Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading The MIT Faculty has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Liu, Yang-Yu, Jose C. Nacher, Tomoshiro Ochiai, Mauro Martino, and Yaniv Altshuler. “Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading.” Edited by Tobias Preis. PLoS ONE 9, no. 10 (October 15, 2014): e109458. As Published http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0109458 Publisher Public Library of Science Version Final published version Accessed Thu May 26 00:45:16 EDT 2016 Citable Link http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/92479 Terms of Use Creative Commons Attribution Detailed Terms http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading Yang-Yu Liu1,2,3*., Jose C. Nacher4., Tomoshiro Ochiai5., Mauro Martino6, Yaniv Altshuler7 1 Channing Division of Network Medicine, Brigham and Women’s Hospital and Harvard Medical School, Boston, Massachusetts, United States of America, 2 Center for Complex Network Research and Departments of Physics, Computer Science and Biology, Northeastern University, Boston, Massachusetts, United States of America, 3 Center for Cancer Systems Biology, Dana-Farber Cancer Institute, Boston, Massachusetts, United States of America, 4 Department of Information Science, Faculty of Science, Toho University, Funabashi, Chiba, Japan, 5 Department of Social Information Studies, Otsuma Women’s University, Tama-shi, Tokyo, Japan, 6 Center for Innovation in Visual Analytics, Watson Research Center, IBM, Cambridge, Massachusetts, United States of America, 7 MIT Media Lab, Cambridge, Massachusetts, United States of America Abstract Prospect theory is widely viewed as the best available descriptive model of how people evaluate risk in experimental settings. According to prospect theory, people are typically risk-averse with respect to gains and risk-seeking with respect to losses, known as the ‘‘reflection effect’’. People are much more sensitive to losses than to gains of the same magnitude, a phenomenon called ‘‘loss aversion’’. Despite of the fact that prospect theory has been well developed in behavioral economics at the theoretical level, there exist very few large-scale empirical studies and most of the previous studies have been undertaken with micro-panel data. Here we analyze over 28.5 million trades made by 81.3 thousand traders of an online financial trading community over 28 months, aiming to explore the large-scale empirical aspect of prospect theory. By analyzing and comparing the behavior of winning and losing trades and traders, we find clear evidence of the reflection effect and the loss aversion phenomenon, which are essential in prospect theory. This work hence demonstrates an unprecedented large-scale empirical evidence of prospect theory, which has immediate implication in financial trading, e.g., developing new trading strategies by minimizing the impact of the reflection effect and the loss aversion phenomenon. Moreover, we introduce three novel behavioral metrics to differentiate winning and losing traders based on their historical trading behavior. This offers us potential opportunities to augment online social trading where traders are allowed to watch and follow the trading activities of others, by predicting potential winners based on their historical trading behavior. Citation: Liu Y-Y, Nacher JC, Ochiai T, Martino M, Altshuler Y (2014) Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading. PLoS ONE 9(10): e109458. doi:10.1371/journal. pone.0109458 Editor: Tobias Preis, University of Warwick, United Kingdom Received April 23, 2014; Accepted September 1, 2014; Published October 15, 2014 Copyright: ß 2014 Liu et al. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. Data Availability: The authors confirm that, for approved reasons, some access restrictions apply to the data underlying the findings. The trading data analyzed in the work was not directly collected by the authors, but provided by an online trading company, according to their data privacy policy and their agreement with MIT. Hence, due to both ethical and legal concerns, the authors cannot make the data public available without the permission of the company. However, upon request, they can refer any researchers to that company, which provides access to past data (and specifically – the same data that was used for this research) through their platform to academic researchers who sign an agreement with them (which is what the authors did). Hence it is totally possible for other researchers to reach the data owner by contacting yanival@media.mit.edu. Funding: This work was partially supported by NS-CTA sponsored by US Army Research Laboratory under Agreement No. W911NF-09-2-0053; DARPA under Agreement No. 11645021; DTRA under Agreement No. HDTRA1-10-1-0100/BRBAA08-Per4-C-2-0033. The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript. Competing Interests: Mauro Martino is an employee of IBM. This does not alter the authors’ adherence to PLOS ONE policies on sharing data and materials. * Email: yyl@channing.harvard.edu . These authors contributed equally to this work. better understanding of collective human behavior in financial markets [4–7]. In this work we focus on economic decision under risk, a key subject of behavior economics [8]. Successful behavior economic theories acknowledge the complexity of human economic behavior and introduce models that are well grounded in psychological research. For example, prospect theory is viewed as the best available descriptive model of how people evaluate risk [9–14]. Prospect theory states that people make decisions based on the potential value of losses and gains rather than the final outcome, and that people evaluate these losses and gains using certain heuristics. Despite the fact that prospect theory offers many remarkable insights and has been studied for more than three decades, there exist very few large-scale empirical research and most of the previous studies have been undertaken with micropanel data [15–21]. Moreover, there are relatively few well-known and broadly accepted applications of prospect theory in economics and finance [14]. The emergence of online social trading platforms Introduction We live life in the ‘‘big data’’ era. Many of our daily activities such as checking emails, making mobile phone calls, posting blogs on social media, shopping with credit cards and making financial trading online, will leave behind our digital traces of various kinds that can be used to analyze our behavior. The sudden influx of data is transforming social sciences at an unprecedented pace [1,2]. Indeed, we are witnessing the shift of social science research paradigm from interviewing a few dozens of people with crafted survey questionnaire to designing experiments involving millions of subjects on social media [3]. The availability of huge amounts of digital data also prompts us to rethink some fundamental perspectives of complex human behavior. Recent studies have already illustrated the potential that extensive behavioral data sets (e.g., Google trends, Wikipedia usage patterns, and financial news developments) could offer us a PLOS ONE | www.plosone.org 1 October 2014 | Volume 9 | Issue 10 | e109458 Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading Fig. 1a). Among them, mirror trade has the highest chance (&83%), much higher than that of single or copy trade. This indicates that in average social trades (especially mirror trades) indeed help traders win more frequently than non-social trades. Interestingly, not all the trade types have positive average ROI (see Fig. 1b). In fact, only mirror trade has positive average ROI (&0:03%), i.e., it generates profit, consistent with previous results [23]. In terms of ROI, social trades do not necessarily perform better than non-social trade. We notice that copy trade even has higher negative ROI than non-social trade, which simply implies that copying someone based on past performance can be dangerous. Overall, mirror trade outperforms both single and copy trades. Yet, the better performance of mirror trade comes at the price that its winning trades have much lower ROI (<0.177%) than that of copy and single trades (see Fig. 1c); while its losing trades have significantly higher negative ROI (<20.9%) than that of copy and single trades (see Fig. 1d). In other words, mirror trade typically does not generate high profit for winning positions but generate high loss for losing positions. Since mirror trade has very high chance of winning, the average ROI of mirror trade turns out to be positive. This implies that there is still much room to improve our social trading experience. To further understand the difference between social and nonsocial trade types, we calculate their duration distributions P(t) (see Fig. 2). Here the duration t of a trade or position is defined to be its holding time (in unit of millisecond), i.e., t : ~tclosed {topened where topened and tclosed are the position opened and closed time, respectively. Interestingly, P(t) displays similar fat-tailed distribution for all different trade types. There are very few positions that were held for very long time (more than one month). Most of the positions were held for less than half an hour. We also notice that for losing positions, many of them are held for less than one second, while for winning positions they are most likely held for longer than one second. This might be due to the so-called bid-ask spread. The price we can sell (bid) and the price we can buy (ask) is different at each time point. It is almost impossible for traders to overcome the spread within very short holding time interval (e.g., one second) by using online financial trading platforms. For t[½103 ,105 , we find that for all different trade types P(t) of positive trades is much lower than that of negative trades, i.e., winning probability is much less than 50% in this particular holding time window. Although the duration distributions of different trade types share many similar features, we do observe a noticeable difference in the regime of tw105 , i.e., longer than one minute. We find that for non-social trades with tw105 , P(t) of positive trades is roughly the same as that of negative trades. In other words, if the holding time of a non-social trade is longer than one minute, the winning chance is about 50%. For copy trades with t[(105 ,108 ), P(t) of positive trades is slightly higher than that of negative trades. For mirror trades with t[½105 ,109 , P(t) of positive trades is significantly higher than that of negative trades. In other words, if the holding time of a mirror trade is longer than one minute and less than one week, then its winning chance is much higher than 50%. We also calculate the trade duration as a function of the net profit for different trade types (see Fig. 3). We draw the box-andwhisker plot of duration (t) for trades with net profit (p) binned logarithmically. (For negative trades pv0, we bin them using DpD.) We denote the median value of durations as tm . We find that for all trade types tm shows asymmetric behavior: tm of losing positions with loss {p is generally higher than that of winning positions with profit p. This is a reflection of the so-called and the availability of burgeoning volume of financial transaction data of individuals help us explore the empirical aspect of prospect theory to an unprecedented large-scale. Moreover, analyzing the trading behavior at the individual level offers an excellent opportunity to develop pragmatic financial applications of prospect theory. By harnessing the wisdom of the crowds to our benefit and gain, social trading has been a revolutionary way to approach financial market investment. Thanks to various Web 2.0 applications, nowadays online traders can rely on trader generated financial content as the major information source for making financial trading decisions. This ‘‘data deluge’’ raises some new questions, answers to which could further deepen our understanding of the complexity of human economic behavior and improve our social trading experience. For example, many social trading platforms allow us to follow top traders, known as gurus or trade leaders, and directly invest our money like they do. The question is then how to identify those top traders. Analyzing their historical trading behavior would be a natural starting point [22]. Analysis The financial transaction data used in this work comes from an online social trading platform for foreign exchanges and commodities trading. This trading platform allows traders to take both long and short positions, with a minimal bid of a few dollars as well as leverage up to 400 times. The most important feature of social trading platform is that each trader automatically has all trades uploaded to the platform where trades can be displayed in a number of statistical ways, such as by the amount of profit made. Traders can then set their accounts to copy one or more trades made by any other traders, in which case the social trading platform will automatically execute the trade(s). Accordingly, there are three types of trades: (i) Single (or non-social) trade: Trader A places a normal trade by himself or herself; (ii) Copy trade: Trader A places exactly the same trade as trader B’s one single trade; (iii) Mirror trade: Trader A automatically executes trader B’s every single trade, i.e., trader A follows exactly trader B’s trading activities. Both (ii) and (iii) are hereafter referred to as social trading. There are about 3 million registered accounts in this online social trading platform. Some of them are practice accounts, i.e., trading with virtual money. Our data are composed of over 28.5 million trades made by 81.3 thousand traders trading with real money from June 2010 to October 2012. There are 31.8% single trades, 0.6% copy trades and 67.6% mirror trades. Apparently, social trading dominates over this trading platform during the time window of our data. It will be desirable to learn how to select the best traders to follow so that we can further improve our social trading experience — a pragmatic motivation of our current work. Quantitatively analyzing trading activities of traders within the framework of behavior economics naturally fits the goal. Ultimately, we would like to be able to predict potential winners based on their historical trading behavior so that we can take full advantage of the social trading paradigm. Results Social vs. Non-social trade We first need to demonstrate if social trades really help. In Fig. 1 we compare the fraction of winning trades (N+/N) and return on investment (ROI (%) : ~netprofit=investment|100) of the three different trade types. We find that all three trade types have more than 50% chance to generate positive net profit (see PLOS ONE | www.plosone.org 2 October 2014 | Volume 9 | Issue 10 | e109458 Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading Figure 1. Performance comparison of different types of trades. (a) Fraction of positive trades. Mirror trade has the highest fraction of positive trades. (b) Mean ROI. Mirror trade is the only trade type that has the positive SROIT. Here error bars mean the standard error of the mean (SEM). (c) Mean ROI of positive trades. Mirror trade has the lowest SROIT for positive trades. (d) Mean ROI of negative trades. Mirror trade has the highest negative SROIT for negative trades. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0109458.g001 zT negative trades. (ii) Win-loss holding time ratio s : ~ St St{ T, where St+ T represents the average holding time of positive/negative trades made by each trader. sw1 means that traders in average hold positive position longer than negative position. (iii) Win-loss SROIz T , where SROI+ T represents the average ROI ratio u : ~ SDROI { DT ROI of positive/negative trades made by each trader. uw1 means that traders in average have larger absolute ROI in positive trades z than in negative trades. (iv) Winning percentage w : ~ NzNzN , { where N+ represents the number of positive/negative trades made by each trader. ww1=2 simply means that traders in average have larger chance of winning than losing a trade. Note that if all traders trade pure randomly without any human emotions we would expect that the distributions of all the four metrics show symmetric behavior around r~1, s~1, u~1 and w~1=2, respectively. Yet, in reality traders behave quite differently from random (see Fig. 4). We find the risk-reward distribution P(r) displays strongly asymmetric behavior around r~1 (black dotted line in Fig. 4a). For rw1, P(r) follows a power law over almost 3 decades, which means it is extremely difficult to find traders with very large r; while for rƒ1, P(r) is almost a constant, which means traders with rƒ1 are almost uniformly distributed. By splitting the traders into two groups: winning and losing traders (i.e., traders with final net profit or net loss) and calculating their P(r) with appropriate normalization based on the ‘‘disposition effect’’: investors tend to sell financial assets whose price has increased while keeping asserts that have dropped in value [24–27]. In other words, investors are less willing to recognize losses, but are more willing to recognize gains. This is a typical irrational behavior that can be partially explained by the ‘‘loss aversion’’ phenomenon and the ‘‘reflection effect’’ in prospect theory [18, 28–32]. We also notice clear differences between mirror trade and the other two trade types. For both nonsocial and copy trades tm generally increases as DpD increases in either positive or negative direction, and tm of losing trades increases much faster as DpD increase than tm of winning trades increases as p increase. While for mirror trade, tm increases very slowly as p increases for positive positions. For mirror trades with negative p, tm increases initially as DpD increases, but quickly reaches a plateau. In other words, the disposition effect is lessened in mirror trade. It has been shown that more experienced investors are less affected by the disposition effect [33]. This might explain the good performance of mirror trade. Winning vs. Losing traders To characterize the trading behavior of traders and identify potential trade leaders, we introduce four behavioral metrics: (i) Spz T Risk-reward ratio r : ~ SDp , where Sp+ T represents the average { DT profit of positive/negative trades made by each trader. rw1 means that traders in average gain more in positive trades than the loss in PLOS ONE | www.plosone.org 3 October 2014 | Volume 9 | Issue 10 | e109458 Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading Figure 2. Duration distribution of different trade types. For each trade type, we further distinguish negative and positive trades based on their net profit. The trades with zero net profit are negligible. The duration distributions of negative and positive trades are normalized according to their corresponding occurrence. (a) All trades. (b) Non-social trades. (c) Copy trades. (d) Mirror trades. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0109458.g002 with very large u. Interestingly, for uƒ0:2, P(u) also follows a power-law over almost 2 decades. We find P(u)’s of winning and losing traders are also very different (see Fig. 4f). Winning traders’ u-range spans over ½10{1 ,300; while losing traders’ u-range is given by ½5|10{4 ,300. For uvu ~2 (pink line), P(u) of losing traders is significantly higher than that of winning traders; while for uwu, it is in the opposite case. For uv0:06, almost all traders are losing traders. Note that a large portion of traders (85:2%) are losing traders with final net loss. The fact that those losing traders typically have rv1,sv1 and uv1 could be explained by the ‘‘loss aversion’’ phenomenon and the ‘‘reflection effect’’ in prospect theory as follows. For positive positions, traders tend to be risk-averse and will close the position quickly to take a small profit or a small ROI. While for losing positions, traders tend to be risk-seeking and reluctant to close the positions as quick as they should. Instead they keep waiting and hoping to recover the loss. If indeed this happens, then they become risk-averse and tend to close the position quickly to take a small profit and result in a small ROI. If unfortunately this does not happen, they waste not only valuable time but also a lot of money, rendering large negative ROI. Thus, the losing traders have to suffer from their irrational trading behavior that can be described by prospect theory. One may naively consider the winning percentage type of behavioral metrics will help us identify gurus. Here we show it is fractions of winning and losing traders (14.7% and 85.2%, respectively), we find that the two groups behave in drastically different ways (see Fig. 4b). Winning traders’ r-range spans over ½10{2 ,103 ; while losing traders’ r-range is given by ½10{4 ,101 . The uniform P(r) for rv1 is largely due to losers; while the powerlaw of P(r) for rw10 is purely due to winning traders. We also notice that for rvr ~4 (pink line), P(r) of losing traders is significantly higher than that of winning traders; while for rwr , it is in the opposite case. We find the win-loss duration ratio distribution P(s) also displays strongly asymmetric behavior around s~1 (black dotted line in Fig. 4c). For sw1, P(s) almost follows a power law over 5 decades, which means it is extremely difficult to find traders with very large s; while for sƒ1, P(s) decays very slowly as s decreases, which means traders with sƒ1 are almost uniformly distributed. This indicates that most traders hold losing positions for a longer time than winning position, a typical disposition effect. Comparing winning and losing traders’ P(s) is also interesting (see Fig. 4d). Though their s-ranges are almost the same, we notice that for svs ~100 (pink line), P(s) of losers is significantly higher than that of winners; while for sws , it is in the opposite case. The win-loss ROI ratio distribution P(u) shows a strong peak around u~0:2 and a strongly asymmetric behavior around u~1 (black dotted line in Fig. 4e). For uw0:2, P(u) follows a power law over 3 decades, which means it is extremely difficult to find traders PLOS ONE | www.plosone.org 4 October 2014 | Volume 9 | Issue 10 | e109458 Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading Figure 3. Disposition effect in different trade types. Here, we bin the net profit p of different trade types in logarithmic bins. (If pv0, we bin it using DpD.) For the trades contained in each bin, we draw the box-and-whisker plot for their duration (t), representing the minimum, first quartile, median, third quartiles, and maximum of the data in the bin. (a) All trades. (b) Non-social trades. (c) Copy trades. (d) Mirror trades. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0109458.g003 values (r , s , u ) of these behavioral metrics indicates the importance of controlling human emotion to minimize the impact of the reflection effect and the loss aversion phenomenon for better trading performance. not the case. Fig. 4g displays the winning percentage distribution P(w), which is asymmetric around w~1=2. (Note that P(w) has significant peaks around some rational numbers w~0,1=2,1=3,2=3,:::,1, which are due to traders who made very few transactions.) Again, we find winning and losing traders’ P(w) show dramatically different behavior (see Fig. 4h). For wvw ~0:95, P(w) of losing traders is significantly higher than that of winning traders; while for www winning traders dominate. The value of w is so high that using it to select trade leaders is almost infeasible. We also notice that for wvw , losing traders actually dominate for a wide range of w. Yet, they are still losing money eventually due to their very low risk-reward ratio r. In other words, they win many times with small positive profit, but once they lose they lose a lot. In principle large values of those metrics do not imply net profit at all. For example, traders with r&1 could be simply due to a few trades with very large profit, but many trades with very small loss. Yet, the above analysis yields three characteristic values (r ~4, s ~100, u ~2) that can be used to statistically predict potential winning traders with high probability. We admit that those characteristic values may slightly depend on the particular dataset or trading platform. We emphasize that the strategy of using characteristic values of novel behavioral metrics to identify potential winning traders should be applicable to general social trading platforms. Furthermore, the existence of characteristic PLOS ONE | www.plosone.org Discussion The dynamics of financial trading is governed by individual human decisions, which implies that the trading performance could be significantly improved by understanding better the underlying human behavior. In this work we systematically analyze over 28.5 million trades made by 81.3 thousand traders of an online financial trading platform. By analyzing and comparing the performance of social and non-social trades, winning and losing traders, we find clear evidences of the reflection effect and the loss aversion phenomenon, which are essential in prospect theory of behavior economics. Many losing traders have very small risk-reward ratio (r), win-loss duration ratio (s), and win-loss ROI ratio (u), suggest that we should develop new trading strategies by systematically minimizing the impact of the reflection effect and the loss aversion phenomenon, e.g., through intentionally controlling s,u and/or r to fight over our human nature and rationalize our trading behavior. To provide traders many preferences in discovering gurus or trade leaders, social trading platforms rank traders on many 5 October 2014 | Volume 9 | Issue 10 | e109458 Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading PLOS ONE | www.plosone.org 6 October 2014 | Volume 9 | Issue 10 | e109458 Prospect Theory for Online Financial Trading Figure 4. Characterizing winning and losing traders based on historical trading behavior. (a, b) Distribution of risk-reward ratio Spz T ). pz and p{ are the profit of winning positions and the loss of losing positions, respectively, of traders. (c, d) Distribution of win-loss (r : ~ SDp { DT zT waiting time ratio (s : ~ St St{ T). Here Stz T and St{ T are the average duration time of winning and losing positions, respectively, of traders. (e, f) SROIz T Distribution of win-loss ROI ratio (u : ~ SDROI ). ROIz and ROI{ are the ROI of winning and losing positions, respectively, of traders. (g, h) { DT z ) of traders. Nz and N{ are the number of winning and losing positions, respectively, of traders. Distribution of winning percentage (w : ~ NzNzN { doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0109458.g004 different metrics, e.g., popularity (number of followers), profitable weeks, and the personal return of rate calculated from the modified Dietz formula [34], etc. Those different metrics typically yield different ranking lists, which effectively renders choosing the gurus something of an inspirational affair or a delicate trick. Moreover, traders should take into account the risks taken by these gurus in order to obtain the returns that they make. Unfortunately, not all the metrics rank the performance of traders on a riskadjusted basis. Here we propose three novel behavioral metrics (risk-reward ratio r, win-loss holding time ratio s, and win-loss ROI ratio u), which reveal the essence of prospect theory, the best available descriptive model of how people evaluate risk in behavioral economics. These metrics are defined for each trader by comparing his/her typical behavior in winning and losing trades, and hence are naturally risk-adjusted. Our analysis suggests that these metrics can be used to statistically predict potential winning traders, offering pragmatic opportunities to further improve our social trading experience. Acknowledgments We thank Albert-László Barabási for insightful comments. This work was partially supported by NS-CTA sponsored by US Army Research Laboratory under Agreement No. W911NF-09-2-0053; DARPA under Agreement No. 11645021; DTRA under Agreement No. HDTRA1-10-10100/BRBAA08-Per4-C-2-0033. Author Contributions Conceived and designed the experiments: YYL JCN TO. Performed the experiments: YYL JCN TO. Analyzed the data: YYL JCN TO. Contributed reagents/materials/analysis tools: YYL JCN TO. Wrote the paper: YYL JCN TO. Reviewed the manuscript: MM YA. References 17. Wu G, Zhang J, Abdellaoui M (2005) Testing Prospect Theories Using Probability Tradeoff Consistency. J Risk Uncertain 30: 107–131. 18. Abdellaoui M, Bleichrodt H, Paraschiv C (2007) Loss aversion under prospect theory: A parameter-free measurement. Manag Sci 53: 1659–1674. 19. Zhang W, Semmler W (2009) Prospect theory for stock markets: Empirical evidence with time-series data. J Econ Behav Organ 72: 835–849. 20. Booij A, Praag BV, van de Kuilen G (2010) A parametric analysis of prospect theory’s functionals for the general population. Theory Dec 68: 115–148. 21. Abdellaoui M, Bleichrodt H, Kammoun H (2011) Do financial professionals behave according to prospect theory? An experimental study. Theory Dec 74: 411–429. 22. Barber B, Odean T (2000) Trading is hazardous to your wealth: The common stock investment performance of individual investors. J Finance 55: 773–806. 23. Pan W, Altshuler Y, Pentland A (2012) Decoding social influence and the wisdom of the crowd in financial trading network. In: SocialCom/PASSAT. IEEE, pp. 203–209. 24. Shefrin H, Statman M (1985) The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long Theory and Evidence. J Finance 40: 777–790. 25. Weber M, Camerer C (1998) The disposition effect in securities trading: An experimental analysis. J Econ Behav Organ 33: 167–184. 26. Odean T (1998) Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? J Finance 53: 1775–1798. 27. Barberis N, Xiong W (2009) What drives the disposition effect? an analysis of a long-standing preference-based explanation. J Finance 64: 751–784. 28. Schmidt U, Traub S (2002) An Experimental Test of Loss Aversion. J Risk Uncertain 25: 233–249. 29. Schmidt U, Zank H (2002) Risk Aversion in Cumulative Prospect Theory. Royal Economic Society Annual Conference 2002 162, Royal Economic Society. 30. Schmidt U, Zank H (2005) What is Loss Aversion? J Risk Uncertain 30: 157– 167. 31. Brooks P, Zank H (2005) Loss Averse Behavior. J Risk Uncertain 31: 301–325. 32. Schmidt U, Zank H (2008) Risk Aversion in Cumulative Prospect Theory. Manag Sci 54: 208–216. 33. Costa ND, Goulart M, Cupertino C (2013) The disposition effect and investor experience. J Banking Finance 37: 16691675. 34. Dietz PO (2004) Pension Funds: Measuring Investment Performance (The Spaulding Series). Macmillian. 1. Lazer D, Pentland A, Adamic L, Aral S, Barabsi AL, et al. (2009) Computational social science. Science 323: 721–723. 2. Battiston S, Puliga M, Kaushik R, Tasca P, Caldarelli G (2012) Debtrank: Too central to fail? financial networks, the fed and systemic risk. Sci Rep 2. 3. Bond RM, Fariss CJ, Jones JJ, Kramer ADI, Marlow C, et al. (2012) A 61million-person experiment in social influence and political mobilization. Nature 489: 295–298. 4. Moat HS, Curme C, Avakian A, Kenett DY, Stanley HE, et al. (2013) Quantifying wikipedia usage patterns before stock market moves. Sci Rep 3: 1801. 5. Alanyali M, Moat HS, Preis T (2013) Quantifying the relationship between financial news and the stock market. Sci Rep 3: 3578. 6. Preis T, Moat HS, Stanley HE (2013) Quantifying trading behavior in financial markets using google trends. Sci Rep 3: 1684. 7. Krasny Y (2013) The effect of social status on decision-making and prices in financial networks. In: Altshuler Y, Elovici Y, Cremers AB, Aharony N, Pentland A, editors, Security and Privacy in Social Networks, Springer New York. pp. 85–131. 8. Diamond P, Vartiainen H (2007) Behavioral Economics and Its Applications Hardcover. Princeton University Press. 9. Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47: 263–291. 10. Tversky A, Kahneman D (1981) The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice. Science 211: 453–458. 11. Tversky A, Kahneman D (1992) Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. J Risk Uncertain 5: 297–323. 12. Wakker P, Tversky A (1993) An Axiomatization of Cumulative Prospect Theory. J Risk Uncertain 7: 147–75. 13. Schmidt U, Starmer C, Sugden R (2008) Third-generation prospect theory. J Risk Uncertain 36: 203–223. 14. Barberis N (2013) Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: A review and assessment. J Econ Perspect 27: 173–196. 15. Camerer CF (1998) Prospect Theory in the Wild: Evidence From the Field. Working Papers 1037, California Institute of Technology, Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. 16. Abdellaoui M (2000) Parameter-Free Elicitation of Utility and Probability Weighting Functions. Manag Sci 46: 1497–1512. PLOS ONE | www.plosone.org 7 October 2014 | Volume 9 | Issue 10 | e109458