Southwest Business and Economics Journal/2010 A Reality-Based Model to Assess the Market Risk of Privatizing Social Security Jerry A. Joseph Indiana University of Pennsylvania Monsurur Rahman Indiana University of Pennsylvania Faye Bradwick Indiana University of Pennsylvania Abstract The debate about whether to privatize part or all of the federal social security system is not settled. There is still disagreement over a number of issues including the level of financial risks to which privatization would subject a person, the primary risk being market risk. Using a model utilizing actual market yields for treasury bonds and returns for equities achieved during each year of eight 46-year periods and applying such yields or returns to period-adjusted income during these eight 46-year periods ending 1999 through 2005, during which time there was a recession and a recovery, followed by the calculation of the results of purchasing an 18-year annuity at the end of each period, a picture is developed of what people actually retiring during these years could have expected to receive had their social security contributions been put into a private account rather than into social security during their working careers. This provides additional insight into the levels of risk and the magnitude of monies involved in the event that the social security system is privatized. INTRODUCTION In the continuing debate about whether to privatize the federal social security system, one of the primary objections made by opponents is that privatization would subject potential recipients to an unacceptable level of risk due to market volatility. Much can be found in the literature about the levels of returns afforded by social security, ranging from a negative return to a low positive return, depending on earnings, marital status, and whether there is only one or more than one earner. (Ferrara, 1986; Crane, 1997) There is essentially no disagreement about whether social security provides a return inferior to what would likely be achieved in the market. It has been shown by a number of researchers to achieve lower returns than either bonds or equities. At best, recipients of social security upon retirement may receive around 2 to 3% on the money that was withheld from them, and this is for low wage earners who benefit from the program’s design to transfer benefits from higher wage earners to them. Higher wage earners are generally shown to receive a negative return from the social security system. Concerning the market risk of funds in a privatized system, the literature contains opinions and studies varying from the AARP’s suggesting that any market-based approach has great risk akin to the commodities market (FactCheck.Org., January 16, 2005) to studies to quantify market variations found over 10-year periods (Munnell, 2004) in which she found that 25% of the time the return on stocks would be lower than 39 A Reality-Based Model to Assess the Market Risk of Privatizing Social Security treasuries, or over 35-year periods in which the lowest 35-year period was one ending in 1982, yielding 3.6%, with the average for such 35-year periods ending between 1961 and 2002 being 7.3%. (National Center for Policy Analysis, January 16, 2003) Another longitudinal analysis of equity investments shows that during a period of 70 years ending in 1996, the worst 46-year interperiod, corresponding to the normal working life of someone contributing to social security, was 7.32% from 1929 to 1974. On the average over the entire period the return was found to be 10.89%. (Santorum, April 18, 2001) During the first half of this decade, our economy suffered the effects of, and then recovered from, a recession. In a previous study (Rahman and Joseph, 2001) used a model showing the results that would have been obtained from different investment and income assumptions, using the actual return of two investment scenarios for each year between 1953 and 1998, and a period-adjusted amount of income for that 46-year working span. Using the model developed for that study, this study steps through each year from 1999 through 2006 in 46-year periods. That is, eight individual 46-year periods whose end years range from 1999 through 2006 are modeled. By stepping the model through these eight periods a record is developed showing what actual returns would have been provided to someone retiring during each of the years 1999 through 2006 had they always had their withholdings privatized and invested in either treasury bonds or in equities. Because this eight-year span includes a recession and a recovery, this provides a real-life dimension to the debate over privatization and helps demonstrate the level of risk and potential monetary amounts involved at the individual level. THE STUDY The model that is used to step through the eight years in 46-year periods from 1999 through 2006 is constructed as described in the following paragraphs. An example of the calculations is shown as Table 1, which are the yield/return calculations for the year 2006. A similar table was constructed for each of the other seven periods ending 1999 through 2005. The worker, whether male or female, was hypothesized to begin working when he/she was 20 years old and to work as a single earner until he/she was 65, at which time he/she would retire. That is, a worker beginning employment at the beginning of 1954 would retire at the end of 1999, and a worker beginning employment at the beginning of 1961 would retire at the end of 2006, with the six intervening 46-year working career periods starting in 1955 through 1959 and ending in 2000 through 2005, respectively. Different retirement ages will occur in the future as the system is currently designed, but for consistency and simplicity these differences were not incorporated in the study. The level of earnings of the worker over the eight 46-year periods are assumed to be the OASDI maximum amount of taxable earnings during this time period. This started at $3,600 in 1954 and ended at $94,200 in 2006. (Social Security Administration, 2007) Different assumptions of earnings could have been used, but different earnings would not affect the actual returns of the markets, only the magnitude of the potential payouts. The actual money invested each year over each of the eight different 46-year periods was assumed to be 61.8% of the amount that is withheld for social security in total. The 1.8% is to approximate the amount that actually goes to social security with the balance going to disabled workers, surviving wives and husbands, children, widowed mothers, widows and widowers, parents, and special benefits. (Table 616, 1998) The amount that is withheld in total from a worker’s employment check for social security 40 Southwest Business and Economics Journal/2010 varies from 3.0% in 1954 to 6.2% in 2006 for the employee’s portion. The employee’s withholding is then doubled to account for the employer’s matching portion. The total amount to be invested in the model is then 61.8% of 6.0% in 1954 and 61.8% of 12.4% in 2006. (SSA Publication No. 05-10003, January 2007) Investment vehicles were assumed to be either treasury bonds (essentially riskless except for interest-rate risk) or equities. The treasury bond rate at the end of each year was used to develop the return for the treasury bond scenario and the change from yearend to year-end in the Dow Jones Industrial Average was used as the return for the equity scenario. The return for any given year was calculated using half the withholding for that year to account for the actual availability of funds for investment for the year of withholding which was then added to the entirety of the previous year’s total cumulative amount. The rates applied are as mentioned above for either treasury bonds or equity. At the time of retirement it was assumed that the retiree would purchase an annuity for 18 years, which approximates the expected remaining life span for people who are 65 in 1998. This statistic was not updated for this study to maintain comparability of results among following years. The rate used in the annuity’s payout is the average return for treasury bonds from 1999 through 2006, which was 5.21%. This would undoubtedly differ from year to year and from company to company from which annuities might be purchased, but for comparability among years, this, quite likely conservative rate, was used. DATA ANALYSIS Since previous studies amply demonstrated that investments in either essentially riskless vehicles such as treasury bonds or in riskier vehicles, at least short-term, such as equities both led to substantially superior returns as compared to the social security system, this study addresses the question of variability of returns and the associated risk of such investments (market risk) had someone retired during the years from 1999 through 2006. Tables 2 and 3 show the average return for each of the eight 46-year periods of employment, ending each year from 1999 to 2006. Table 2 shows that the average yield for treasury bonds over the period from 1954 through 1999 was 6.74% and that for someone retiring in each ensuing year the average yield showed a steady, small increase ending at 6.99% in 2006. Table 3 shows more variability, reflecting the effects of the recession, but in no year was the average return for the eight 46-year periods with investments in equities less than 7.35%, reaching that in 2005 after the recovery from the recession and the effects of 911. In each of the eight years the investment return in equities, the more volatile of the two investment scenarios, exceeds the yield of the treasury bond scenario. Tables 2 and 3 also show the cumulative investment amount, the monthly payout and the annual payout that would be achieved from an annuity over an 18-year period, assuming that the entire amount of the investment was placed in a costless annuity at 5.21%, the average rate of interest on the treasury bonds over the eight periods. The cumulative investment amounts in treasury bonds varied from a low in 1999 of $249,291 to a high of $384,811 in 2006. The annual payouts for treasury bonds varied from $21,372 to $32,990 over the same years. The cumulative investment amounts in equities varied from a low of $375,577 in 2002 to a high of $581,363 in 2006. The annual payouts for the same years were $32,199 and $49,841. As was found above with returns, 41 A Reality-Based Model to Assess the Market Risk of Privatizing Social Security the total cumulative amounts and the annual payouts for the equity scenario exceeds those of the treasury bond scenario for each year included in the study. Table 4 shows the actual, annual rates of return for either treasury bonds or the DJIA in each of the eight years studied. It also shows the change in returns from the previous year. It can be seen that there is significantly more variation from year to year in the DJIA annual returns than in treasury bonds, as would be expected. However, over the eight years from 1999 to 2006, the average returns are about the same, with treasury bonds somewhat outperforming the DJIA, Also, the average of the change from year to year, or volatility, almost breaks even for both scenarios even though the range of volatility from year to year is significantly greater for the equity scenario. The data in the tables show that while there is significant volatility in the year-toyear returns on equity investments from 1999 to 2006 as represented by the changes in the DJIA as a proxy for the equity scenario, with the averaging that occurs by annual investment over the 46-year employment period of the hypothesized worker, regardless of when this period started, the effect of the variation on the end amount available for purchase of an annuity is greatly diminished. Rather, because of the greater average returns over any of the eight 46-year periods, even during the recent recession, the equity scenario provided returns and total available funds that were superior to those provided by treasury bonds in each year of the eight retirement years. This superiority of results of equities is achieved even though the treasury bond rates show very little variation during the recession. And, it should be remembered that previous researchers have found the returns of the current social security system to be inferior to either treasury bonds or average equities in the returns provided by contributions made during a working career. Consequently, at least during the most recent recession, people retiring would have been significantly better off, even in the middle of the recession, had they had their withholdings invested in either treasury bonds or an average mix of equities during their working years. Further, it is shown that during these particular eight years for retirement a person would have received greater returns had he/she invested his/her contributions in equities rather than treasury bonds. One can imagine, though, the remorse that someone retiring in the equity scenario after 1999 and particularly in 2002 would feel when they eventually see that they might have had about $1,500 a month more if they had waited four more years to retire. It might be hard for that person to take solace in his/her being better off than if he/she had been in the treasury bond scenario or in the social security system. LIMITATION OF STUDY The study encompasses only one period of recession. There might be different outcomes in other recessionary periods. Further, the results are dependent on the results of yields of treasury bonds or the equity market and the magnitude of withholdings and subsequent investments during only the eight 46-year periods beginning in 1954 and ending in 2006. Results may be different for other 46-year periods. 42 Southwest Business and Economics Journal/2010 CONCLUSION While the years for the hypothesized workers to be retiring were only eight 46year periods for which withholdings were made and invested by the hypothesized worker, they did include a recent recession and a recovery from that recession. Consequently, by showing the actual yields and monetary results of retirement under two different scenarios during these years, with rates based on actual yields for the years involved and the amounts invested being based on period-adjusted income amounts, general information is provided about what would have happened to someone actually retiring during those years had he/she invested his/her contributions into either treasury bonds or a fund indexed to the DJIA. The study demonstrates that to the extent this recession and the eight 46-year working periods encompassed by the study are similar to other recessions and other 46-year working periods, the argument that the variability of bond or equity markets creates too much risk to allow the privatization of social security is not supported. Rather, workers are shown to be better off had their withholdings, or savings equal to withholdings, been invested in either treasury bonds or equities approximating the DJIA rather than being sent to the social security system. 43 A Reality-Based Model to Assess the Market Risk of Privatizing Social Security References Crane, Edward H. (1997). The Case for Privatizing America’s Social Security System. Address to S.O. S. Retraite Sante, Paris, France, December 10, 1997. FactCheck.Org. ( January 16, 2005) Social Security Ads: Risk or Protection? Ferrara, Peter J. (1986). Social Security Rates of Return for Today’s Young Workers. National Chamber Foundation. Munnell, Alicia, H. (2004). Risk and Privatized Social Security, The Boston Globe. December 31, 2004. National Center for Policy Analysis. (2003) Social Security and Stock Market Risk, No. 429. January 16, 2003. Rahman, Monsurur & Joseph, Jerry A. (2001). Privatization of Social Security: A Study of Three Hypothetical Cases, Journal of Accounting and Finance Research, Volume 9, Number 5, pp. 27-40. Santorum, Rick. (April 18, 2001) Facts, Not Politics, Drive Social Security Reform, Tribune-Review. Social Security Administration. (2006). Your Social Security Statement, Form SSA – 7005-SM-SI(05/06). SSA Publication No. 05-10003, January 2007. Table No. 616. (1998). Social Security(OASDI)- Benefits by types of Beneficiary” 1980 to 1998. U.S. Social Security Administration, annual Statistical Supplement to the Social Security Bulletin. 44 Southwest Business and Economics Journal/2010 Table 1: High Wage Earner Investment of 61.8% of OASDI 45 A Reality-Based Model to Assess the Market Risk of Privatizing Social Security Table 2: Treasury Bond TOTAL ANNUITIES, AVERAGE RETURNS, MONTHLY ANNUITY PAYOUTS, AND ANNUAL ANNUITY PAYOUTS BASED ON YEAR OF RETIREMENT YEAR 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 AVERAGE 46-YEAR RETURN 6.74% 6.80% 6.86% 6.91% 6.95% 6.97% 6.97% 6.99% TOTAL AMOUNT OF ANNUITY 249,291 267,084 285,852 304,624 324,427 344,554 363,928 384,811 MONTHLY PAYOUT OF ANNUITY 1780.99 1,908.11 2,042.19 2,176.30 2,317.78 2,461.57 2,598.00 2,749.18 ANNUAL PAYOUT OF ANNUITY 21,372 22,897 24,506 26,116 27,813 29,539 31,176 32,990 Table 3: Equity TOTAL ANNUITIES, AVERAGE RETURNS, MONTHLY ANNUITY PAYOUTS, AND ANNUAL ANNUITY PAYOUTS BASED ON YEAR OF RETIREMENT YEAR 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 46 AVERAGE 46-YEAR RETURN 9.67% 8.58% 7.97% 7.56% 8.39% 7.72% 7.35% 7.91% TOTAL AMOUNT OF ANNUITY 504,823 476,344 445,206 375,577 475,548 494,836 496,174 581,363 MONTHLY PAYOUT OF ANNUITY 3,606.57 3,403.11 3,187.31 2,683.21 3,397.43 3,535.22 3,544.78 4,153.39 ANNUAL PAYOUT OF ANNUITY 43,279 40,837 38,148 32,199 40,769 42,423 42,537 49,841 Southwest Business and Economics Journal/2010 Table 4 ANNUAL RETURNS AND CHANGES IN RETURNS FROM PREVIOUS YEARS YEAR 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 AVG (1999-2006) TREASURY BOND RETURN 5.09% 6.35% 5.49% 5.48% 5.01% 5.11% 4.88% 4.54% 4.81% 5.21% RETURN CHANGE FROM PREVIOUS YEAR 1.26% -0.86% -0.01% -0.47% 0.10% -0.23% -0.34% 0.27% -0.04% EQUITY RETURN 16.10% 25.22% -6.18% -7.10% -16.76% 25.32% 3.15% -0.61% 16.29% 4.92% RETURN CHANGE FROM PREVIOUS YEAR 9.12% -31.40% -0.92% -9.67% 42.09% -22.17% -3.76% 16.90% 0.02% 47 A Reality-Based Model to Assess the Market Risk of Privatizing Social Security 48