WORKING PAPER SERIES Centre for Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy

advertisement
Apr 2015
No.226
Does Market Size Matter Also for Charities?
Kimberley Scharf & Janne Tukiainen
WORKING PAPER SERIES
Centre for Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy
Department of Economics
Does Market Size Matter Also for Charities?∗
Kimberley Scharf†
Janne Tukiainen‡
April 2015
A BSTRACT
We analyze implications of market size on market structure in the not-forprofit sector. We show that, while a standard model of oligopolistic competition
between for-profits predicts a positive relationship between market size and firm
size, an analogous model of not-for-profit competition predicts no such correlation. We then interrogate these predictions empirically by focusing on five charitable markets for local public goods. These findings both reject the applicability
of the classic theories of oligopolistic competition between for-profit firms to the
not-for-profit case and fail to reject the simple model proposed here.
KEY WORDS: Competition in the Non-profit Sector, Market Structure
JEL CLASSIFICATION: L11, L13, L15, L31, L33
∗ We
thank Itai Ater, Jana Friedrichsen, Essi Eerola, Oskari Harjunen, Jonathan Haskel, Heikki
Pursiainen, Carol Propper, Tanja Saxell, Michael Waterson and seminar participants at HECER and
VATT, and the 2014 EARIE, the 2015 FEAAM and the 2015 RES conference for their comments. We are
also grateful for the financial support of the UK’s Economic and Social Research Council. Correspondence should be addressed to: Janne Tukiainen, VATT Institute for Economic Research, Arkadiankatu
7, P.O.Box 1279, FI-00101 Helsinki, Finland; janne.tukiainen@vatt.fi.
† Department
of Economics and CAGE, University of Warwick, Coventry, UK and CEPR;
k.scharf@warwick.ac.uk
‡ VATT
Institute for Economic Research, Finland, and HECER, Finland;
janne.tukiainen@vatt.fi
D OES M ARKET S IZE M ATTER A LSO FOR C HARITIES ?
A BSTRACT
We analyze implications of market size on market structure in the not-forprofit sector. We show that, while a standard model of oligopolistic competition
between for-profits predicts a positive relationship between market size and firm
size, an analogous model of not-for-profit competition predicts no such correlation. We then interrogate these predictions empirically by focusing on five charitable markets for local public goods. These findings both reject the applicability
of the classic theories of oligopolistic competition between for-profit firms to the
not-for-profit case and fail to reject the simple model proposed here.
1
Introduction
In many countries the charitable sector is responsible for providing a considerable
share of public services. The sector is also subject to government regulation and
receives a substantial amount of direct or indirect financial support from government.1 While most academic attention has focused on donors’ choices – for example, on how tax incentives can promote charitable giving2 – the question of how
inter-charity competition shapes entry decisions and market structure in the charitable sector has been little studied. Yet, the design of optimal government policies
vis-à-vis the charitable sector is likely to depend on the answer to this question. This
paper seeks to help fill this gap, offering a new model of oligopolistic competition
1 For
example, in the United Kingdom in 2013, the total revenue of the charitable sector was £61
billion and the UK treasury provided £3.25 billion of tax relief to UK charities; in Canada in 2012,
approximately $8.5 donations made by almost 6 billion people, about 7% of GDP, received federal tax
relief of more than $2.9 billion.
2 See
Scharf and Smith (2015) for a recent overview of the literature.
1
between charities as well as the first empirical analysis of competitive conduct in
many different donative non-profit/charitable sectors.3
We first develop a simple analytical model of oligopolistic competition between
for-profit firms providing a homogeneous product through increasing-returns-toscale technologies (operationalized with a combination of fixed and convex variable
costs) under conditions of free entry. This parallels the structure of the standard
framework used in the study of industrial organization with reference to producers
of private goods.4 We then adapt the model for the non-profit case by taking into
account the long-run distribution constraint, that is, charities cannot make profits in
the long-run. Absent a profit motive, we consider both the case where charities’ motivation is purely pro-social, that is, their objective coincides with social surplus, as
well as departures from that behavior that are driven by charities concerns for their
own individual activities.
Our model generates the usual predictions for the for-profit sector – both the
number of firms and their average size will increase in market size (see e.g. Campbell and Hopenhayn, 2005, hereafter referred to as CH for short) – but in the nonprofit case results are strikingly different than those that obtain in the for-profit case.
3 Scharf
(2014) presents a theoretical model of competition between charities and charity selection;
and Perroni et al., (2014) examines the effect of coordination on efficiency. Relatedly, implications
of policy reforms for competition and quality of provision of health services have been analyzed
extensively (e.g., Propper et al., 2008; and Cooper et al., 2011). However, these studies do not focus
on entry effects or the nature of competition. Other studies, including those of Gaynor and Vogt
(2003), and Capps et al., (2010), have asked if the choice of organizational form affects the pricing
decisions of competing hospitals. But these studies also abstract from entry decisions. Other studies
focus on the effect of competition on entry decisions of hospitals, but there are very few contributions
looking at other types of private providers of public goods, which is what we are interested in doing
here. Recent exception is Bowblis (2011), who examines, among other things, the effect of public
insurance on closures of for-profit and non-profit nursing homes respectively. One paper that does
focus on entry in the broader non-profit context is Lakdawalla and Philipson (2006), but their interest
is on the question of selection of organizational form through entry decisions, and not, as is ours,
the implications of market size on market structure in a non-profit context. Gaynor and Town (2011)
contains a very comprehensive and recent overview of the literature.
4 See
e.g., Bresnahan and Reiss (1991).
2
Unlike in the case of for-profit firms, an increase in market size simply raises the
number of providers but has no effect on the size of individual providers (rather
than raising average firm size); this applies whether or not providers are biased towards their own activities. Thus the model provides testable predictions concerning
the relationship between market size and average producer size, and these predictions are distinctively different depending on providers’ competitive conduct.
Secondly, we test empirically whether these predictions hold in a panel data on
registered Canadian charities. We separately study five different charitable sectors:
food and clothes banks, daycare, housing, senior care and disabled care. In order
to study well-defined markets as the unit of observation in the empirical analysis,
we restrict our attention to local charities, i.e. charities that operate only in a given
geographical area, provide public goods consumed locally and compete for funding from local donors. We focus on these five sectors because they are the ones that
contain the largest proportion of “local” charities in our data (where local charities
are defined as those that operate in only one municipality) and because their products can be regarded as local public goods. This empirical analysis can be seen as a
fairly close replication, in a non-profit context, of the CH study on how market size
is related to firm size in various for-profit industries.
We find that market size is not correlated with average charity size in four out of
the five sectors we analyze. A model of non-profit competition can rationalize these
findings. In one sector, we even find a negative correlation between market size and
average charity size, a result that could be accounted for by heterogeneous capacity
constraints for non-profit providers. The results are in stark contrast to those of CH,
who find that in ten out of twelve analyzed industries, average firm size increases
with market size. The results clearly reject the applicability of the standard for-profit
model of oligopolistic competition to these sectors, while also failing to reject the
model of non-profit competition proposed here. These conclusions are robust to
including a rich set of control variables and market level fixed effects, restricting
the analysis to a sub-sample of comparatively more insulated markets, and using
alternative measures of market size.
Our findings have potentially important implications for the debate on the effect
of government policies on the private provision of public goods, a debate that has
3
largely ignored the effects of public funding on inter-charity competition and market structure in the third sector. Our analytical framework predicts that free entry
may result in charities that are inefficiently small relative to the optimal size; but this
effect should be independent of market size – a prediction that is confirmed by our
findings. Thus, government intervention may be warranted to encourage charities
to exploit economies of scale (e.g. by directing government grants towards charities’
core funding needs) independently of market size and of market concentration; in
other words, if, in a given charity sector, there is a tendency for charities to be inefficiently small, a larger market size and more competition cannot be counted on to
offset the problem.
The departure from profit maximization in the context of non-profits has been
investigated by others; but, as mentioned, that literature has focused mainly on provision of health services through hospitals. In this paper, we focus on more broadly
defined non-profits. There have been a few contributions focusing on competition
between charities and on its implications for government regulation, but these have
focused mainly on the implications of organizational form for within-charity performance along various dimensions,5 and/or differential regulatory and tax regimes.6
The mechanics of entry in the non-profit sector, however, and their implications
for competitive conduct of the charitable sector has received scant attention. This
is rather surprising, as it is hard to find another category of economic activity for
which competition would not be at the center of any economic analysis one way or
another. In striking contrast, the competitive conduct of firms in the profit sector and
its implications for industry structure have been studied extensively by a long and
established literature.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. The next section introduces a
theoretical model that compares competition outcomes for for-profit firms and for
charities in the presence of fixed costs. Section 3 describes the data, the estimation
procedures and the empirical results. Section 4 concludes.
5 See
for example, Alchian and Demsetz (1972); Hansmann (1980); Easley and O’Hara (1983);
Glaeser and Schleifer (2001).
6 For
example, Lakdawalla and Philipson (2006).
4
2
Impact of Market Size on Market Structure
We present parallel models of oligopolistic competition under conditions of free entry for the for-profit and the not-profit sectors. Our aim is to make both of these
models as simple as possible, and as comparable as possible, both with respect to
each other and with respect to standard theories of competition. As a benchmark,
we follow the model presented in Bresnahan and Reiss (1991) (BR for short) closely.
However, the BR analysis starts with reduced form equations. As we are interested
in comparing competitive behavior in the for-profit and non-profit sector, we first
develop a simple analytical framework of competition in the non-profit sector and
derive the reduced form of the model from first principles. This will allow us to
highlight the differences in behavior and responses across the two sectors.7
In our analysis, we take market size (defined in terms of the aggregate value of
demand for a homogenous good) as exogenous, and model how the equilibrium
size and number of providers varies endogenously with exogenous changes in market size. In this sense, the model is a partial-equilibrium model that abstracts from
endogenous effects on market size arising from changes occurring in other markets
– or equivalently as a general equilibrium model in which the the cross-price elasticity of demand of the good produced in the market under consideration is zero. In
turn exogenous variations in market size in the model can be thought of arising from
variations in income and/or population or variations in the level of demand itself.8
2.1
The For-profit Case
We begin by developing a simple model of competition in the for-profit sector. Consider a market with N identical oligopolistic firms. Firm i = {1, . . . , N } supplies qi
units of a homogeneous product, with market supply being given by ∑iN=1 qi ≡ Q.
The cost function of a representative firm, i, (the same for all firms) is C (qi ) =
7 Our
model generates predictions that are comparable to those obtained in BR.
8 Variation
in demand may be the result of variation in factors that affect demand – e.g. demand
for beverages might be affected by variations in whether conditions, or “demand”, for soup kitchens
for the hungry may be affected by variations in the numbers of the needy.
5
F + c(qi ), with c0 (qi ) > 0, and c00 (qi ) > 0, where F represents fixed costs and c(qi )
are convex variable costs. Assume that all firms hold Cournot conjectures about
their own choices and the choices of other firms. Let φ ∈ R be market size, or equivalently, the value of market demand, p Q( p) = φ where, p denotes the price of the
homogeneous good; and let aggregate market demand be given by Q( p) = φ/p.9
Inverse aggregate market demand can be written as p( Q) = φ/Q, and so each
firm i’s profits are
Πi = p ( Q ) qi − c ( qi ) − F =
φ qi
− c(qi ) − F.
Q
(1)
Each firm, i, chooses qi so as to maximize its own profits while taking output choices
of all other firms, x−i , as given. The first order condition for firm i’s optimal choice
of qi is then given by
φ
Q − qi
− c0 (qi ) = 0.
Q2
(2)
In a symmetric noncooperative equilibrium with N symmetric firms each supplying an amount q (Q = N q), the equilibrium markup choice is obtained by substituting Q = N q into the above expressions
N−1 φ
− N c0 (q) = 0;
N q
(3)
and the zero-profit condition that identifies the equilibrium number of firms in a
free-entry equilibrium, in conjunction with (3), is
φ
− c(q) − F = 0.
N
(4)
Note that the equilibrium conditions (3)-(4) differ from the condition that defines
the socially optimal number and size of firms, obtained from maximizing social sur
plus, φ ln N q̂( N ) − N c q̂( N ) + F , by choice of q and N. Of the resulting two
9 This
specification, in which φ acts as a proxy for market size, is consistent with Cobb-Douglas
consumer preferences whereby the value, φ, of demand in the market of interest amounts to a constant
share, θ, of disposable income M, with M exogenous (i.e. φ = pQ = θM).
6
conditions, one is formally identical to (4), but the second one – the condition idenφ
tifying q in place of condition (3) – becomes − N c0 (q) = 0; which for the same N,
q
implies a larger q. Thus, under for-profit competition, firm size is inefficiently small.
The following result fully parallels that of BR:
Proposition 1 As market size increases, the number and the size of firms increases.
P ROOF: Totally differentiating the optimal markup and the zero profit condition with respect
to φ, N and Q yields the following comparative static results:
dN
1 ( N − 1) φ − N q c0 (q) + N q2 c00 (q)
;
=
dφ
D
N 2 q2
(5)
dq
1 φ − N q c0 (q)
=
;
dφ
D
N2 q
(6)
( N − 1)φ2 + N x c0 (q) φ − N 2 q c0 (q) + N 2 q2 φ c00 (q)
D≡φ
.
N 3 q2
(7)
By the first order condition,
φ − N q c0 ( x ) > φ − N 2 q c0 ( x ) > ( N − 1)φ − N 2 q c0 (q) = 0,
(8)
so that the numerators of the above three expressions are all positive, and thus
dN
>0
dφ
and
dq
> 0.
dφ
(9)
The size of a representative firm, measured in revenue terms, is s ≡ p( Nq)q = φ/N, and
market size, S ≡ N p( Nq)q equals φ. Rewriting (4) as N = φ/(c(q) + F ), the effect of an
increase in q on N is ∂N/∂q = −c0 (q)φ/(c(q) + F )2 . Using this, the effect of an increase in
market size (φ) on s can be expressed as
1
φ ∂N dq
1
φ2 c 0 ( q )
dq
ds
=
− 2
=
+ 2
> 0.
2
dφ
N
N ∂q dφ
N
N (c(q) + F ) dφ
(10)
This implies that, as market size increases, both the number and the size of firms increase. Thus, an increase in market size causes firms to become larger, and closer in size
to the socially optimal size (for N approaching infinity, condition (3) coincides with
7
the condition identifying the socially optimal firm size); i.e. a larger market brings
about rationalization of production choices.
Example: Specialize c(q) to be c(q) =
tions:
φ + φ (φ + 8F )
N=
4F
4φF
s=
φ + φ (φ + 8F )
1 2
q . We can then obtain closed-form solu2
1/2
;
(11)
1/2 .
(12)
Both of the above are increasing and concave in φ. That is, there are steeper marginal
effects of market size on market structure when market size is small.10
2.2
The Non-profit Case
Charities – be they donative charities (non-commercial, i.e. receiving donations) or
commercial charities (charging a price for its output) – differ from for-profit organizations because they face a long-run binding non-distribution constraint, that is,
they might incur surpluses and losses in the short run, but, on average (i.e., in a ‘long
run’ sense), their revenues must equal their expenditures.11
10 Although
entry thresholds are not the focus of this study, we also note that all of our results are
in harmony with those found in the BR estimations: this result consistent with declining thresholds
effects for sequential entry in the discrete case; and as market size increases, the number of firms
increases at a decreasing rate (the threshold for entry of the first firm is positive and the per firm
threshold for entry of subsequent firms remain positive and are larger than those for the previous
firm. Moreover, as market size increases, there is fast convergence to competition consistently with
the empirical results of BR.
11 The
discussion in this section focuses on the donative charity case, which directly implies
marginal cost pricing. Nevertheless, it can be shown that the same analysis and results also apply
to the case of commercial charities that engage in average cost pricing – provided that they operate
under the same non-distribution constraint.
8
In deriving results for the non-profit case, we abstract from the public good nature of output – if present. Consistently with the for-profit case, the marginal valuation of output by buyers/donors (the “shadow price” of output) is v( Q) = φ/Q.
In a symmetric noncooperative equilibrium, the binding non-distribution constraint means that, in order for providers not to incur a loss, donations must cover
full costs, c(q) + F. At the margin, however, donors face a marginal cost of provision
equal to c0 (q).12 The optimal giving choice is therefore characterized by setting the
marginal valuation of output by the donors to the marginal cost of provision, that is
φ
= c 0 ( q ).
Nq
(13)
Hence, in the non-profit case, market size, as measured by the revenues of charities,
N c(q) + F , does not coincide with φ as it does in the for-profit case.
Condition (13) identifies the equilibrium level of q for a given N, denoted by
q̂( N ). Totally differentiating (13) with respect to q and N shows that the equilibrium
level of q is decreasing in N,
φ
q
∂q̂
=−
< 0.
∂N
N φ + N q2 c00 (q)
(14)
A fully pro-social not-for-profit provider who chooses to operate in the market
in a symmetric equilibrium with N identical providers aims at maximizing social
surplus, which equals
Γ E ( N ) = φ ln N q̂( N ) − N c q̂( N ) + F .
12 This is the non-profit analogue to marginal cost pricing in the for-profit sector.
(15)
If charity providers
are commercial, they may or may not be able to rely on non-linear pricing schemes and/or price
discrimination. If they can do so, and also aim at maximizing social surplus, then they will price
the marginal unit at marginal cost. If they cannot rely on non-linear pricing schemes and/or price
discrimination, then they will price at average cost, AC (q) = c(q) + F /q; but even in this case,
given that marginal costs are increasing, they will be able to choose a scale of operation q such that
AC (q) = c0 (q), and it will be optimal for them to do so (as social surplus is maximized at this scale
of operation). Thus, in our framework, implications of market size for entry for donative and for
commercial charities are the same.
9
Then, if the marginal provider exits the market, the provider’s payoff is
Γ X ( N ) = φ ln ( N − 1) q̂( N − 1) − ( N − 1) c q̂( N − 1) + F .
(16)
The optimal entry decision, identifying an equilibrium level of N in a symmetric
outcome, is then identified by the level of N for which Γ E ( N ) ≥ Γ X ( N − 1) and
Γ E ( N + 1) < Γ X ( N ), or, in differential terms (i.e. allowing N to vary continuously),
φ φ
∂q̂ ∂q̂
=
− c(q) − F = 0.
q+N
− c(q) − F − N c0 (q)
Nq
∂N
∂N
N
(17)
The assumption of full pro-social motivation by charities can be viewed as extreme; and indeed a large literature has highlighted how charities may pursue objectives other than profit maximization or social surplus maximization, such as, for
example, the maximization of own revenues (see the previously mentioned survey
by Gaynor and Town, 2011). A simple way of modeling such departure from surplus
maximization objectives is to amend (15) as follows:
Γ E ( N ) = µ c q̂( N ) + F + φ ln N q̂( N ) − N c q̂( N ) + F ,
(18)
where the last two terms coincide with social surplus, and where the first term, with
µ ≥ 0 is a premium that the provider attaches to own activities, as measured by
terms their cost or associated revenues, above and beyond the provider’s concern
for social surplus (pro-social motivation) as represented by the last two terms.13 In
this case, the no-entry condition must be amended as follows:
φ
µ c(q) + F + − c(q) − F = 0.
N
(19)
The presence of a premium on own activities involves a divergence from optimality with respect to the number and size of providers operating in the charitable
13 This
specification is consistent with the literature incorporating additional elements over and
above social surplus, that literature however, has not focused on entry decisions, but rather on the
effect that additional component may have on ex-post competitive conduct. Instead, we focus on the
implications of the additional motives on entry decisions, that is, our additional term in the payoff
would accrue to charity contingent on entry; whereas, the social surplus component would accrue to
charity independently of whether or not it enters.
10
market: for µ = 0, condition (19) coincides with the condition for social surplus
maximization, i.e. it identifies the socially optimal number of providers for a given
market size, φ; an increase in µ from zero starting from the socially optimal N makes
the left-hand side of the above positive, and so N must rise relative to the the case
µ = 0 (the total derivative dN/dµ evaluated at µ = 0 is positive). This implies that
own-output biased non-profits make positively biased entry decisions, resulting in
excessive entry and a suboptimal scale of production.14
Such positive entry bias, however, is independent of market size – and so has no
implications for how market size affects charity size:
Proposition 2 Unlike in the case of for-profit firms, an increase in market size raises the
number of providers but has no effect on the size of individual providers – independently of
whether or not charity providers are fully pro-socially motivated.
P ROOF: Totally differentiating condition (13), we obtain
∂q̂
φq
=−
,
∂N
Nφ + N 2 q2 c00 (q)
(20)
∂q̂
q
=
.
∂φ
φ + Nq2 c00 (q)
(21)
and
The marginal benefit to a firm entering is
φ
µ c(q) + F +
− c(q) − F ≡ Ω.
N
(22)
The equilibrium number of charities, N, is identified by
Ω = 0;
(23)
totally differentiating this with respect to N and φ, using the fact that φ = Nqc0 (q) – from
(13) – and simplify, we obtain
N
dN
= .
dφ
φ
14 Some
(24)
of the literature on non-profits – e.g. Philipson and Posner (2009) – effectively assumes
µ = ∞, i.e. that non-profit providers only care about their own output.
11
The effect of an increase in φ on the size of a charity (measured in terms of revenues), c(q) +
F ≡ s, is
ds
∂q
∂q dN
0
= c (q)
+
.
dφ
∂φ ∂N dφ
(25)
Substituting the expression for dN/dφ from (24) into the above, substituting the expressions
for ∂q/∂φ and ∂q/∂N from (20) and (21), relying again on the identity φ = Nqc0 (q), we obtain
ds
= 0.
dφ
(26)
The total effect of an increase in φ on market size, as measured by total revenues, Ns ≡ S, is
dS
dN
=s
> 0.
dφ
dφ
(27)
Thus an increase in market size, brought about by an increase in φ, has no effect on charity
size or on their cost structure.
Example: As before, specialize c(q) to be c(q) =
N=φ
s=
1 2
q . For µ > 0, we obtain:
2
1+µ
;
2(1 − µ ) F
(28)
2F
.
1+µ
(29)
Thus, if charity providers attach a constant marginal premium to own activities
(as measured by revenues), the number of charities will be too high, but an increase
in market size will have no effect on charity size – just as in the case of fully prosocially motivated providers (µ = 0). If there is a departure from pure pro-social
objectives, this will result in sub-optimally small providers just as in the for-profit
case; but unlike in the for-profit case, increased competition in a larger market will
not act to promote rationalization in production choices.15
15 As
noted earlier, these conclusions extend to commercial charities. If a charity is a pro-socially
12
3
Empirical Evidence
3.1
Data
Charitable contributions in Canada are eligible for tax relief and tax receipts to donors
are offered by the organizations to whom the donation is made. The Canada Customs and Revenue Authority (CCRA) keeps track of these tax receipts by requiring
all issuing organizations to file an annual information return, the T3010 within a
specified period after the end of the charity’s financial year. Among other things,
information contained on the forms includes charities’ fiscal period end, their registration number, detailed information about their revenues and expenditures, their
geographical areas of activities (municipal; provincial; national; international); their
full postal address; and a summary of their main activities. Our raw data consists of
the universe of T3010 forms submitted to CCRA over the period 1997-2005.
The data consists of 50,141 charities (in the year 2001) whose activities are aimed
only at the local (municipal) level.16 We focus on five charity service sectors that
are likely to be consumed only locally, and which are well represented in the data.
For example, with reference to the year 2001, we use information on 1,304 food and
clothing banks, 1,103 daycare centers, 1,254 housing charities, 1,319 senior care and
1,368 disabled care organizations.
We defined our market at the level of a statistical unit called the Forward Sortation Area (FSA). In Canada, a postal code is an alphanumeric six-character string
motivated commercial provider pricing at average cost, then the equilibrium entry level N coincides
with the level that maximizes (15) subject to a constraint φ/( Nq) = c(q) + F /q ≡ AC (q). This
gives an optimum level of output per charity, q, that is identified by equality between marginal and
average cost, i.e. by the condition c0 (q) = AC (q). As this is independent of N, the size of individual
providers, s = AC (q) q, will also be independent of N and thus of total market size, Ns; the same
conclusion applies if the charity is own-output biased.
16 These
charities were asked to declare the area for which their programs are carried out. Of the
69,473 charities in total: there is no information on 1,146; of the charities in the sample, 50,141 reported
that their activities are carried out in a single rural, city or metropolitan area; 10,533 reported that they
have activities carried on in a province or territory; and 7,653 have activities that are carried out in
more than one province or territory.
13
that takes the form ‘A1A 1A1’. The FSA is a geographical area in which all postal
codes start with the same three characters (the ‘A1A’ part of the code). The first letter
‘A’ of the code stands for a postal district (most provinces/territories are assigned a
unique postal district – with the exception of Ontario and Quebec, which, due to
their respective sizes, have more (three for Ontario and five for Quebec); the cities of
Toronto and Montreal each have their own postal district (‘H’ for Montreal and ’M’
for Toronto). The digit is a variable that takes on a value of zero for a wide-area rural
region, and nonzero for urban areas. The second letter represents a specific rural region, an entire medium-sized city, or a section of a major metropolitan area. We link
the charities to FSAs using charities’ postal address. We assume that they operate
only within that FSA although there is not a perfect overlap between the FSAs and
the municipalities.
To construct a panel with information on market characteristics, we link our charity data to Canadian census data from years 1996, 2001 and 2006 at the FSA level.
We have to link 1996 Census data to 1997 charity information and 2006 Census data
to 2005 charity information. A panel with five years between each cross-section is
useful for our purposes, since it should contain over time variation in the main explanatory variable, the market size.
One potential issue with this way of of defining of a market is that the FSA may
not be a self-contained market. This is especially so in the larger cities, where FSAs
are typically small in terms of land area, and where the neighboring FSAs are often densely populated, which not only means that it is easy to use the goods in
neighboring markets but also that some donors may donate money to charities in
neighboring FSAs. In such cases, we would not be capturing independent markets.
To address this potential problem, we construct a neighborhood matrix for all FSAs
using GIS. We then study the robustness of the results to using only a sub-sample of
FSAs that are more densely populated than any of their neighbors. This means that
we never include neighboring markets, thus making the independence assumption
more plausible.
To facilitate comparison between the existing empirical evidence concerning market size and size of firms in the for-profit sector, we simply replicate the analysis
conducted in CH. CH estimations are done in a reduced form, and thus we sim-
14
ply correlate market size with average charity size, and compare the results to the
comparative statics implied by our models. Average charity size is measured as the
average of charities’ total revenues in the market, and market size is the total population in the FSA. To begin with we present, in Table 1, descriptive statistics for these
main variables of interest as well as for our control variables. For ease of interpretation we report these descriptive statistics only for the cross-section of charities in
the year 2001. We have a total of 1,573 markets. In all sectors analyzed, charities
are active in slightly less than half of the markets. All variables exhibit substantial
variation across markets.
[Table 1 about here]
3.2
Estimation
CH are interested in the effects of market size on producer size. As discussed in
Section 2, a standard and robust prediction from oligopoly theory is that since larger
markets are more competitive and have lower price-cost mark-ups producers need
to sell more in large markets than in small markets to recover their fixed costs. CH
test these predictions empirically and find that ten out of twelve industries exhibit a
positive relationship between the size of a market and average establishment size of
producers in that market.
To facilitate comparison with the main results in CH, who do not have access
to panel data, we start by analyzing a 2001 cross-section of markets. We conduct
the estimation separately for each of the five sectors. Results from a simple OLS
estimation are reported in Table 2. We begin with a specification without any controls
in the leftmost column. The columns to the right report specification with increasing
amount of control variables, that are added in the order they are reported in Table
1. We find that in four out of five sectors there is no association between market size
and charity size. Only in the senior care sector do we find a positive and statistically
significant correlation that is robust to adding control variables.
[Table 2 about here]
15
In Table 3, we use data from all the three years in our panel. To investigate the
robustness of the results to adding new data compared to Table 2, we report results
from a pooled OLS regression. The qualitative results are identical to those in Table
2, and also very similar in magnitude.
[Table 3 about here]
In Table 4, we exploit the panel structure of the data further and introduce FSA
fixed effects to all specifications in order to control for time-invariant unobservables;
otherwise the results are reported as in Tables 2 and 3. There are two notable differences when focusing on within-market variation as opposed to between-market
variation. The positive and significant correlation in the senior care sector is no
longer present. Moreover, we now have a negative and significant coefficient for
the daycare sector in the richer specifications. Given that the daycare result is significant, there seems to be enough within-market variation in the population to identify
possible effects of market size on charity size. Table 4 can therefore be taken as representing the most reliable set of results, and accordingly we focus the rest of our
discussion on those.
[Table 4 about here]
In Table 5, we restrict attention on the subset of markets that are more densely
populated than any of their neighboring markets. This reduces the size of the sample
and thus increases the standard errors. Of main interest is that the point estimates
are very similar to those in Table 4, in particular for the daycare sector, which was the
only significant result in Table 4. The results indicate robustness to market definition.
[Table 5 about here]
We also examined alternative definitions of market size to make sure that a possible measurement error in the relevant market size variable was not responsible for
16
statistical insignificance. For the senior care we defined the market size as the number of old-age inhabitants and for the daycare as the number of young. The results
are almost identical to those using the total population, and are thus not reported.
According to CH, the main potential endogeneity issues in such analysis are that
if large markets have larger fixed costs or consumers with more elastic demand
curves, they will contain larger producers even if adding competition does not lower
markups. This would result in a spurious positive correlation between market size
and establishment size. We do not find a robust and positive correlation between
charity size in terms of total expenditures and market size in any of the five sectors.
Since the main potential endogeneity issues should not cause bias towards zero or
negative values, and since the endogeneity issues we face are likely to be similar
to those in CH, we can conclude that a typical charitable sector seems to compete
differently than the for profit industries. Moreover, the results for four out of five
sectors are in line with the predictions from our model of non-profit competition.
We find a deviation from the neutrality prediction of Proposition 2 only one out of
five sectors, in a downwards direction, which cannot be explained by a model of
for-profit competition.
The single instance of negative correlation may be confounded by the aforementioned potential endogeneity issue; but it could also be accounted for by the presence
of heterogenous provider sizes stemming from heterogeneous capacity constraints
under non-profit competition.17
Another potential source of bias for our results is that we are missing information on the number of active government or private producers in these markets.
However, this is unlikely to lead to wrong conclusions for two reasons. First, our
model predictions apply to each individual producer. We use the average over the
17 When providers are heterogeneous,
comparatively more efficient, lower-cost providers will enter
the market first and then be followed by less efficient providers, implying that marginal entrants will
be smaller than the average provider; it can then be shown that, under certain conditions, an increase
in market size can result in a fall in the average size of non-profit providers, even when, for the same
technologies, an increase in market size could bring about an increase in the average size of for-profit
firms.
17
charity as the outcome only because we need a market level variable. But since the
prediction applies to each individual producers, the average size should respond
accordingly in any subset of producers in a each market. Second, the presence of
private or public producers is very likely to vary across sectors, and is nonexistent
in the food and clothing banks sectors. If this omitted information were driving the
results, we should see more heterogeneity in results across the sectors in terms of
qualitative conclusions. Similarly, we have also restricted the analysis to only local
charities. Some bigger charities that are active in our markets are omitted variables.
Again the same two arguments why this should not cause substantial bias hold.
These results are striking and interesting. We can reject the standard model of
for-profit oligopolistic competition in all the sectors considered. The results are consistent with our model for charities in four out of five sectors, and we can reject a
model of for-profit competition in all five. The key implication from such finding is
that in non-profit markets increased competition does not have the same effect on
the structure of production as it does in the for profit case: it may be the case that
production choices in the non-profit sector are perfectly efficient; but if inefficiencies
exist in the non-profit sector with respect to the scale of their operation, a change in
the degree of concentration of providers brought about by a larger market size will
leave those inefficiencies unchanged.
4
Conclusions
We provide a simple oligopoly model of charities that compete for donors. The
model has testable predictions that allow us to differentiate between competitive
conduct in charitable markets and the same in for-profit markets. Moreover, we
can test for whether charities are biased towards their own production. We test the
model predictions by correlating market size to average charity size in the market.
We find that for four out of five charitable sectors, market size has no effect on average charity size in the market and in one sector the correlation is negative, whereas
as any reasonable model of for-profit oligopoly competition predicts a positive correlation. According to these results, we can reject the standard model of for-profit
competition. The results are typically consistent with our model of for-profit compe18
tition between either biased or unbiased charities.
Besides providing and testing a model of competition for the third sector, a novel
undertaking as such, the results have also policy implications. First, it seems that
the same policies will not be suitable for all charitable sectors, because the nature
of competition, and thus, the optimal size of charities varies across sectors. Second,
our theoretical analysis suggests that increased competition in non-profit markets
should have no effect on market structure: while in the for-profit sector a larger market size can promote rationalization of production choices, this is not the case with
non-profit competition even when non-profit competitors have private motives, a
conclusion that seems to be borne out by the empirical evidence; accordingly, government policies may have just an equally important role to play in “more competitive” non-profit markets as in smaller ones.
19
References
Alchian, A., and H. Demsetz, 1972. “Production, Information Costs, and Economic
Organization.” American Economic Review 62, 777-95.
Bowblis, J., 2011. “Ownership conversion and closure in the nursing home industry.”
Health Economics 20, 631-644.
Bresnahan T., and P. Reiss, 1991. “Entry and Competition in Concentrated Markets.”
Journal of Political Economy 99, 977-1009.
Campbell J., and H. Hopenhayn, 2005. “Market Size Matters.” Journal of Industrial
Economics 53, 1-25.
Capps, C., D. Dranove, and R. Lindrooth, 2010. “Hospital Closure and Economic
Efficiency.” Journal of Health Economics 29, 87-109.
Cooper, Z., S. Gibbons, S. Jones, and A. McGuire, 2011. “Does Hospital Competition Save Lives? Evidence From The English NHS Patient Choice Reforms.”
Economic Journal 121, F228-F260.
Easley, D., and M. O’Hara, 1983. “The Economic Role of the Nonprofit Firm.” Bell
Journal of Economics 14, 531-38.
Gaynor, M., and W. Vogt, 2003. “Competition Among Hospitals.” RAND Journal of
Economics 34, 764-785.
Gaynor, M., and R. Town, 2011. “Competition in Health Care Markets.” Chapter 9 of
by M. Pauly, T. McGuire and P. Pita Barros (eds.), Handbook of Health Economics,
Vol. 2, 499-637, Elsevier.
Glaeser, E., and A. Schleifer, 2001. “Not-for-profit Entrepreneurs.” Journal of Public
Economics 81, 99-115.
Hansmann, H., 1980. “The Role of the Non-profit Enterprise.” Yale Law Journal 89,
835-901.
20
Lakdawalla, D., and T. Philipson, 2006. “The Nonprofit Sector and Industry Performance.” Journal of Public Economics 90, 1681-98.
Perroni, C., G. Pogrebna, S. Sandford, and K. Scharf, 2014. “Are Donors Afraid of
Charities’ Core Costs? Scale Economies in Nonprofit Provision, Technology
Adoption and Entry.” CEPR Discussion Paper Number 10179.
Philipson, T., and R. Posner, 2009. “Antitrust in the Not-for-profit Sector.” Journal of
Law and Economics 52, 1-18.
Propper, C., S. Burgess, and D. Gossage, 2008. “Competition and Quality: Evidence
from the NHS Internal Market 1991-9.” Economic Journal 118, 138-170.
Scharf, K., 2014. “Impure Pro-Social Motivation in Charity Provision: Warm-Glow
Charities and Implications for Public Funding.” Journal of Public Economics 114,
50-57.
Scharf, K., and S. Smith, 2015. “The Price Elasticity of Charitable Giving: Does the
Form of Tax Relief Matter?” International Tax and Public Finance 22, 330-352.
21
Table 1: Descriptive statistics for the year 2001
Variable
No. Obs.
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min
Max
Population (1,000)
1,573
19,117
14,989
40
132,435
Household mean income (1,000)
1,573
59,857
23,385
0
279,759
Share of low income families (%)
1,573
12.0
7.6
0
60
Share over 65 (%)
1,573
5.5
2.2
0
27.5
Share under 5’s (%)
1,573
2.9
0.9
0
12.5
Share of university education (%)
1,573
10.3
7.0
0
43.3
Share of max grade 9 education (%)
1,573
16.9
11.6
0
69.5
Share of immigrants (%)
1,573
15.6
15.4
0
72.4
Unemployment share (%)
1,573
8.1
5.5
0
50
Rental prices (1,000)
1,573
624
225
0
1,968
Mean size, Food & Cloth
721
162,978
411,351
303
5,654,617
Mean size, Daycare
619
762,432
3,646,695
257
8.90E+07
Mean size, Housing
641
988,129
1,732,783
25
1.66E+07
Mean size, Seniors
666
332,777
1,107,736
99
1.38E+07
Mean size, Disabled
687
1,209,306
2,735,799
1
3.38E+07
22
Table 2: Regression results: average charity size on market size –
Table&2&(&NCCQT101.wmf&
&
2001 cross-section
&
&
Log(population)
-0.05
-0.044
s .e.
0.088
0.077
N
R-sq
709
0
704
0.1
Food/cloth?bank
-0.026
0.002
0.077
0.077
0.002
-0.039
-0.063
0.079
0.078
0.079
704
704
704
704
704
0.11
0.12
0.12
0.13
0.14
Daycare
Log(population) 0.054
0.052
0.075
0.093
0.093
0.079
0.06
s .e.
0.069
0.077
0.077
0.077
0.079
0.078
0.08
N
610
602
602
602
602
602
601
R-sq
0
0.02
0.05
0.07
0.07
0.08
0.09
Housing
Log(population) 0.175*
0.210*
0.19
0.191
0.171
0.131
0.129
s .e.
0.106
0.116
0.118
0.119
0.121
0.122
0.122
N
636
631
631
631
631
631
631
R-sq
0
0.04
0.04
0.05
0.05
0.06
0.06
Seniors
Log(population) 0.294*** 0.304*** 0.375*** 0.394*** 0.337*** 0.303*** 0.282**?
s .e.
0.1
0.105
0.109
0.106
0.107
0.11
0.113
N
661
656
656
656
656
656
655
R-sq
0.01
0.07
0.09
0.09
0.11
0.11
0.12
Disabled
Log(population) 0.152
0.212*
0.168
0.167
0.163
0.165
0.138
s .e.
0.112
0.123
0.122
0.12
0.124
0.127
0.13
N
677
672
672
672
672
672
671
R-sq
0
0.01
0.02
0.06
0.06
0.06
0.06
Nro?of?controls
0
2
4
6
7
8
9
&
&
&
&
Notes: The unit of observation is a market defined as an FSA. The outcome is the average expenditures of all charities of given sector in the market. The set of control variables include, and are
added in this order: log(population), log(average household income), share of low income families,
share of population over 65 years of age, share of population under 5 years of age, share of population with no higher than grade 9 education, share of population with university education, share of
immigrant population, share of unemployed and average rental price. Standard errors are robust to
heteroskedasticity but not clustered at any level; * denotes statistical significance at the 10% level, **
at the 5% level and *** at the 1% level.
23
Table 3: Regression results: average charity size on market size –
1997, 2001 and 2005, pooled OLS
Table&3&(&NCCQT101.wmf&
&
Log(population)
-0.058
Food/cloth7bank
-0.022
0.035
-0.035
s .e.
(0.074)
(0.077)
N
R-sq
2063
0.00
2054
0.01
-0.037
-0.060
-0.069777
(0.072)
(0.072)
(0.073)
(0.073)
1312
0.13
1312
0.13
1311
0.14
0.057
0.058
0.036777
(0.062)
(0.062)
(0.061)
(0.062)
1151
0.07
1151
0.08
1150
0.09
0.166*
1772
1151
0.06
0.07
Housing
0.171
0.130
0.097
0.080
0.073777
(0.105)
(0.109)
(0.107)
(0.106)
(0.075)
Log(population)
0.041
0.033
2054
1312
0.04
0.13
Daycare
0.071
0.062
s .e.
(0.050)
(0.059)
(0.058)
N
R-sq
1788
0.00
1772
0.02
Log(population) 0.145*
s .e.
(0.088)
(0.099)
N
R-sq
1840
0.00
1832
0.01
s .e.
(0.093)
(0.098)
N
R-sq
1958
0.01
1952
0.02
Log(population)
0.105
s .e.
N
R-sq
Nro7of7controls
(0.108)
1832
1192
1192
1192
1192
0.01
0.04
0.04
0.05
0.05
Seniors
Log(population) 0.269*** 0.300*** 0.394*** 0.389*** 0.341*** 0.334*** 0.310***
&
&
&
(0.100)
(0.115)
(0.114)
(0.115)
(0.112)
1281
0.10
1281
0.10
1278
0.10
0.146
1952
1281
0.06
0.09
Disabled
0.134
0.094
0.087
0.086
0.065777
(0.094)
(0.100)
(0.102)
(0.107)
(0.108)
(0.107)
(0.108)
2060
0.00
0
2051
0.00
2
2051
0.01
4
1355
0.07
6
1355
0.07
7
1355
0.07
8
1353
0.07
9
&
&
Notes: The unit of observation is a market defined as an FSA. The outcome is the average expenditures of all charities of given sector in the market. The set of control variables include, and are added
in this order: log(population), log(average household income), share of low income families, share of
population over 65 years of age, share of population under 5 years of age, share of population with
no higher than grade 9 education, share of population with university education, share of immigrant
population, share of unemployed and average rental price. Standard errors are clustered at the FSA
level; * denotes statistical significance at the 10% level, ** at the 5% level and *** at the 1% level.
24
Table 4: Regression results: average charity size on market size –
1997-2005 fixed-effects panel estimations
Table&4&(&NCCQT103.wmf&
&
Log(population)
0.365
20.194
s .e.
(0.246)
(0.165)
N
R2sq
2063
0.00
2054
0.11
Log(population) 0.219*
20.220
s .e.
(0.116)
(0.141)
N
R2sq
1788
0.00
1772
0.21
Log(population) 0.779***
Food/cloth8bank
20.071
20.264
(0.185)
(0.299)
20.270
20.239
20.267888
(0.294)
(0.298)
(0.290)
2054
1312
1312
1312
1311
0.12
0.07
0.07
0.07
0.08
Daycare
20.242* 20.443** 20.433** 20.420** 20.423**8
(0.184)
(0.182)
(0.184)
(0.182)8
1151
0.20
1151
0.20
1150
0.20
0.322
1772
1151
0.23
0.19
Housing
0.286
0.269
0.250
0.300
0.288888
(0.250)
s .e.
(0.283)
(0.265)
N
R2sq
1840
0.01
1832
0.06
Log(population)
0.137
s .e.
N
R2sq
(0.140)
(0.394)
(0.393)
(0.387)
(0.390)8
1192
0.03
1192
0.03
1192
0.03
20.130
1832
1192
0.06
0.02
Seniors
20.025
20.334
20.317
20.306
20.283888
(0.096)
(0.181)
(0.193)
1958
0.00
1952
0.07
Log(population)
0.034
s .e.
(0.351)
N
R2sq
Nro8of8controls
2060
0.00
0
&
&
&
(0.363)
(0.351)
(0.358)
(0.337)
1281
0.05
1281
0.05
1278
0.04
20.320
1952
1281
0.08
0.05
Disabled
20.264
0.035
0.028
0.021
20.028888
(0.356)
(0.353)
(0.375)
(0.383)
(0.374)
(0.371)
2051
0.02
2
2051
0.02
4
1355
0.02
6
1355
0.02
7
1355
0.02
8
1353
0.02
9
&
&
Notes: The unit of observation is a market as defined by an FSA. The outcome is the average expenditures of all charities of a given sector in the market. The set of control variables include, and are added
in this order: log(population), log(average household income), share of low income families, share of
population over 65 years of age, share of population under 5 years of age, share of population with
no higher than grade 9 education, share of population with university education, share of immigrant
population, share of unemployed and average rental price. Standard errors are clustered at the FSA
level; * denotes statistical significance at the 10% level, ** at the 5% level and *** at the 1% level.
25
Table 5: Regression results: average charity size on market size –
1997-2005,
fixed-effects panel estimations, FSAs with lower-density neighbors
Table&5&(&NCCQT103.wmf&
&
Log(population)
0.053
Food/cloth9bank
10.278
10.190
10.335
s .e.
(0.215)
(0.170)
N
R1sq
481
0.00
481
0.10
Log(population) 0.205**
(0.185)
(0.475)
10.299
10.351
10.476999
(0.426)
(0.440)
(0.447)
305
0.08
305
0.08
305
0.10
10.060
481
305
0.10
0.07
Daycare
10.178
10.343
10.437
10.400
10.441999
(0.151)
(0.393)
(0.384)
(0.415)
249
0.25
249
0.26
249
0.27
s .e.
(0.104)
(0.125)
N
R1sq
391
0.00
391
0.19
(0.367)
Log(population)
0.484
0.185
391
249
0.21
0.25
Housing
0.205
10.069
s .e.
(0.504)
(0.492)
(0.473)
N
R1sq
412
0.00
412
0.03
Log(population)
0.126
s .e.
N
R1sq
(0.595)
0.078
0.185
0.073
(0.614)
(0.701)
(0.725)
264
0.06
264
0.06
264
0.08
10.124
412
264
0.03
0.06
Seniors
10.008
0.265
0.352
0.337
0.081
(0.143)
(0.182)
(0.179)
(0.911)
467
0.00
467
0.04
Log(population)
0.053
s .e.
(0.416)
N
R1sq
Nro9of9controls
548
0.00
0
(0.962)
(0.929)
305
0.08
305
0.08
303
0.06
10.442
467
305
0.05
0.08
Disabled
10.415
10.409
(0.842)
10.362
10.450
10.435
(0.419)
(0.401)
(0.527)
(0.560)
(0.583)
(0.587)
548
0.05
2
548
0.05
4
364
0.06
6
364
0.06
7
364
0.06
8
364
0.06
9
&
Notes: The unit of observation is a market defined as an FSA. The outcome is the average expenditures of all charities of given sector in the market. The set of control variables include, and are added
in this order: log(population), log(average household income), share of low income families, share of
population over 65 years of age, share of population under 5 years of age, share of population with
no higher than grade 9 education, share of population with university education, share of immigrant
population, share of unemployed and average rental price. Standard errors are clustered at the FSA
level; * denotes statistical significance at the 10% level, ** at the 5% level and *** at the 1% level.
26
Download