has been a "more widely accepted and solidly established feature of government administrationthan in other countries" (p. 97). Tsuru discusses several of the administrativemechanismsused: privilegedfinance,tax arrangements, infrastructureinvestment, land reclamation, and even selective allocation of sugarquotas as a means of supplementaryfinance. "Window guidance" was the monetary arm of administrativeguidance: a series of financial controls, incentives such as low-interest finance, and informal "suggestions"by the Bank of Japandesigned to channel domestic savings into industrialinvestments.In the end, Tsuru shows us all the pieces of a system of protectionand promotionthat created massive productioninnovation and internationallycompetitiveindustries. Not surprisingly,the strongest part of the book is the section on the immediatepostwarperiod. The nuanceddiscussion of the reforms,political debates, and decision-makingprocesses during the Occupationand highgrowth years provides us with a rich understandingof the forces that produced the institutional foundations of modern Japan. Tsuru's aim shifts slightly in his discussionof Japan'shistorysince the 1972 oil crisis. Because his goal is to demonstratethe social problemsinherentin Japanesecapitalism, he devotes somewhat less attention to historical details and more to economic argumentsaboutthe welfare effects of high growthand the "pitfalls of affluence." Consequently,the book sheds little light on the specific ways Japanhas changed since the high-growth era. The Japanese system has evolved, pressedby oil shocks, land-priceinflation,corporateprofits,financialscandals, and multiple yen appreciations.Although Tsuru touches on all these factors,those interestedin understandingchanges in the way Japan'sindustrial structureand political institutionsshape economic outcomes must look elsewhere for theiranswers. Strategic Capitalism:Private Business and Public Purpose in Japanese Industrial Finance, by Kent Calder, also focuses overwhelmingly on the firstquestionwe outlined:How did Japan'seconomy work duringthe highgrowth era? Calderpresentsa radicallydifferentpictureof the logic of the developmentalheyday.His focus is on the fracturesinside the Japaneseindustrialpolicymakingsystem and the autonomousstrategiccapacity of the privatesector in drivingthe creationof new sectors. Using credit allocation as his lens into public/privaterelations, he argues that the capacity of the stateto strategicallyallocatecapitalhas been constrainedby rivalrieswithin This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 238 Journalof JapaneseStudies 22:1 (1996) the state and "by the natureof the private sector, the influence of party politicians,and occasionallyby foreign actors"(p. 14). On the whole, "industrial strategists within the governmenthave lacked the wide-ranging ability to shapethe financialsystem to theirvision of priorities"(p. 14). It is not thatJapanis a liberalmarketeconomy,arguesCalder,but rather thatthe capacityfor strategyanddirectionlies in "a formidableanddistinctive set of private-sectorinstitutions," especially in the financial sector (p. 16). Japan'seconomic success rests on a public-privatesystem that is predominantlydrivenby private-sectordecisions. In this simple form, and as a correctiveto the sometimesoverdrawnpopularargumentsthatthe Japanese governmentcan simply impose outcomes on domestic and international markets,this book is useful. But the real question must be whether Calderprovidesa convincing argumentregardingthe extent of government influence.Here, analyticdifficultiesemerge. Calder's argument rests on the distinction between "strategy" and "regulation."Governmentrivalries exist between the strategists (in this story essentially the Ministry of InternationalTrade and Industry[MITI]) and the regulatoryministries (in this story essentially the Ministry of Finance [MOF]). MITI has the visions; MOF has the tools but a regulatory bias of maintainingfinancialstability.Calderarguesthat the strategistsare institutionallyconstrainedin theirattemptsto directpolicy outcomes. However,the distinctionbetweenstrategyandregulationis farless clear thanCaldersuggests. Regulatorydecisions and structuresoften reflectgovernmentpurposesbeyond maintainingmarketstability.More importantly, when ministries are responsiblefor regulatingthe industriesthey nurture, "strategic"goals (such as protectionor industrysupport)are impossible to separatefrom regulatoryfunctions.The Ministryof Post and Telecommunications is at once regulatorand promoterof Japan'stelecommunications industry.2The Ministry of Health, which includes the Japaneseequivalent to the U.S. Food and Drug Administration,has regulatorygoals that intermingle with the purposesof promotingthe interestsof the pharmaceutical industry.The fact that MOF is a regulatoryagency does not mean it lacks strategicpurposesor will not workto facilitatethe purposesof others.There are many mechanismsfor assuring the integrity of the financial markets. Differentmechanismshave differentobjectives. In addition to analyticalproblems such as the strategy/regulationdistinction, Calder'sanalysis suffersfrom his exclusive focus on creditallocation. Administrativeguidancethroughfinanceis not simply a matterof the 2. See ChalmersJohnson,"MITI,MPT,andthe Telecom Wars:How JapanMakesPolicy for High Technology,"in ChalmersJohnson,LauraTyson, and John Zysman, eds., Politics and Productivity:The Real Story of WhyJapan Works(Cambridge,Mass.: Ballinger, 1989). This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Review Section 239 initial allocation of loans. Mechanisms also exist that allow government actorsto micro-managecrisis situationsfor troubledbanks.The handlingof the thirdworld debt crisis revealedsuch mechanisms;the currenteconomic crisis reemphasizesthem. These mechanismsgenerateenormous influence for governmentactors. They often also requireMOF to accommodateand strike bargainswith other ministries.The point is that administrativeguidance goes deeper than mere credit allocation decisions and is not always characterizedby bureaucraticrivalry.Ministerialcooperationalongside rivalry is an importantcharacteristicof Japan'spolitical economy. The importanceof those interministerialarrangementsis not reflected in Calder'sdiscussion of Japan's"Bankers'Kingdom." Calder argues that the structureof Japan'sfinancial system during the high-growth era was characterizedby the predominanceof indirect financing that made bank loans the majorform of corporatefinance, domestic interestrate controls, controls on exchange rates, an imbalance of liquidity between city banks and otherpartsof the financialsystem, overlendingfrom the Bank of Japan to city banks, and a bifurcatedsystem of privatefinancial intermediaries, with city banks lending to large firms and local banks to small firms (p. 136). The result, he argues,was a centraland influentialrole for private financialinstitutions:a bankers'kingdom. Perhaps.But while Japanmay have been a bankers' kingdom, it was also an industrialdevelopmentheaven. MOF regulationscreatedchannels and mechanismsthat assuredboth high, stable marginsfor banks and lowcost, long-term investmentfunds to the industrialsector over several generations.The bankers'kingdom was characterizedby channels that linked undercompensatedsavings to underpricedindustrialinvestment;these were nonmarketmechanisms operating with administeredprices. The array of interministerialdecisions linking finance and industrialdevelopmentwere elements in the reciprocalbargainsthatcharacterizeJapan. If we focus our analysis on regulatorypurposes and the interaction among ministries, we come to a very different conclusion than Calder, a conclusion consistent with Tsuru'shistory. The assuranceof readily available industrial finance through the regulation of the financial system amountedto a crucialnationalstrategicdecision. A distinctindustriallogic emerged from this combination of readily available low-cost capital, the assuranceof bankingprofits,and the managementof industrialrisk so that lending losses would not disrupteither the financial system or particular financial houses. Japanesefirms were able to pursue aggressive strategies aimed at capturingmarket share precisely because they had implicit and explicit governmentassurancesthat the risks of these strategies would be muted.As Tsurunotes, the structureof industrialfinancehad a logical consequence:excess capacityas a result of the rivalryof industrialgroups and This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 240 Journalof JapaneseStudies 22:1 (1996) theirbankingallies. That excess capacitypressed firms towardproduction innovation in order to gain new marketshare and to remain competitive. Excess capacity also encouragedthe emergenceof mechanismsto support aggressiveexporttactics. Another difficulty emerges from Calder's assertion that government spendingon infrastructureand traditionalsectors is evidence that the strategic focus of lendingwas limited.Therearetwo problemswith this conclusion. One is an "accounting"issue; the otheris one of politics. First,many of the categories of funds dismissed as nonindustrialcategories are in fact used to supportindustrialventures,and not just in Japan.When the French built seaside steel complexes in the north and south of the country,enormous investments in land reclamation,urban development, and rail and other transportlinks had to be made at the same time. Those were hugely expensive public investments.Similarinvestmentswere made for the Disney complex outside Paris. A similarargumentcan obviously be made for Japan. Second, and as important,is the political story of how the promotionof rapid industrialgrowth was politically sustained.Economic development always implies social dislocations.Unless those who aredislocatedand disadvantagedare bought off and co-opted throughcompensation(or simply beaten politically), an endless series of conflicts and disputes will disrupt the market.The policy trickis to containoppositionbut not to subsidizethe losers to such an extent that positive marketsignals are muted.We cannot dismiss the funding of the declining sectors as simple captureor as lack of strategicpurpose.Before acceptingCalder'sargumentthatfundingto infrastructureandtraditionalstructuresreflectsthefailure of strategicability,we must be able to identify Japan'smechanisms for allocating the pains and gains of growth.As the governmentattemptedto managethe politicalproblems associated with economic winners and losers, what was the place of financialinstruments,bureaucraticaction, and political agreements? In sum, Calderprovidesa richerand more complex pictureof the actors in the Japaneseindustrialfinance system, emphasizingtheirrivalryand the significantinfluenceof private-sectoractorsin shapingeconomic outcomes. What is missing, though, is a sense of the politics in which the story is embedded.How did the marketdynamicevolve over the years?Partof this omission is a conscious choice by Calder,who deliberatelyavoids writinga chronologicalaccountof Japaneseindustrialfinance:"A chronologicalapproachcould not presenta succinctcritiqueof the developmental-statecon3. For an interestingversion of this line of argument,see YasusukeMurakami,"Toward a Sociocultural Explanationof Japan'sEconomic Performance,"in Kozo Yamamura,ed., Policy and Trade Issues of the Japanese Economy: American and Japanese Perspectives (Seattle:Universityof WashingtonPress, 1982). This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ReviewSection 241 cept. Such treatmentwould simply yield the unexceptionalconclusion that the Japanesestate is slowly losing control capabilitiesover time. The more fundamentalpoint is ... the surprisinglyreactivecharacterof the Japanese state and the contrastingactivism of its privatesector at any point in time" (p. 17). Yet the conclusion thatthe Japanesestate is slowly losing control is not "unexceptional,"as Calderclaims. It is clearly truethatthe dynamicsof the Japanesefinancialsystem have evolved. But other authors,such as Steven Vogel, have contendedthat the supposedfinancialderegulationhid a more fundamentalreregulationthat reassertedbureaucraticpower ratherthan a loss of governmentalcontrol.4As in the Tsuru volume, there are elements of change in Calder,but we cannot from his book derive a new model to understandhow Japan'sfinancegame now operates. More fundamentally,the book does not fully succeed in its primary goal: demonstratingthe reactive characterof the Japanese state. In his specific case discussions, Caldernotes a broadrange of instances in which governmentdid act and act powerfully-despite his argumentthat privatesector actors were the primarycatalysts for change. In the end, the reader cannot really assess from this account the role of the governmentin influencing privateactorsor in setting the terms on which the financialmarkets induced industrial behavior. It is not simply particularactions-assessments of whetherthe governmentdid this or that-that matter.Rather,it is the structureof incentives and constraintsthat induced particularnational marketlogics. By asking narrowlywhich actorswere makingparticulardecisions, Calderseems not to capturethe characterand dynamicsof strategic competitionwithin Japanand then in world markets. It is the interplayof choice that is so powerful. If we adjust the story Caldertells for the types of concerns outlinedabove-such as the real successes of interventionnoted even in this book, the mixed packages of government aid that obscured the accounting of industrialvs. non-industrial aid, the fact that limited intervention can powerfully affect corporate strategy, and the reality of promotion within a regulatory agency-we emerge with a very differentpictureof the government'srole in industrial development.We come back to a picture,albeit one taken from a different angle, of a developmentaleconomic strategyfilled with reciprocalconsent by governmentand privateplayers. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growthand Public Policy was pre4. See Steven K. Vogel, "The BureaucraticApproachto the FinancialRevolution:Japan's Ministryof Financeand FinancialSystem Reform," Governance:An InternationalJournalof Policy and Administration,Vol. 7, No. 3 (July 1994), and Freer Markets,More Rules: The Paradoxical Politics of RegulatoryReformin the AdvancedIndustrialCountries(Ithaca:Cornell UniversityPress, 1996). This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 242 Journalof Japanese Studies 22:1 (1996) pared for the World Bank by a researchteam led by John Page (and supported at least in part by the Governmentof Japan).The book speaks directly to the third question outlined at the beginning of this article: How does Japan'sstory interminglewith the stories of other Asian countries?It is a significantcontributionto broaderdebatesaboutthe role of government interventionin economic development. For too long there has been a cartoon-like debate in which one set of scholars attributedAsian economic growth to strong governmentinterventions, while another group of scholars claimed that growth occurred despite those interventions.That in turn encouragedsome analysts to reconsider the interventionsand conclude that either they had not happened or did not matter. The East Asian Miracle reopens these debates in a more sophisticatedmanner.Although the book suffers from inconsistencies and occasional contradictions (due perhaps to multiple authorship or perhaps to political compromises made at the World Bank during its writing), it stands as a landmarkin the policy debates on developmental economics. The book examines eight "high performing Asian economies" (HPAEs):Japan,Hong Kong, the Republic of Korea, Singapore,Taiwan, Indonesia,Malaysia,and Thailand.Its task is to outline the causes of rapid economic growth in these eight countries, which have since 1960 grown more than twice as fast as the rest of East Asia and three times fasterthan Latin America and South Asia. The report argues that the success of the HPAEsrestedon two factors.First,the countries"got the basics right"with sound macroeconomicpolicies, high levels of saving and domestic investment, andexpandinghumancapital.Second, governmentspursuedselective interventionsin three broad areas:industrialpromotion,mild financialrepression,and export promotion. TheEast Asian Miracle is clearin its conclusionthat "gettingthe basics right" was the single most importantfactor in permittingAsian economic growth.It is less consistentin its assessmentof governmentintervention.In parts,the tone is positive, suggesting that carefulinterventionswere useful complements to sound macroeconomicpolicies. In other parts, it takes a more skepticaltone regardingthe wisdom of marketinterventions. Given the fact thatthe final version of the book was a political compromise, it is perhapsfittingthatthe book's primarycontributionis also political. The East Asian Miracle has succeeded in introducingindustrialpolicy as a legitimateareaof inquiryin the policy community.Accordingto Japan Overseas Economic Cooperation Fund Vice President Masaki Shiratori (who was one of the most vigorous campaignersfor the World Bank to conductthe survey):"TheWorldBank is still dominatedby neo-classicists. But I see a very tiny change. When I was at the Bank Board, and when young Japanese economists tried to talk about subjects such as directed This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ReviewSection 243 credit or industrialpolicy, they were put down. Now they can openly talk aboutthe replicationor applicationof these policies."5 Consequently,even the lukewarmconclusions of the book are revolutionaryin theirattemptto bridgediscussionsof differentnationaleconomies with analyticstudies of growth.While the researchteam emphasizes,properly, the broad macroeconomicconditions of saving, investment, and the creationof humancapital,the volume lays out a foundationby which very different analytical traditions may begin to speak to each other. A few themes merit commenthere. First, the volume begins to approachthe notion that a particularmix of policies and institutionscan create a marketdynamic. But the authorsstop short. For example, the volume acknowledges that most HPAEs began industrializationwith protectionistpolicies (althoughthe authorsalso stress that most have also graduallyembracedmarket-openingpolicies). During the high-growthera, participationin export marketspushed firms toward greaterefficiency,while domestic protectionsimultaneouslyinsulatedthem. According to the WorldBank study, these "mixed trade regimes" created offsetting differences in the prices of exports and local goods: "Export prices were set in the internationalmarketand were often substantiallyless than currentmarginalor averagecosts. Losses on export productionoffset profitsin the protectedmarket,while competition in the internationalmarket ensured that the firm would not suffer from loss of cost discipline" (p. 295). In a mathematicalsense, the combinationof export subsidies and protection/domesticpromotion may have resulted in relative price neutrality. But constructedneutralityand virgin neutrality are not the same thing. Protection/domesticpromotion in large or relatively large markets creates a solid home base that encourages particularkinds of company strategies.The resultis a new marketdynamicthat is not neutral. In the case of Japan,domestic policies createdinternal "contests" that substitutedfor pure marketsin honing the competitivedevelopmentof national firms.Those contests rested, as Tsurunotes, on the broadavailability of finance to rival zaibatsu or keiretsu groups. The resulting market dynamic generateda downpouringof exports (leading to enormoustradesurpluses with North America and Europe); that new dynamic also pushed Japanesefirmsto compete for marketsharethroughcontinuousproductinnovation.The WorldBank studydoes not offer a conceptualframeworkthat traces the way these institutionalarrangementsand policy choices shape marketdynamicsin emergingAsian economies. Second, the volume correctlynotes thatrapidgrowthand relativesocial equity have run together.To many Westernobservers, the political weak5. Quoted in Edith Terry, "How Asia Got Rich: World Bank vs. Japanese Industrial Policy," JPRIWorkingPaperNo. 10, JapanPolicy ResearchInstitute,June 1995. This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 244 Journalof Japanese Studies 22:1 (1996) ness of Asian tradeunions obscuresthe fact that the HPAEshave achieved low and declining levels of inequalitycomparedto otherregions. Although the solutions have not always been democratic,the relativeincome equality is certainlysurprising.This opens a broaderissue. The economic study of growthmust be embeddedin an understandingof how, like a simultaneous equation,the technicaland political problemsof growthare solved at once. In this regard,the Japaneseexperience becomes a model, an alternateunderstandingof how marketsand governmentscan interconnect. Third,it is criticalto understandnot only the ways thatJapanis a development model, but also the limits of that model. The authorsof The East Asian Miracle do an impressivejob of exploringthe similaritiesamong the HPAEs. Yet their decision to group the eight countries together into one analyticalwhole obscuresimportantdifferencesamongthem. After all (and as the volume notes), SoutheastAsian countriesmust pursuedevelopment strategiesin a much differentenvironmentthan other countries did. Both Japanand Koreabenefitedfrom U.S. economic and militaryassistance,as well as easy access to the U.S. market.The United States is no longer as willing to tolerate merchandisetrade imbalances;nor is the U.S. government flush with foreign assistanceas it was duringthe cold war. Moreover,the technologicalrequirementsfor competitivesuccess have changed.In the past, it was possible to follow a developmenttrajectorythat utilized second-generationtechnology, along with low domestic factor prices, to be internationallycompetitive.Today,most developing countries see the electronicsindustryas key to their development.The technological learning, economic spillovers, and large export markets associated with electronics have propelled that sector into the center of nationaldevelopmentpolicies all over the world.Yetthe industryrequireshuge initialcapital investments-and mistakes in capital allocation can be fatal for a firm. In such a competitive environment,Southeast Asian countries are finding it necessary to insert themselves into the internationaldivision of labor that has been createdby the expansion of cross-borderproductionnetworksof multinationalcorporations(MNCs) operatingin Asia. Domestic differencesalso make it impossiblefor Asian countriesto embrace a "Japan-style"developmentstrategy.Japan'sindustrializationin the nineteenthcenturywas based on domestictechnologicalinnovation.Taiwan and South Korea,by contrast,relied on achieving competitivenessthrough low wages, and theirindustrialexpansionwas based on learningratherthan indigenousinnovation.6SoutheastAsian countriesconstituteyet a different "thirdtier" of late developers.These countries do not have the history of 6. See Alice Amsden, Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization(New York:OxfordUniversityPress, 1989). This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ReviewSection 245 domestic manufacturingthat developed indigenouslyin Japanand that was createdthroughsuccessful import substitutionindustrializationpolicies in South Koreaand Taiwan.This lack of historicalmanufacturingexperience rendersSoutheastAsian countries more dependenton MNCs for their industrialdevelopment.7 Thus, the WorldBank study sets the stage for a series of conversations in the academicand policy communitiesaboutthe ways the Japancase can shed light on the experiencesof otherAsian countries.These revolve around severalthemes:the ways governmentscan shapemarketdynamics;the ways governments can simultaneouslymanage the political and economic demands of industrialization;and the ways Japan'seconomic development serves as a model yet at the same time changes the policy options for "thirdtier" Asian industrializers. How have our initial three questions fared in these volumes? While it seems that we have a good model for the rapid-growthyears, as proposed both by Tsuru and (more guardedly)by the WorldBank study, the Calder volume certainly suggests that the debate is not closed. Because debates about that baseline will continue to provoke disagreementabout optimal governmentpolicies (and will continueto fuel academiccareersby encouraging "productdifferentiation"),the debateis likely neverto be closed. Our second question-how government-industryrelations change at the postdevelopmentalstage-remains unansweredby these volumes. Indeed, the debateover the extent and characterof changein the Japanesesystem is just beginning. As these debates progress, it will be critical to rememberthat outstandingdisagreementsregardingthe high-growthyears will inevitably affect our discussions and understandingof contemporaryJapan. Third, with regard to Japan'srole in Asia, the World Bank study lays out some interestinghypotheses-and themes for furtherdiscussions-about the lessons and "non-lessons" that Japan'sdevelopment holds for other Asian countries.Just as importantin those futurediscussionsis the role of Asia in Japan'scontinueddevelopment.More must be learnedabout the way Japanese firmshave respondedto yen appreciationsand othercompetitivepressures by reconstructingtheir productionnetworksin Asia. These activities may fundamentallyalter the internationalimplications of Japan'spostwar domestic marketlogic. For example, are Asian marketsfor final products expandingrapidlyenough to absorbsome of the exports currentlytargeted for NorthAmericanand Europeanmarkets?Increasingly,the place of Japan in Asia's economic development, and of Asia in Japan'scontinuing economic development,have become entangledstories. 7. See Mitchell Bernardand John Ravenhill, "Beyond ProductCycles and Flying Geese: Regionalization,Hierarchy,and the Industrializationof East Asia," WorldPolitics, Vol. 47, No. 2 (January1995), especially pp. 195-200. This content downloaded from 137.205.50.42 on Wed, 26 Feb 2014 05:09:25 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions